Equilibrium selection in an experimental macroeconomy.
Lei, Vivian ; Noussair, Charles N.
1. Introduction
One of the most influential literatures in economics is the theory
of growth (for surveys see Azariadis 1993; Barro and Sala-i-Martin 1995;
Romer 1996; Sala-i-Martin 2002). The basis of much of the literature is
the Ramsey (1928)/Cass (1965)/Koopmans (1965) growth model. In this
model the economy is assumed to behave like a benevolent social planner,
who chooses capital stock and consumption levels over an infinite time
horizon with the goal of maximizing the discounted utility of the
consumption stream. The principal result of the model is that
consumption and capital stock converge to unique optimal steady state
levels that are independent of the initial endowment and the utility
function of the social planner.
An implication of the model, therefore, is that different countries
would converge toward a common income level even if their initial
endowment of capital differed, provided that they have access to the
same production technology. Relatively poor countries would exhibit
higher growth rates than richer ones. These two predictions are testable
with field data. However, field studies have generally failed to support
the hypothesis of convergence toward a common income level (see Durlauf
and Quah 1999; Temple 1999; and Islam 2003 for surveys). Rather, the
data are more consistent with the alternative hypothesis of club
convergence (Baumol 1986), which postulates that a small number of
steady states exist, and that each country has a tendency to converge
toward one of them. (1) Such a framework can explain the observed
pattern over time of an increase in income differences between the
Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development countries and the
developing world, as well as a decrease in the differences within each
of the two groups.
The empirical support for club convergence has encouraged the
development of theoretical models with multiple equilibria. While some
countries may reach optimal equilibria, unfortunate countries might find
themselves in low-income equilibria, which are often labeled as poverty
traps. These countries are unable to reach a better equilibrium without
coordination. Originally due to Rosenstein-Rodan (1943), the insight
that the existence of multiple equilibria might provide an explanation
of international income differences has led to a literature that
considers a variety of growth models with multiple equilibria. For
example, Azariadis and Drazen (1990) construct an overlapping
generations model with two stable Pareto-rankable equilibria. In the
inferior equilibrium, no agent trades with members of other generations.
Murphy, Shleifer, and Vishny (1989) build a model with synergies between
industries. Each industry is profitable only if other industries are
operating and there are equilibria where all of the industries operate
and other, Pareto-dominated equilibria where none operate. Galor and
Zeira (1993) and Banerjee et al. (2001) show that inequality and
differential access to credit can keep an economy in a Pareto-dominated
equilibrium.
Recognizing whether or not an economy has multiple equilibria is
important, because policy prescriptions differ depending on whether an
economy is in an inferior equilibrium or whether it is in an equilibrium
that is unique. Unfortunately, it is generally not possible to identify
whether an economy has multiple equilibria (see Cooper 2005 for a
discussion of the empirical issues involved). The underlying parametric structure of economies is typically unobservable, and in economies with
multiple equilibria, the comparative statics are often ambiguous.
In this paper we take advantage of the fact that experimental
methods allow the underlying parameters of the economy to be observed
and manipulated, and we construct and study the behavior of dynamic
laboratory macroeconomies that are known to have multiple, locally
stable, Pareto-rankable stationary steady states. (2) As described in
section 3, each steady state corresponds to a stationary competitive
equilibrium, and therefore each steady state is a plausible attractor
for the economy. The structure of the economies is one for which
straightforward application of the Ramsey/Cass/Koopmans optimal growth
model, which assumes that a benevolent social planner guides economic
activity, makes a prediction that the economy will converge to the
optimal of the steady states. These predictions provide null hypotheses
about outcomes in our economies. However, another motivation of the
paper is exploratory. We look for patterns in the data that might be
characteristics of economies with multiple steady states, and that could
be helpful in distinguishing between single and multiple steady state
economies when the structure is unknown to the observer. While there is
no ex ante reason to expect a difference between single and multiple
steady state economies, there may be signatures in the economic data
that reveal a uniqueness or multiplicity property of the underlying
structure. This is potentially important because the right policy to
promote growth or efficiency may differ in the two situations.
Two questions are posed with regard to model predictions. The first
is whether or not a decentralized dynamic economy with multiple steady
states will reach one of the steady states. To facilitate consideration
of this question by allowing it to be interpreted within an existing
framework, we use an institutional structure employed in Lei and
Noussair (2002, hereafter LN), described in section 2, under which
economies exhibit convergence to their optimal steady state in cases
where the steady state is unique and stable. However, the situation
considered here is different in that in economies with multiple steady
states, a degree of coordination of actions and expectations is required
to reach one of the steady states. We observe that the economy typically
does operate at or very close to one of its steady states, and therefore
coordination does occur in our dynamic economy.
