Explaining the rain: The Rise and Decline of Nations after 25 years.
Heckelman, Jac C.
1. Introduction
Mancur Olson's (1982) The Rise and Decline of Nations was
hailed as an instant classic in several circles but was met with its
fair share of critics. To date, there are over 1800 citations of Rise
and Decline listed in the Social Science Citation Index. The citation count continues to be strong, ranging from 50 to 100 in any given year
since its publication (Figure 1). As detailed by Whaples (2003), while
Rise and Decline ranks second in citations only to Alfred
Chandler's The Visible Hand among all books in economic history, at
the same time it has received a decidedly mixed reaction from economic
historians, both in initial reviews and in current retrospection. McLean
(2000) asserts the common wisdom among public choice scholars that,
despite being an economist, Olson was probably more revered within
political science. Yet despite this (or perhaps because of it), Olson
has also been attacked as just another economist wrongly applying
economic theory to political science (Green and Shapiro 1994).
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Although a wide variety of related concepts can be found throughout
the book, most attention has been paid to Olson's concept of
"institutional sclerosis," in which it is hypothesized that
special interest groups will accumulate over time in stable societies
and eventually reduce the economic efficiency of the economy in which
they operate. An outline of the basic development of this theory is
presented in the next section.
The main purpose of the paper, however, is to consider the body of
evidence testing for institutional sclerosis. This is done in two parts:
first by examining previous cross-sectional regressions explaining
variation in growth rates and then by discussing the large-scale
descriptive accounts others have made regarding the experience of
various nations. As with any theory that has undergone a multitude of
tests, support for institutional sclerosis is not universal. On the
whole, however, it has been well received and appears to be equally
supported by both cross-sectional econometric tests and descriptive case
studies of individual nations. The interdisciplinary nature of
Olson's work is made clear by the almost equal appearance of these
tests in both economics and political science journals and by scholars
on both sides of the Atlantic. No systematic bias in favor or opposition
to Olson's theory is found to have arisen in any of these camps.
2. From The Logic to Rise and Decline
Mancur Olson's research covered a variety of topics, but he
will always be most closely connected to interest group formation and
their macroeconomic consequences. Olson's focus on interest groups
can be traced back to his dissertation at Harvard, later published as
The Logic of Collective Action (1965). (1) In Logic, Olson's
primary concern was the provision of goods or services that provide
benefits to multiple individuals, even those who do not participate in
their provision. Olson argued that collective provision of such goods or
services confronts the same difficulties as do cartels. Individuals will
take advantage of inexcludable benefits by declining to participate in
the provision of these goods and services, thereby acquiring the benefit
without incurring the cost. According to Olson, individual incentives
will tend to work against the formation of groups whose purpose is to
provide these public goods. Olson notes that in this context, the free
market would underprovide public-type goods. He emphasized, however,
that the extent of this free-riding behavior would be a function of
group size. Small groups would be more likely to form than would large
groups because free riding is easier to monitor in smaller groups.
Larger groups are expected to have trouble attracting membership
and would need to rely on a system of selective incentives. Such groups
would need to also simultaneously offer special excludable private
goods, such as low-cost insurance, to act as an enticing carrot, while
social pressures, such as ostracism or physical harm, would represent a
threatening stick. However, if a single member could obtain a benefit
that would exceed the total cost, he or she may provide the good while
others free ride on its nonexcludability. Olson referred to this
phenomenon as "exploitation of the great by the small." In
game-theoretic terms, complete free riding is the Nash equilibrium to a
prisoners' dilemma game, but exploitation of the great by the small
is akin to the equilibrium in a game of chicken, where even the
exploited is better off, although in a personal second-best situation
(Mueller 2003, chap. 2).
The analysis stemming from Logic suggests that narrow special
interests will be more prevalent than larger groups, which suffer from
free-riding problems. In The Rise and Decline of Nations (Rise and
Decline hereafter), Olson set out to develop the macroeconomic
consequences of the interests facing such groups. In particular, he
argued that past research on the sources of growth were lacking since
they did not answer the fundamental question as to the primary
establishment of growth prospects; rather, "they trace the water in
the river to the streams and lakes from which it comes, but they do not
explain the rain" (Olson 1982, p. 4). Olson set out to explain the
rain that created the environment for growth and the avenues in which
growth was blocked by these same forces.
As developed in Rise and Decline, because the benefits of economic
growth are widely dispersed across members of society, the likely gain
to any group that advocates faster growth will be only a small share of
these benefits unless the group is sufficiently encompassing of society
overall. At the same time, a progrowth advocacy group will incur all the
costs of its efforts. As such, economic growth can be viewed as another
sort of public good. Following through from Logic, Olson argued that
incentives work against the formation of progrowth groups. On the other
hand, groups that form to advocate excludable redistribution will obtain
large benefits for themselves while imposing costs on the broader
society. Redistribution of this sort is akin to a negative externality that the interest group does not consider (in full). Consequently,
groups that encourage redistribution are more likely to successfully
form than groups that advocate growth. Moreover, since it takes time for
even small groups to overcome their collective action problems, over
time more special interest groups are expected to form and engage in
redistributive activities. As these groups form, their impact will serve
to divert scarce economic resources away from technological advances and
other growth-enhancing activities that are nonexcludable toward
redistributive activities. Thus, Olson predicts that economic growth
will naturally decline over time in stable societies as groups continue
to flourish.
These sclerotic effects are due to the formation of special
interest organizations. If the interest groups or their means of
influencing policy are destroyed, growth prospects would be enhanced.
Instability, such as coups and revolutions, is expected to destroy the
influence of these groups and their avenues for controlling social
resources. Constant instability, however, will also open up new avenues
for rent seeking. Thus, Rise and Decline predicts that the best growth
prospects should be present where there is recent social upheaval but
that long-term stability is expected to follow.
3. Tests of the Theory of Institutional Sclerosis
In chapter 3 of Rise and Decline, Olson lays out nine distinct
implications from his analysis. (2) Although he discusses all the
hypotheses to some extent in the remaining four chapters, Olson pays
particular attention to three of the implications:
Implication 2: Stable societies with unchanged boundaries tend to
accumulate more collusions and organizations for collective action over
time.
Implication 4: On balance, special interest organizations and
collusions reduce efficiency and aggregate income in the societies in
which they operate and make political life more divisive.
Implication 7: Distributional coalitions slow down a society's
capacity to adopt new technologies and to reallocate resources in
response to changing conditions and thereby reduce the rate of economic
growth.
Only a handful of studies have directly tested Implication 2. The
vast majority of the literature has instead either tested some variant of Implications 4 and 7 or combined the three implications to relate
stability to economic growth, leaving the role of special interest
organizations and distributional coalitions implicitly in the
background.
Empirical Tests Involving Regression Analysis on Economic Growth
Olson's econometric evidence in Rise and Decline focuses on
the various state economies of the United States, where it is shown that
measures of state age are directly correlated with union membership
(Implication 2), union membership is inversely correlated with the
growth rate of income (Implications 4 and 7), and state age is inversely
correlated with income growth (combination of Implications 2, 4, and 7).
The length of a state's life is based either on the date of
statehood or the end of the Civil War for the states of the Confederacy because these latter states were thought to have had their institutional
structures rebuilt in the aftermath of Reconstruction. Many subsequent
independent studies largely followed Olson's empirical framework.
The evidence regarding Olson's theory of institutional
sclerosis is summarized in Table 1. The theory of institutional
sclerosis has been most frequently tested by comparing cross-national or
American state growth rates. The top portion of Table 1 includes only
empirical tests that have relied on regression analysis of growth rates.
Because the sclerosis literature is so vast, studies that use other
dependent variables are not included in the table. Some examples of
alternative sclerotic effects investigated include the level of GDP (Quiggen 1992), inflation and unemployment (Paloheimo 1984), income
inequality (Chart 1989), investment (Coates and Heckelman 2003b), and
degree of financial development (Rajan and Zingales 2003). Empirical
tests of other implications from Rise and Decline are not discussed
here. (3)
In cross-national tests, the number of years of stable borders and
uninterrupted democracy for each country is sometimes used to proxy for
the sclerotic effect (Weede 1984, 1986b; Bernholz 1986). However, this
does not address Olson's theory or the spirit of Olson's tests
very well, as wars or internal coups can create upheaval without
changing the society's borders. Others have marked the number of
years since the last domestic war (Landau 1985; Tang and Hedley 1998) or
created "trauma" variables (Chan 1987; Goldsmith 1987) to
measure the degree of destruction caused by wars and revolutions.
These studies are indirect in that the role of interest groups is
only implicit and does not appear directly in the regression analysis.
The problem may stem from Olson's own analysis, where he first
presented regressions on the relationship between state age and growth,
which combines Implications 2, 4, and 7, before breaking them down into
direct tests of individual implications. Direct tests would relate
interest groups directly to growth. Unfortunately, because of data
limitations, such an approach is rarely undertaken. Olson's proxy
for interest group activity among the U.S. states is union membership
rates because "labor unions are the main organizations with
negative effects on local growth, and their membership should also serve
as a proxy measures of the strength of such other coalitions that are
harmful to local growth" (p. 105). Following Olson's proxy
choice, Gray and Lowery (1988) and Crain and Lee (1999) generated
contrasting results for the U.S. states, while Lange and Garrett (1985)
found mixed support among a small sample of OECD nations.
Gray and Lowery (1988) find only weak evidence that business
interest groups harm growth among the U.S. states and conclude by
generally rejecting Olson's hypothesis. However, they measure
business groups relative to union size on the idea that, although unions
are redistributive in nature, business groups should be progrowth. Such
an interpretation is counter to Olson's view that considers
business groups to be like cartels, focused more on their own gains and
less on society at large. When measuring the number of business
associations in isolation, Crain and Lee (1999) find support for Olson
in their negative impact on state income growth.
McCallum and Blais (1987) claim support for Olson's thesis
when they find measures of stability to be a significant factor for
growth (which is an indirect test) among the OECD nations, even though
at the same time they note that in unreported regressions,
Murrell's (1984) measure of the number of sectional coalitions
(which represents a more direct test) is not. Using this same proxy for
interest groups, Coates and Heckelman (2003a) find that the harmful
effects on growth from the presence of interest groups are nonlinear.
Expanding the sample to include less developed countries (LDCs),
Heckelman (2000) finds a consistent negative relationship between
Murrell's interest group count and economic growth, but the effect
is not significant except when using econometric methods that take into
account the weakness of the proxy relationship between the observed
number of groups and the unmeasurable strength of these groups. In
contrast, Knack and Keefer (1997) and Knack (2003) find that increased
membership in "Olson groups" does not reduce growth.
Most empirical tests of institutional sclerosis are limited to
either OECD nations or the U.S. states. This is probably because
Olson's own empirical analysis focused on developed democracies,
which may give the false impression that sclerosis can occur only in
these nations. Olson is aware that "the possibility is the theory
is true or largely true for these countries [postwar developed
democracies] but does not apply to other types of societies, such as the
developing nations or the communist countries" (p. 147), but
devotes his chapter 6 on development to dismissing this concern.
Olson makes only passing reference to Soviet-style economies in
Rise and Decline but later applied the same logic in his
"devolution" papers (Olson 1990b, 1992; Murrell and Olson
1991). The analysis in Rise and Decline was extended to communist
societies by focusing on bureaucratic direction in the policy process.