The second question is whether, given that the economy attains a
steady state, there exists any tendency to reach a steady state that is
Pareto-dominated. In other words, do the economies fall into their
poverty traps? Avoiding or exiting an inferior steady state involves a
different and possibly more demanding coordination task than merely
converging to some steady state. An ability of our economies to avoid
inferior steady states would suggest that such coordination could occur
in a natural way, even in economies with a decentralized structure such
as ours. On the other hand, if our economies exhibit a tendency to reach
inferior steady states, it illustrates that coordination problems are
potentially consequential in macroeconomies. Furthermore, a result that
the economy reaches inferior steady states is potentially useful for
future research because it would create an arena in which different
institutions could be introduced into the economy to identify those that
might allow an economy to recoordinate on a better steady state. Indeed,
we find that the economy often converges to a suboptimal steady state,
and will typically do so if the initial endowment of capital is
sufficiently low.
The exploratory analysis considers two topics. The first topic is
whether an economy with multiple steady states exhibits behavior that is
not characteristic of economies with a unique steady state. The
existence of such behaviors might provide clues to observers who do not
know the underlying parameters of the economy about whether or not the
economy has multiple steady states. We study this question by comparing
the patterns in our data with those observed by LN, who studied
economies with a unique optimal steady state, and we find some
suggestive evidence that economies with multiple steady states exhibit
larger fluctuations from one period to the next and are more susceptible
to severe downturns.
The second topic concerns the behavior of an economy with a similar
underlying parametric structure under an idealized institutional
arrangement. We consider the outcome when the economy is populated with
agents who have incentives to act as benevolent social planners. All
members of the economy possess full information about the structure of
the economy and have an identical incentive to maximize the overall
welfare of the economy. We explore the empirical patterns generated from
the decisions of these social planners. We observe that a social
planner, who faces no coordination problem, is not susceptible to
poverty traps. On the other hand, the absence of trade means that no
price information exists, making it difficult for the planner to
identify the optimal sequence of consumption and investment.
Of course, the inferences that we make are necessarily valid only
for the specific structure of our experimental economy, which, like all
economic models, is highly stylized. Economic experiments are subject to
the same critique as theoretical models in that, under a narrow
interpretation, our results apply only for economies with the precise
structure of our experimental environment. However, although theoretical
modeling describes the outcomes that are implied from assumptions on the
principles of behavior in an economy with a specific structure, the
results are used to advance conjectures and to create intuition about a
class of related environments, possibly including field economies. Later
research may show that a change in assumptions influences the
conclusions qualitatively. An analogous argument can be made with
experimental research. The extent that any conclusions that we find here
carry over to other economies must await further research. However, our
environment has no particular features of which we are aware that would
render it nongeneric.
2. The Economies
General Structure
The economies we study in our experiment can be approximated by an
economy with the following structure. A representative consumer in the
economy, who can also be thought of as a benevolent social planner, has
a lifetime utility as given in Equation 1,
[[infinity].summation over (t = 0)] [(1 + [rho]).sup -t]
U([Csub.t]), (1)
where [rho] is the discount rate, [C.sub.t] is the quantity of
consumption at time t, and U([C.sub.t]) is the utility of consumption.
The economy faces the resource constraint given in Equation 2,
[C.sub.t] + [K.sub.t] + 1 [less than or greater than] A *
F([K.sub.t]) + (1 - [delta])[K.sub.t], (2)
where [delta] is the depreciation rate, [K.sub.t] is the
economy's aggregate capital stock at the beginning of period t, and
A is an efficiency parameter on the production technology. The value of
A depends on the economy's capital stock. There exists a threshold
level of capital stock, above which A has the value [bar.A] and below
which it has the value < [bar.A]; that is,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3)
where [A.bar] and [bar.A] are low and high production technology
efficiency parameters, respectively, and [??] denotes the threshold
level of the aggregate capital stock. The threshold can be interpreted
as the existence of a positive externality in production, generated by
the aggregate quantity of capital stock in the economy. (3)
Decentralization
The economy described in Equations 1-3 can also describe the
aggregate structure of a decentralized economy. Suppose that each agent
has the utility of consumption given in Equation 4,
[[infinity].summation] t = 0] [(1 +
[rho]).sup.-t][u.sup.t]([c.sup.i.sub.t], [m.sup.i.sub.t]), (4)
where [u.sup.i] ([c.sup.i.sub.t], [m.sup.i.sub.t]) is the utility
of individual i for his consumption [c.sup.i.sub.t] and his holding of a
numeraire good [m.sup.i.sub.t]. Utility functions are quasi-linear so
that [u.sup.i] ([c.sup.i.sub.t], [m.sup.i.sub.t]), = [v.sup.i]
([c.sup.i.sub.t] + [m.sup.i.sub.t]. Here m is a good that cannot be
produced (it can be thought of as money that can be spent in period t to
yield utility). Agents may have a negative holding of m and we assume
that [[summation].sub.i][m.sup.i.sub.t] = 0, [for all]t. The functions
[v.sup.i] ([c.sup.i.sub.t]) are such that
[[summation].sub.i][[dv.sup.i](c.sup.i.sub.t])/ d[c.sup.i.sub.t]].sup.1]
= [dU(C.sup.1])/[[dC.sub.t].sup.-1]. That is, the sum of the individual
inverse demands in the decentralized economy yields the total market
inverse demand for consumption.
Each individual is endowed with a production function, A *
[f.sup.i](k.sup.i.sub.t]), which maps his individual capital stock into
output, and he faces the resource constraint
[c.sup.i.sub.t] + [k.sup.i.sub.t] + 1 [less than or equal to] A *
[f.sup.i]([k.sup.i.sub.t]) + (1 -[delta])[k.sup.i.sub.t] +
[d.sup.i.sub.t]. (5)
Here [d.sup.i.sub.t] is individual i's net purchase of output
in period t, and A exhibits the production externality described in
Equation 3. The threshold is reached when [K.sub.t] + 1 =
[[summation].sup.5.sub.1] [k.sup.i.sub.t] + 1 [greater than or less
than] [??], so that productivity is a function of the aggregate capital
stock holding. After committing to the production activity, the agent
can supplement or reduce his output level by exchanging some of his
output for [m.sup.i.sub.t]. Because the net quantity individual i
purchases is given by [d.sup.i.sub.t], the following constraint has to
hold:
[P.sub.t][d.sup.i.sub.t] = [-m.sup.i.sub.t], (6)
where [P.sub.t], is the price of output in the market in terms of
the numeraire. The functions [f.sup.i] ([k.sup.i.sub.t]) for each i are
chosen so that [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] when
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Parameters of the Experiment
The parameters of the experiment are given in Table 1. The actual
production functions used in the experiment were discrete, mapping
integers to integers, and were approximations to 7.88 *
[K.sup.0.5.sub.t] for [K.sub.t] < 31 and 16.771 * [K.sup.0.5 .sup.t]
for [K.sup.t], [greater than] 31. For instance, given 26 units of input,
the economy was able to produce 40 units of output. At 31 units, there
was a threshold at which production became more efficient. Both segments
of the production function, the range [K.sub.t] < 31 and the range
[K.sub.t] [greater than] 31, were quasi-concave. The aggregate utility
of consumption at time t was approximately U([C.sub.t]) = 400[C.sub.t] -
[2([C.sub.t]).sup.2]. It was expressed in terms of an experimental
currency, called "francs," which was converted to U.S. dollars
at the end of the experiment at a predetermined exchange rate. The
parameters A, [delta], and [rho] were always equal to the values
specified in Table 1.
The aggregate production capability and the value of consumption of
units were divided among the five agents populating the economy. The
economy-wide production capability, A * F([K.sub.t]), was allocated
among the five agents in the following manner. The marginal product of
the first unit of [K.sub.t] was allocated to agent 1, the marginal
product of the second unit of [K.sub.t] to agent 2, etc. For instance,
the marginal products of the first five units of [K.sub.t] in the
economy were 8, 3, 3, 2, and 2 units of output, respectively. Therefore,
with the first unit of [k.sup.i.sub.t], agent 1 could produce 8 units of
output, agents 2 and 3 could each produce 3 units, and agents 4 and 5
could each produce 2 units. (4) Furthermore, since the aggregate
production function consisted of two segments, the individual production
schedule contained two parts, one part associated with 7.88 *
[K.sup.0.5.sub.t] for [K.sub.t] < 31 and the other part reflecting
16.771 * [K.sup.0.5.sub.t] for [K.sub.t] [greater than] 31. The
individual production schedules were private information. In other
words, no agent knew any other agent's production capability. A
similar rule was applied to allocate the economy-wide valuation for
consumption among the five agents. The marginal utility of consumption
of agent i was thus a discrete approximation of
[v.sup.i]'([c.sup.i.sub.t]) = 396 + 4i - 20[c.sup.i.sub.t].