Because the state directly controlled resources, bureaucratic interests
were in a strong position to seek rents and redistribute toward
themselves. As these interests became more entrenched, they became more
efficient at siphoning resources away from other needed areas, creating
greater and greater harm for the economy overall while continuing to
improve their own positions. Murrell and Olson (1991) showed that
stability in centrally planned economies eventually led to economic
growth rates falling below those of market economies. Faith and Short
(1995) present empirical tests for Czechoslovakia and Hungary that
confirm the central implications of devolution theory that over time
bureaus became more autonomous and formed into distributional
coalitions, thereby lowering technical efficiency.
As discussed later in this paper, Olson describes in Rise and
Decline how his theory applies to a select group of developing nations
but does so without any accompanying econometric evidence. Weede (1986a)
may have been the first to run regressions for growth rates of LDCs on a
measure of sclerosis. (4) Weede's proxy of an index of price
distortions, however, is far removed from any direct connection to
Olson. Neither groups nor national stability appear in the regression,
and any number of non-Olsonian factors may have contributed to the
variation in price distortions. Thus, Weede's claimed support for
Olson must be qualified.
More recently, samples mixing developed and developing nations
appear to be the norm. In a predominantly but not exclusively
OECD-oriented sample, Knack's (2003) proxy for interest group
intensity comes from a survey of the number of sectional groups to which
respondents belong. Heckelman (2000) extends the McCallum and Blais
(1987) OECD-exclusive sample by adding group counts for three additional
OECD nations and 22 non-OECD nations. (5) By far the largest sample
testing for institutional sclerosis is the LDC-dominated 114-nation
sample in Koubi (2005). Care should be taken, though, not to mix stable
and unstable nations in the same sample. Olson (p. 167) states that
"the most basic implication of the theory for unstable societies,
then, is that their governments are systematically influenced" by
various vested interests that can quickly organize. Thus, the proper
comparison would be to relate length of stability to growth, as long as
each nation was stable during the entirety of the growth period. Indeed,
although Heckelman (2000) reports an inverse correlation between the
number of sectional groups and growth across the full sample of
countries analyzed, the relationship was found to be statistically
significant only for the subset of nations not having undergone any
coups or revolutions during the sample growth period.
In sum, the majority of studies conducting empirical tests
generally find support for Olson's thesis. A quarter of them do
not, while the rest find mixed support. Given the variety of proxies
utilized and samples considered, it would appear that a lot of
econometric evidence has been generated, largely substantiating the
theory of institutional sclerosis.
Descriptive Narrative Histories
In Rise and Decline, Olson also presents narrative histories of the
post--World War II experience for many nations that are consistent with
his theory. The fastest-growing nations in the postwar period were those
that suffered the most destruction within their society, including
especially the eradication of their wartime and prewar governments. In
these countries, namely, Germany, Japan, and Italy, newly installed
democratic governments fostered stability in economic and political
relationships. Nations whose governments and institutions were not
altered by the war, such as the United States, Britain, Australia, and
New Zealand, generated much lower growth after the war.
Olson quickly realized his original theory of institutional
sclerosis was underdeveloped and, in his 1983 Southern Economic
Association presidential address, makes the point that political
institutions can be altered in such a fundamental fashion that upheaval
can occur even without wars and coups. He stresses as examples the 1965
Voting Rights Act and the end of Jim Crow laws, which gave the southern
states a fresh start, clearing out the existing sclerotic institutions
and opening up avenues of influence to new parties and ideas. Olson
argued that this is why the southern states were able to grow much
faster in recent years than they had previously but expected their rate
of growth to once again decline over time. This suggests that to
properly test for sclerotic effects on the economy of a country, state,
or province, it is necessary to understand the political and
institutional histories of that jurisdiction.
Olson explains in Rise and Decline how the caste system in India
and apartheid in South Africa served as institutional forms of
discrimination that hampered growth prospects. These
"multigenerational distributional coalitions foster
inefficiency" (p. 160) by exhibiting "all the features of
cartels and other special-interest organizations" (p. 157).
Eliminating these systems would open up the avenues for growth by
destroying their sclerotic effect.
Developing nations have received much less attention in the
institutional sclerosis literature. Of all the narrative case studies
listed in the bottom portion of Table 1, only a few (Manzetti 1992;
Weyland 1996; Hojman 2002; Demir 2005) focus exclusively on a currently
developing nation, all but one of which are part of Latin America. Each
of these studies claims to support the idea of institutional sclerosis
in their respective nations. By contrast, European nations have received
the bulk of the attention, and the overall picture here is somewhat less
clear but still generally supportive.
Case studies are eclectic by nature. The studies listed in the
lower portion of Table 1 are limited to those where the discussion of
institutional sclerosis received prominent attention rather than simply
a brief mention. (6) Unlike regression analysis, which has a definitive
dependent variable and specified proxies and where (for better or worse)
conclusions are based primarily on the size of estimated t-statistics,
narrative histories are broader in scope but also fuzzier to interpret.
Several aspects of a theory can be considered at once, with the
resulting discussion rarely coming down consistently on one side. And
while most studies look for evidence of how and when interest groups
form and get destroyed and whether they do exert a drag on efficiency
and growth when they are in existence, a few have examined the
"encompassingness" of coalitions to determine if these
specific types of groups are growth enhancing. For example, the
decentralized nature of Swiss representation and reliance on direct
democracy led Olson to characterize this nation as the exception that
proved his rule regarding institutional sclerosis. Lehner (1983),
however, presented a much more detailed account of the Swiss system and
concluded that there was only partial support for Olson's
conjecture.
The "case studies" in Rise and Decline are fairly brief,
as they are meant to illuminate specific aspects of the general theory.