The experiment had two treatments, the High and Low Endowment
treatments. Under High Endowment, the initial level of capital stock
[K.sub.0] equaled 35, allocated in equal initial individual endowments
of seven units for each of the five members of the economy. Under Low
Endowment, each agent received an initial endowment of four units, for
an economy-wide total of 20. The economies under the Low Endowment
treatment, in which the initial endowment lies below the threshold of
31, may pose a more challenging coordination problem because capital
must be accumulated in a range of diminishing returns to production
between the initial level of capital stock and the threshold.
The Sessions
Each experimental session consisted of the following sequence of
events. Upon arrival at one of the sessions, subjects reviewed a
tutorial that lasted approximately 40 minutes on the use of the z-Tree
software (Fischbacher 2007), which was used to implement the market for
trading output. Afterwards the experimenter handed out and read the
instructions for the experiment.
Subjects then participated as agents in an economy where they made
a sequence of consumption, investment, purchase, and sale decisions over
a series of periods. A practice period, which did not count toward
subjects' final earnings, was also implemented to check
subjects' understanding of the material in the instructions. All of
the materials used in conducting the experiment are available from the
authors.
At the beginning of each period, production took place that
transformed each agent's current capital stock holding
[k.sup.i.sub.t] into output A * [f.sup.i] ([k.sup.i.sub.t]) Agents could
then trade output in a market with other members of the economy for a
period of two minutes. After the market closed, subjects were required
to decide how to allocate their current output between consumption,
[c.sup.i.sub.t], and capital stock, [k.sup.i.sub.t] + 1. The period
ended after this decision, and subjects were then asked to calculate
their period earnings. Each agent's period earnings equaled
[u.sup.i]([c.sup.i.sub.t], [m.sup.i.sub.t]) = [v.sup.i]([c.sup.i.sub.t])
+ [m.sup.i.sub.t], the utility of consumption and any profit gained from
trading on the market.
After each period ended, the experimenter circulated among subjects
to record the individual end-of-period capital stock, [k.sup.i.sub.t] +
1, and to calculate the aggregate capital stock, [K.sub.t] +
[[summation].sup.5.sub.1] + [k.sup.i.sub.t] + 1. The experimenter
announced publicly whether or not aggregate capital stock was above or
below the threshold level of 31. (5) The exact value of [K.sub.t+1] was
not announced. Along with this piece of public information, the
individual end-of-period capital stock, [k.sup.i.sub.t+1], and the
production schedule enabled a subject to determine how much output, A *
[f.sup.i] ([k.sup.i.sub.t+1]), would be available to him at the
beginning of period t + 1.
The market for trading output was computerized and followed
continuous double auction rules (Smith 1962). To facilitate trading on
the market, each agent was given a loan of 10,000 units of experimental
currency at the beginning of each period. The current loan for the
period had to be paid back at the end of each period. In other words,
the cash balance was always reinitialized to 10,000 at the beginning of
each period, but the net change in cash from the beginning to the end of
each period counted for or against individual earnings. An agent could
make a buy or a sell order at any point in time while the market was
operating. Each subject was allowed to buy or sell only one unit at a
time. Therefore an offer simply consisted of a price at which the agent
submitting the offer would like to purchase or sell. He could also
purchase or sell units of output by accepting offers made by other
agents. Purchases in the market decreased his cash balance, while sales
increased his cash balance.
The Infinite Horizon
A random ending rule was used to induce a decision situation
equivalent to an infinite time horizon with discounting. (6) Under the
assumption that subjects in the experiment are risk neutral in their
final monetary payment, a constant probability of 20% of the horizon
ending in each period is equivalent to an infinite horizon in which
[rho] = 0.25. A horizon is defined as the time interval that Equations
1-3 describe. The experimenter implemented the ending rule by rolling a
10-sided die at the end of each period to determine if the horizon would
end. If the die read number 1 or 2, the horizon ended immediately.
Otherwise the horizon continued.
The period of time defined by a horizon is typically distinct from
that defined by a session, the length of time a group of subjects
interacts in the laboratory. Each session was scheduled for three hours.