This has been a general complaint among economic historians in
particular when reviewing Olson's work (see Whaples 2003). As was
also true regarding the empirics, Olson opened the door for the
descriptive accounts but repeatedly acknowledged to his critics that he
left the heavy lifting to others (Olson 1986, 1997). Other authors have
been able to devote the space necessary to detail all the institutional
nuances unique to each individual country by focusing exclusively on
only one country or a small number of countries in a full-fledged case
study. With rare exceptions (Olson 1983, 1984, 1990a), this was not
Olson's focus, as he was more interested in showing how broadly his
theory could be applied. In general, the theory of institutional
sclerosis has often been used by other scholars to successfully explain
experiences throughout history, but only rarely has it come out
unscathed. Perhaps more important, there seem to be only isolated
instances where a critic has dismissed the theory wholesale (in
particular, Rasch and Sorensen 1986 [for Norway] and Paque 1996 [for
Germany]).
Does the Evidence Vary Systematically by Source?
In a survey concerning public choice-related research administered
to a semi-random sample of members of the American Economics Association
(AEA) and the American Political Science Association (APSA), Heckelman
and Whaples (2006) report that both economists and political scientists
overall agree that "the size of government has grown due to the
proliferation of special interests," but both tended to disagree
that "economies grow faster after coups and revolutions due to the
destruction of existing special interest organizations." On the
former statement, economists favored the idea more strongly than
political scientists, but no significant differences emerged on the
latter. (7) Among the 34 statements contained in the questionnaire, AEA
members gave the government growth explanation statement its
sixth-highest level of support overall, but it was only tenth among the
APSA members. The support from both groups on the economic growth
statement was toward the very bottom of all the statements. Apparently,
there is not widespread belief in Olson's explanation for the rain.
The simple survey evidence suggests there may be some slight
difference in the views of economists and political scientists regarding
the main implications of Rise and Decline. This could be explained by a
variety of factors. To a certain extent, it is widely believed that
Olson may have been more highly regarded in political science than
within his own field of economics (McLean 2000; Heckelman and Coates
2003b). While Olson held the presidency of several different economics
associations, APSA specifically recognized Rise and Decline in 1983 by
giving it the Gladys W. Kammerer Award for the best political science
publication in the field of U.S. national policy and in 1993
acknowledged Olson's lifetime achievements by creating the Mancur
Olson award for best dissertation on political economy, presumably a
direct nod to the continued importance of Logic, which stemmed from his
own dissertation. No such prizes were forthcoming from the AEA. Still,
certain political scientists may have an inherent bias against Olson as
an economist outsider, dismissing him, as Green and Shapiro (1994) do,
as part of the rational choice approach to politics they hold in
contempt. (8)
Less nefariously, the body of accumulated evidence may be
interpreted differently by economists and political scientists. If
institutional sclerosis is supported to a greater extent in studies
appearing in economics journals, which political scientists are less apt
to read, or vice versa, then there could be a bias in the source of
information on which these scholars make their determination.
Alternatively, if rank-and-file APSA members are less comfortable than
typical AEA members in wading through tables of econometric evidence,
they may focus more on--or have more faith in--reading the narrative
case studies. If the evidence from regression analysis systematically
differs from the case study approach, that could have differential
influences across the disciplines as well.
Table 2 summarizes the conclusions derived from the studies listed
in Table 1 and also groups them by methodology, outlet, and author
location. (9) There is a roughly even split between the type of evidence
considered for institutional sclerosis, with almost an equal number
comprised of quantitative regression analysis versus the narrative case
study approach. There also does not appear to be much of a publication
bias in the journal outlets, with 22 studies appearing in economics
journals (10) compared to 18 in political science journals. A smaller
number have appeared in book form. Authorship, however, is dominated by
scholars based at American institutions.
Authors from both American and European institutions have evenly
split their publications between economics and political science
journals. Of the studies produced by scholars at American institutions,
almost twice as many are regression based compared to descriptive case
studies, whereas the reverse is true among the European authors.
Somewhat surprisingly, narrative case studies are more likely to appear
in an economics journal than a political science journal, whereas
econometric studies are not. Separate books or original studies within a
collected volume are heavily dominated by the case study approach, with
only three studies appearing in this format employing regressions as the
primary means of analysis.
Importantly, the evidence on institutional sclerosis does not seem
to be overly dependent on these criteria. There do not appear to be any
systematic differences between the evidence found from regression-based
studies versus narrative case studies, whether the author's home
affiliation is from a North American or a European institution or
whether the study appeared in an economics or a political science
journal, but those that were printed as part of a collective volume or
as an independent book tended to support the implications from Rise and
Decline to a somewhat greater extent. (11) The overall support rate of
57% is almost perfectly matched in each of the categories except for the
book/collected volume set of studies, which is slightly higher.
Unreported regression analysis supports this conception as well.
Assigning support levels as +1, 0, or -1 (for support, mixed, or does
not support), dummy variables for methodology, source, or author
location (12) were never significant in various combinations in
regressions explaining support for Rise and Decline. (13) Nor does the
evidence vary systematically over time, as evidenced by nonsignificance
of a variable marking the year of publication. On average, the evidence
in favor of institutional sclerosis is just as strong in recent years as
when Rise and Decline was first published. So, in general, no bias in
the literature has been identified. Given the general support for
institutional sclerosis, which remains constant across the dimensions of
methodology, outlet, authorship, and timing, it is surprising then that
the survey result presented in Heckelman and Whaples (2006) on the
statement that "economies grow faster after coups and revolutions
due to the destruction of existing special interest organizations"
does not reveal greater appreciation from both AEA and APSA members.
4. Conclusion
In the quarter century since publication of The Rise and Decline of
Nations, a large literature has evolved debating many of the ideas and
issues initially developed in Olson's book. Overall, the bulk of
the evidence from over 50 separate studies favors Olson's theory of
institutional sclerosis. The overall degree of support appears to be
independent of the methodological approach between econometric
regression analysis on growth rates versus narrative case studies,
publication in an economics or a political science journal, location of
authorship from an American or European institution, or the year of
publication. Assessing the evidence, it appears that the relevance of
Rise and Decline remains even after 25 years of helping to explain which
streams will grow with more rain and which will tend to dry up.
I thank Dennis Coates, Suzanne Gleason, Dan Hammond, Ivo Bischoff,
David Mitch, and Randy Holcombe for their comments and suggestions.
References
Asselain, J.-C., and C. Morrison. 1983. Economic growth and
interest groups: The French experience. In The political economy of
growth, edited by D. C. Mueller. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press,
pp. 157-75.
Bernholz, P. 1986. Growth of government, economic growth, and
individual freedom. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics
142:661-83.
Blankart, C. 2001. Popitz law, Bryce's law and government
centralization in Prussia and in Germany. Journal of Public Finance and
Public Choice 19:71-81.
Booth, A., J. Melling, and C. Dartmann. 1997. Institutions and
economic growth: The politics of productivity in West Germany, Sweden,
and the United Kingdom, 1945-1955. Journal of Economic History
57:416-44.
Broadberry, S. N. 1988. The impact of world wars on the long run
performance of the British economy. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 4:25-37.
Cameron, D. 1988. Distributional coalitions and other sources of
economic stagnation: On Olson's Rise and Decline of Nations.
International Organization 42:561-603.
Chan, S. 1987. Growth with equity: A test of Olson's theory
for the Asian Pacific Rim countries. Journal of Peace Research
24:135-49.
Chart, S. 1989. Income inequality among LDCs: A comparative
analysis of alternative perspectives. International Studies Quarterly
33:45-65.
Choi, K. 1983. A statistical test of Olson's model. In The
political economy of growth, edited by D. C. Mueller. New Haven, CT:
Yale University Press, pp. 57-78.
Coates, D., and J. C. Heckelman. 2003a. Absolute and relative
effects of interest groups on the economy. In Collective choice, edited
by J. C. Heckelman and D. Coates. Berlin: Springer-Verlag, pp. 129-42.
Coates, D., and J. C. Heckelman. 2003b. Interest groups and
investment: A further test of the Olson hypothesis. Public Choice
117:333-40.
Crain, W. M., and K. J. Lee. 1999. Economic growth regressions for
the American states: A sensitivity analysis. Economic Inquiry 37:242-57.
Demir, F. 2005. Militarization of the market and rent-seeking
coalitions in Turkey. Development and Change 36:667-90. Faith, R. L.,
and N. C. Short. 1995. Bureaucratic tenure and economic performance in
centrally planned economies. Public Choice 83:139-57.
Garand, J. C. 1992. Changing patterns of relative state economic
growth over time: Limitations on cross-sectional tests of Olson's
thesis. Western Political Quarterly 45:469-83.
Goldsmith, A. A. 1987. Does political stability hinder economic
development? Comparative Politics 19:471-80.
Gray, V., and D. Lowery. 1988. Interest group politics and economic
growth in the U.S. states. American Political Science Review 82:109-31.
Green, D. P., and I. Shapiro. 1994. Pathologies of rational choice.
New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Gustafsson, A. 1986. Rise and
decline of nations: Sweden. Scandinavian Political Studies 9:35-50.
Heckelman, J. C. 2000. Consistent estimates of the impact of
special interest groups on economic growth. Public Choice 104:319-27.
Heckelman, J. C., and D. Coates. 2003a. Collective choice: Essays
in honor of Mancur Olson. Berlin: Springer-Verlag.
Heckelman, J. C., and D. Coates. 2003b. On the shoulders of a
giant: The legacy of Mancur Olson. In Collective choice: Essays in honor
of Mancur Olson, edited by J. C. Heckelman and D. Coates. Berlin:
Springer-Verlag, pp. 1-13.
Heckelman, J. C., and R. Whaples. 2006. Do economists differ from
political scientists on public choice? Evidence from a survey. Korean
Journal of Public Choice 1:35-41.
Hennart, J.-F. 1983. The political economy of comparative growth
rates: The case of France. In The political economy of growth, edited by
D. C. Mueller. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, pp. 176-202.
Hojman, D. E. 2002. The political economy of Chile's fast
economic growth: An Olsonian interpretation. Public Choice 111:155-78.
James, P. 2003. Developing the Canadian government's
bargaining position on the Constitution, June-July 1980: An application
of Olson's argument from The Rise and Decline of Nations. In
Collective choice, edited by J. C. Heckelman and D. Coates. Berlin:
Springer-Verlag, pp. 113-27.
Kang, S., and J. Meernik. 2005. Civil war destruction and the
prospects for economic growth. Journal of Polities 67:88-109.
Kirby, M. W. 1992. Institutional rigidities and economic decline:
Reflections on the British experience. Economic History Review
45:637-60.
Knack, S. 2003. Groups, growth and trust: Cross-country evidence on
the Olson and Putnam hypotheses. Public Choice 117:341-55.
Knack, S., and P. Keefer. 1997. Does social capital have an
economic payoff? A cross-country investigation. Quarterly Journal of
Economics 112:1251-88.
Koubi, V. 2005. War and economic performance. Journal of Peace
Research 42:67-82.
Landau, D. L. 1985. Government expenditure and economic growth in
the developed countries: 1952-76. Public Choice 47:459-77.
Lane, J.-E., and S. Ersson. 1986. Political institutions, public
policy and economic growth. Scandinavian Political Studies 9:19-34.
Lange, P., and G. Garrett. 1985. The politics of growth: Strategic
interaction and economic performance in the advanced industrial
democracies, 1974-1980. Journal of Politics 47:792-827.
Lehner, F. 1983. Pressure politics and economic growth:
Olson's theory and the Swiss experience. In The political economy
of growth, edited by D. C. Mueller. New Haven, CT: Yale University
Press, pp. 203-14.
Maitland, I. 1985. Interest groups and economic growth rates.
Journal of Polities 47:44-58.