If the current horizon ended with more than a half hour remaining, a new
horizon was started with the initial endowment (20 under Low and 35
under High Endowment) in effect for the treatment. Restarting with the
same initial values after an exogenous random ending has no
distortionary effect on optimal decisions. If a horizon did not
terminate by the end of the third hour, it would be continued on another
evening. Subjects were free to return for that session and continue in
the same role at the point where they left off. If a subject was
unwilling or unable to return, a substitute would be recruited to
replace him. The earnings the substitute made would be awarded to the
original subject as well as to the substitute himself. This technique,
first applied in LN, preserved the incentive for subjects to make
optimal decisions, even when they would not be participating when the
economy was continued in the future session.
Fifteen sessions were conducted using the procedures described in
this section. One of the 15 sessions, MktH1b, was a continuation of a
previous session, MktH1a, with the same participants. The session was
continued on another evening because the session ended during a horizon.
Sessions were conducted at Purdue University and University of
Wisconsin-Milwaukee. Subjects were undergraduate students who were
recruited from introductory micro- or macroeconomics courses and were
inexperienced with any similar experiment. Individual subjects earned an
average of $38.80 per session. Information about the number of periods
and horizons in each session is contained in Table 2.
3. Models
In section 3.1 we derive the optimal steady state of the economy.
These define the values to which the variables in the economy would
converge if a benevolent social planner with full information about the
structure of the economy made all of the economy's consumption and
investment decisions. In section 3.2 we calculate an additional,
suboptimal, steady state of the economy. In the decentralized economy,
each of the two steady states corresponds to a stationary competitive
equilibrium.
Optimality
Suppose the economy behaves as if it is under the direction of a
benevolent social planner, who chooses [C.sub.1], ...,
[C.sub.[infinity]] to maximize Equation 1 subject to Equations 2, 3, and
the constraints that [C.sub.t], [K.sub.t] [greater than or equal to] 0.
We also require that [K.sub.t+1] [greater than] (1 - [delta])[K.sub.t]
(negative gross investment in a period is not possible). The
transversality condition
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (7)
is assumed to hold (in the experiment the condition is assured by
the ending rule we employ). The first-order conditions are
[U.sup.']([C.sub.t]) = [(1 + [rho]).sup.-1] [1 - [delta] + A *
[F.sup.']([K.sub.t] + 1)] [U.sup.']([C.sub.t] + 1), [for all]
t, (8)
and
[C.sub.t] + [K.sub.t] + 1 = A * F([K.sub.t]) + (1 -
[delta])[K.sub. t], [for all]t. (9)
An optimal steady state must satisfy [C.sub.t] = [C.sub.t+1] =
[C.sup.*] and [K.sub.t] = [K.sub.t +1] = [K.sup.*], for all t, and the
first-order necessary conditions in Equations 8 and 9. This implies that
[C.sup.*] = A * F([K.sup.*]) - [delta][K.sup.*], (10)
and
A * F' ([K.sup.*]) = [delta] + [rho]. (11)
For the parameters given in Table 1, if capital and consumption are
constrained to take on only integer quantities, there are three
solutions to Equations 10 and 11, two of which are stable. The stable
solutions occur at ([K.sup.*], [C.sup.*]) = (45, 68) and ([K.sup.**],
[C.sup.**]) = (9, 16). However, numerical simulations show that from any
initial level of capital stock [K.sub.0] (including [K.sub.0] = 9), the
optimal sequence of consumption and investment decisions converges to
([K.sup.*], [C.sup.*]) = (45, 68). (7) Thus, there is an optimal steady
state at ([K.sup.*.sub.spo], [C.sup.*.sub.spo]) = (45, 68). The
subscript spo (Social Planner Optimum) indicates the capital stock and
consumption levels in the optimal steady state.
Competitive Equilibrium
A rational expectations equilibrium for the decentralized economy
described above is a sequence of consumption quantities, capital stock
quantities, and prices ([C.sub.t], [K.sub.t], [P.sub.t]) for all periods
t, such that each individual is making optimal consumption and
investment decisions at each time t given present and future prices, and
such that [P.sub.t] clears the market for output. The rational
expectations equilibrium has two steady states. That is, there are two
profiles ([C.sup.*.sub.t], [K.sup.*.sub.t P*) that are constant over
time so that ([C.sup.*.sub.t], [K.sup.*.sub.t], [P.sup.*.sub.t]) =
([C.sup.*], [K.sup.*], [P.sup.*]). Each of these steady states thus can
be viewed as describing a stationary competitive equilibrium. These
correspond, albeit inexactly, to the values of [C.sub.t] and [K.sub.t]
that solve Equations 10 and 11. One of the equilibria is Pareto-optimal
and one is Pareto-inferior, with a lower level of consumption and
capital stock for each individual and for the economy as a whole.