Manzetti, L. 1992. The evolution of agricultural interest groups in
Argentina. Journal of Latin American Studies 24:585-616.
McAloon, J. 2006. Long slow boom? Manufacturing in New Zealand,
1945-70. Australian Economic History Review 46:45-69.
McCallum, B., and A. Blais. 1987. Government, special interest
groups, and growth. Public Choice 54:3-18.
McLean, I. 2000. The divided legacy of Mancur Olson. British
Journal of Political Science 30:651-68.
Milner, H. 1994. Social democracy and rational choice: The
Scandinavian experience and beyond. New York: Routledge.
Mueller. D. C. 1983. The political economy of growth. New Haven,
CT: Yale University Press.
Mueller, D. C. 2003. Public choice III. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Murrell, P. 1984. An examination of the factors affecting the
formation of interest groups in OECD countries. Public Choice 43:151-71.
Murrell, P., and M. Olson. 1991. The devolution of centrally
planned economies. Journal of Comparative Economics 15:239-65.
Nardinelli, C., M. S. Wallace, and J. T. Warner. 1987. Explaining
differences in state growth: Catching up versus Olson. Public Choice
52:201-13.
Nardinelli, C., M. S. Wallace, and J. T. Warner. 1988. State
business cycles and their relationship to the national cycle: Structural
and institutional determinants. Southern Economic Journal 54:950-60.
O Grada, C., and K. O'Rourke. 1996. Irish economic growth,
1945-88. In Economic growth in Europe since 1945, edited by N. Crafts
and G. Toniolo. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 388-426.
Olson, M. 1962. The economics of strategic bombing in World War II.
The Airpower Historian 2:121-7.
Olson, M. 1965. The logic of collective action. Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press.
Olson, M. 1982. The rise and decline of nations. New Haven, CT:
Yale University Press.
Olson, M. 1983. The south will fall again: The south as leader and
laggard in economic growth. Southern Economic Journal 49:917-32.
Olson, M. 1984. Australia in perspective of The Rise and Decline of
Nations. Australian Economic Review, Issue 67:7-17.
Olson, M. 1986. An appreciation of the tests and criticisms.
Scandinavian Political Studies 9:65-80.
Olson. M. 1990a. How bright are the northern lights? Some questions
about Sweden. Lund: Institute of Economic Research, Lund University.
Olson, M. 1990b. The logic of collective action in Soviet-type
societies. Journal of Soviet Nationalities 1:8-33.
Olson, M. 1992. The hidden path to a successful economy. In The
emergence of market economies, edited by C. Clague and G. C. Rausser.
New York: Blackwell, pp. 55-75.
Olson, M. 1997. An appreciation: Reply to Booth, Melling, and
Dartmann. Journal of Economic History 57:445-7.
Olson, M., and C. Harris. 1959. Free trade in "corn": A
statistical study of the prices and production of wheat in Great Britain from 1873 to 1914. Quarterly Journal of Economics 73:145-68.
Orchard, L., and H. Stretton. 1997. Public choice. Cambridge
Journal of Economics 21:409-30.
Paloheimo, H. 1984. Distributive struggle and economic development
in the 1970s in developed capitalist countries. European Journal of
Political Research 12:171-90.
Paque, K.-H. 1996. Why the 1950s and not the 1920s? Olsonian and
non-Olsonian interpretations of two decades of German economic history.
In Economic growth in Europe since 1945, edited by N. Crafts and G.
Toniolo. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 95-106.
Quiggen, J. 1992. Testing the implications of the Olson hypothesis.
Economica 59:261-77.
Rajan, R. G., and L. Zingales. 2003. The great reversals: The
politics of financial development in the twentieth century. Journal of
Financial Economics 69: 5-50.
Rasch, B. E., and R. J. Sorensen. 1986. Organizational behavior and
economic growth: A Norwegian perspective. Scandinavian Political Studies
9:51-63.
Rosser, J. B. 2007. The rise and decline of Mancur Olson's
view of The Rise and Decline of Nations. Southern Economic Journal
74:4-17.
Scruggs, L. 2001. The politics of growth revisited. Journal of
Polities 63:120-40.
Tang, E. W. Y., and A. R. Hedley. 1998. Distributional coalitions,
state strength, and economic growth: Toward a comprehensive theory of
economic development. Public Choice 96:295-323.
van Zanden, L., and A. van Riel. 2004. The strictures of
inheritance: The Dutch economy in the nineteenth century. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Vedder, R., and L. Galloway. 1986. Rent seeking, distributional
coalitions, taxes, relative prices and growth. Public Choice 51:93-100.
Waldow, K. H. 1993. The rise and decline of the saltern:
Rent-seeking at its best. Journal of European Economic History
22:581-64.
Wallis, J. J., and W. E. Oates. 1988. Does economic sclerosis set
in with age? An empirical study of the Olson hypothesis. Kyklos
41:397-417.
Weede, E. 1984. Democracy, creeping socialism, and ideological
socialism in rent-seeking societies. Public Choice 44:349-66.
Weede, E. 1986a. Rent seeking, military participation, and economic
performance in LDCs. Journal of Conflict Resolution 30:291-314.
Weede, E. 1986b. Sectoral reallocation, distributional coalitions
and the welfare-state as determinants of economic- growth rates in
industrialized democracies. European Journal of Political Research
14:501-19.
Weyland, K. 1996. Obstacles to social reform in Brazil's new
democracy. Comparative Politics 29:1-22.
Whaples, R. 2003. If I had a hammer: Mancur Olson as an economic
historian. In Collective choice, edited by J. C. Heckelman and D.
Coates. Berlin: Springer-Verlag, pp. 143-61.
Whitely, P. F. 1983. The political economy of economic growth.
European Journal of Political Research 11:197-213.
(1) The Logic of Collective Action is often incorrectly asserted to
be Olson's first book. Olson had previously published The Economics
of the Wartime Shortage two years earlier on a completely unrelated
subject. This first book has received almost no attention, and after the
success of Logic, Olson moved away from his earliest work in traditional
economic history (Olson and Harris 1959; Olson 1962) to focus on
political economy, although he often applied his theories to historical
economic development (Whaples 2003).
(2) The full listing of all nine implications are presented in
Rosser's paper in this issue (Rosser 2007).
(3) For example, Maitland (1985) tests Rise and Decline's
Implication 5 that "encompassing organizations have some incentive
to make the society in which they operate more prosperous, and an
incentive to redistribute income to their members with as little excess
burden as possible, and to cease such redistribution unless the amount
redistributed is substantial in relation to the social cost of the
redistribution" by comparing contributions by political action
committees.
(4) Goldsmith (1987) relied mainly on cross-tabs to evaluate the
impact of stability on growth in a larger sample of LDCs, but he also
mentions that regression analysis did not support a significant
relationship between changes in stability and changes in growth.
(5) The groups counts for these additional nations were compiled by
Murrell (1984) but not included in his study.
(6) This may perhaps bias the sample of reported studies in favor
of Rise and Decline since brief mentions are more likely to be
dismissive rather than supportive.
(7) For the survey, respondents were asked to rate their level of
support on a scale from 1 (strongly disagree) to 5 (strongly agree). On
the "size of government" statement, the average response from
economists was 3.83 versus 3.48 from political scientists. On the
"economies grow faster" statement, the averages were 2.53 for
economists and 2.39 for political scientists.
(8) See also Orchard and Stretton's (1997) critical appraisal of public choice analysis.
(9) Another approach often used to assess an accumulated body of
evidence is meta-analysis. This is normally limited to empirical studies and would ignore the vast number of case studies dedicated to
Olson's theory.
(10) Several of these appear in Public Choice. Although this
journal is aimed at being interdisciplinary, its methodology is that of
economics, and until this past year, the editors have always been
economists. The journal regularly appears on lists of economics journal
rankings. The same is true for the journal Kyklos. For the purposes
here, both are considered economics journals.
(11) The collected volumes included here were either dedicated
entirely to Rise and Decline (Mueller 1983) or a retrospective on
Olson's overall ideas (Heckelman and Coates 2003a). At the same
time, several of the studies in Table 1 also appeared in special issues
of a journal dedicated either to Rise and Decline or to Olson more
generally.
(12) The lone New Zealand author (McAloon) was lumped in with the
European group. American authors were considered separately or in
conjunction with Canadian authors.
(13) Given that Olson's own studies might not be considered
"independent" testing, a dummy for Olson was also created.
While this dummy was generally significant, its presence did not alter
the lack of significance for the other variables, nor did dropping the
Olson studies from the sample altogether. An alternative dummy that also
added former Olson colleagues and students (this includes studies by
Choi 1983, Wallis and Oates 1988, Knack and Keefer 1997, Heckelman 2000,
Knack 2003, Heckelman and Coates 2003b, and James 2003) was tried but
was never significant.
Jac C. Heckelman, Wake Forest University, 110 Carswell Hall,
Winston-Salem, NC 27109 USA: E-mail Jac_C_Heckelman@ mta.wfu.edu.
Table 1. Empirical and Descriptive Tests of Institutional Sclerosis
Cross-Section Regressions Sample
Olson (1982) (cd) U.S. states
Choi (1983) (cd) 18 OECD nations
Whitely (1983) (be) 19 OECD nations
Weede (1984) (ae) 19 OECD nations
Lange and Garrett (1985) (bd) 15 OECD nations
Landau (1985) (ad) 16 OECD nations
Weede (1986a) (be) 31 LDCs
Weede (1986b) (be) 19 OECD nations
Bernholz (1986) (ae) 17 OECD nations
Vedder and Gallaway (1986) (ad) U.S. states
Lane and Ersson (1986) (be) 24 OECD nations
McCallum and Blais (1987) (af) 17 OECD nations
Chan (1987) (bd) 13 Asian-Pacific nations
Goldsmith (1987) (bd) 77 LDCs
Nardinelli, Wallace, and Warner U.S. states
(1987) (ad)
Nardinelli, Wallace, and Warner U.S. states
(1988) (ad)
Wallis and Oates (1988) (ad) U.S. states
Gray and Lowery (1988) (bd) U.S. states
Garand (1992) (bd) U.S. states
Knack and Keefer (1997) (ad) 29 market economies
Tang and Hedley (1998) (ad) 8 Asian-Pacific and 12
Latin American nations
Crain and Lee (1999) (ad) U.S. states
Heckelman (2000) (ad) 42 nations
Scruggs (2001) (bd) 16 OECD nations
Coates and Heckelman 22 OECD nations
(2003a) (cd)
Knack (2003) (ae) 38 nations
Koubi (2005) (bd) 114 nations
Kang and Meernik (2005) (bd) Unspecified
Cross-Section Regressions Sclerosis Measure(s)
Olson (1982) (cd) State age/postconfederacy;
unionization rate
Choi (1983) (cd) Years since consolidation of
modernizing leaderships; years
since consolidation following a
logistic time path adjusted
downward for occupation by foreign
forces, indigenous totalitarian
government control, defeat during
major wars, and revolutions
Whitely (1983) (be) Age of the present democratic
constitution
Weede (1984) (ae) Years of uninterrupted democracy
within unchanged borders
Lange and Garrett (1985) (bd) Additive index of percentage of
unionization and centralization
of unions into peak associations
Landau (1985) (ad) Years since foreign occupation,
independence, violent revolution,
or civil war
Weede (1986a) (be) Index of price distortions
Weede (1986b) (be) Years of uninterrupted democracy
within unchanged borders
Bernholz (1986) (ae) Years of uninterrupted full
democracy
Vedder and Gallaway (1986) (ad) State age; dummy for south civil
war; union membership; average
level of AFDC benefits;
percentage receiving AFDC
benefits; change in revenue
from (separately) personal
individual income taxes,
corporate taxes, sales taxes
Lane and Ersson (1986) (be) Choi's (1983) index; trade union
organization
McCallum and Blais (1987) (af) Choi's (1983) index; number of
sectional groups; unionization
rate
Chan (1987) (bd) Scaled index of military deaths from
civil war and Japanese occupation
forces
Goldsmith (1987) (bd) Normalized index of. assassinations,
irregular executive transfers,
armed attacks, deaths from
domestic political violence
Nardinelli, Wallace, and Warner State age/postconfederacy
(1987) (ad)
Nardinelli, Wallace, and Warner State age/postconfederacy/end of
(1988) (ad) Jim Crow laws
Wallis and Oates (1988) (ad) State age/postconfederacy
Gray and Lowery (1988) (bd) State age/postconfederacy;
unionization rate; number of
unions relative to business
organizations; number of unions
relative to government size
Garand (1992) (bd) State age
Knack and Keefer (1997) (ad) Mean number of groups per respondent
Tang and Hedley (1998) (ad) Year of last turmoil (involving 1000
battle deaths from internal war
not involving border dispute,
independence from colonial rule,
or beginning year of consolidation
of modernizing leadership);
percentage of land concentration;
union membership; working days
lost due to industrial disputes;
percentage urban
Crain and Lee (1999) (ad) Business association revenue share
of income; business association
revenue per capita; number of
business associations; union
membership
Heckelman (2000) (ad) Sectional groups per capita
Scruggs (2001) (bd) Labor organization
Coates and Heckelman Sectional groups per capita;
(2003a) (cd) sectional groups per capita
relative to size of government
Knack (2003) (ae) Mean number of groups per respondent
Koubi (2005) (bd) Severity, duration, intensity of war
Kang and Meernik (2005) (bd) Standardized index of length and per
capita deaths from civil wars
Cross-Section Regressions Author's Conclusion
Olson (1982) (cd) Support
Choi (1983) (cd) Support
Whitely (1983) (be) Support
Weede (1984) (ae) Support
Lange and Garrett (1985) (bd) Mixed support
Landau (1985) (ad) Mixed support
Weede (1986a) (be) Support
Weede (1986b) (be) Support
Bernholz (1986) (ae) Support
Vedder and Gallaway (1986) (ad) Support
Lane and Ersson (1986) (be) Support
McCallum and Blais (1987) (af) Support
Chan (1987) (bd) Support
Goldsmith (1987) (bd) Does not support
Nardinelli, Wallace, and Warner Does not support
(1987) (ad)
Nardinelli, Wallace, and Warner Does not support
(1988) (ad)
Wallis and Oates (1988) (ad) Does not support
Gray and Lowery (1988) (bd) Does not support
Garand (1992) (bd) Mixed support
Knack and Keefer (1997) (ad) Does not support
Tang and Hedley (1998) (ad) Support
Crain and Lee (1999) (ad) Support
Heckelman (2000) (ad) Mixed support
Scruggs (2001) (bd) Support
Coates and Heckelman Support
(2003a) (cd)
Knack (2003) (ae) Does not support
Koubi (2005) (bd) Support
Kang and Meernik (2005) (bd) Does not support
Author's
Case Studies Focus Conclusion
Olson (1982) (cd) Allied and Axis Support
nations,
India, China,
South Africa
Olson (1983) (ad) U.S. southern Mixed support
states
Asselain and Morrison France Mixed support
(1983) (ce)
Hennart (1983) (cd) France Support
Lehner (1983) (ce) Switzerland Mixed support
Olson (1984) (ad) Australia Support
Rasch and Sorensen (1986) (be) Norway Does not support
Gustafsson (1986) (be) Sweden Mixed support
Cameron (1988) (be) Germany, Japan, Does not support
Sweden,
France, Britain
Broadberry (1988) (ae) Britain Support
Olson (1990a) (cd) Sweden Support
Manzetti (1992) (bd) Argentina Support
Kirby (1992) (ae) Britain Support
Waldow (1993) (ae) Luneburg Support
Milner (1994) (cf) Sweden, Norway, Support
Finland,
Denmark
Weyland (1996) (bd) Brazil Support
O Grada and O'Rourke Ireland Mixed support
(1996) (ce)
Paque (1996) (ce) Germany Does not support
Booth, Melling, and West Germany, Does not support
Dartmann (1997) (ae) United Kingdom,
Sweden
Blankart (2001) (ae) Prussia/Germany Support
Hojman (2002) (ae) Chile Support
James (2003) (cd) Canada Support
van Zanden and van Riel Netherlands Mixed support
(2004) (ce)
Demir (2005) (bd) Turkey Support
McAloon (2006) (ag) New Zealand Mixed support
(a) Economics journal.
(b) Political science journal.
(c) Book or collected volume.
(d) United States.
(e) Europe.
(f) Canada.
(g) New Zealand.
Table 2. Summarized Evidence for Institutional Sclerosis Studies
Mixed Does Not
Total Support Support Support
All combined 53 30 (57%) 12 (23%) 11 (21%)
Methodology
Regression 28 16 (57%) 5 (18%) 7 (25%)
Case study 25 14 (56%) 7 (28%) 4 (16%)
Outlet
Economics journal 22 12 (55%) 5 (23%) 5 (23%)
Political science journal 18 10 (56%) 3 (17%) 5 (28%)
Book or collected volume 13 8 (62%) 4 (31%) 1 (8%)
Author location
North America (a) 32 19 (59%) 6 (19%) 7 (22%)
Europe (b) 21 11 (52%) 6 (29%) 4 (19%)
(a) Includes 29 from the United States and 3 from Canada.
(b) Includes 20 from Europe and 1 from New Zealand.