[P.sup.*.sub.opt] = 118 is the price that supports the Pareto-optimal
equilibrium, and [P.sup.*.sub.inf]= 334 supports the Pareto-inferior
equilibrium. The equilibrium capital stock and consumption levels such
that [P.sup.*.sub.opt] clears the market occur at ([K.sup.*.sub.opt],
[C.sup.*.sub.opt]) = (45, 70). [P.sup.*.sub.inf] clears the market at
([K.sup.*.sub.inf], [C.sup.*.sub.inf]) = (9, 16). This Pareto-inferior
stationary competitive equilibrium can be interpreted as a poverty trap.
At the Pareto-optimal steady state, each agent consumes 14 units
per period for an economy-wide total of 70 units of consumption. In
equilibrium the capital stock is distributed among the agents in the
following manner: [[bar.k].sup.1] = 12, [[bar.k].sup.2] = 9,
[[bar.k].sup.3] = 6, [[bar.k].sup.4] = 8, and [[bar.k].sup.5] = 10,
where [[bar.k].sup.i] is the equilibrium capital holding of agent i,
yielding a total [[summation].sup.5.sub.1][[bar.k].sup.i] = 45. At the
Pareto-inferior equilibrium, agents 1-4 each consume 3 units, and agent
5 consumes 4 units per period for a total consumption of 16. The
allocation of capital stock in this equilibrium is [[bar.k].sup.1] = 1,
[[bar.k].sup.2] = 2, [[bar.k].sup.3] = 1, [[bar.k].sup.4] = 2, and
[[bar.k].sup.5] = 3 and yields a total equilibrium capital stock of 9
units. (8)
4. Results
Decentralized Economy
Figure 1 illustrates the movement of capital stock over time in
relation to several benchmarks. The optimal steady state level is
indicated as [K.sup.*.sub.opt], and the Pareto-inferior steady state is
indicated as [K.sup.*.sub.inf]. The threshold level of capital stock,
31, is also shown in the graph as [K.sub.threshold]. [K.sub.gold] is the
golden rule level of capital stock, which would result from the
decisions of a social planner who treats [rho] as equal to zero. Figure
I a shows the data for Low Endowment, and Figure lb contains the data
for High Endowment. Figures 2a and 2b illustrate the observed time
series of the realized utility of consumption, U([C.sub.t]), in relation
to the equilibrium levels. The figures also in essence show the patterns
of consumption over time because actual consumption quantities are
almost perfectly correlated with the realized utility of consumption.
Figures 3a and 3b show the time series of average output prices.
The figures suggest a great deal of stability in the Low Endowment
treatment. With the exception of session MktL4, capital stock in the
last horizon converges toward the Pareto-inferior equilibrium and shows
no tendency to approach any of the other potential attractors shown in
the graphs. (9) The time series of the utility of consumption shows a
similar strong tendency to converge to the poverty trap level. The price
of output in sessions MktL1-3 and MktL6 converges smoothly toward the
Pareto-inferior equilibrium in the last horizon. The price remains
rather low relative to the poverty trap level in sessions MktL4 and
MktL7, and somewhat too high in MktL5. Overall, however, the economy
under Low Endowment exhibits a strong tendency to converge to near its
poverty trap.
[FIGURE 1a OMITTED]
[FIGURE 1b OMITTED]
A different pattern is observed in the High Endowment data. Session
MktH1 has a tendency to converge to near the optimal steady state, and
the tendency grows stronger over the three horizons in which the group
participates. The other six sessions are characterized by a tendency to
converge toward the optimal steady state level, but with the economies
experiencing dips below the threshold level of capital at least once,
that lowers consumption, capital, and earnings greatly. These episodes
usually occur late in the sessions when participants have considerable
experience. This occurs, for example, in period 11 in the first horizon
of MktH3, period 4 of horizon 5 of MktH4, and period 8 of horizon 6 of
MktH6. When below the capital threshold, the economies tend to converge
toward the Pareto-inferior steady state. An over-accumulation of capital
stock in the following horizon tends to follow an episode of convergence
toward the poverty trap.
[FIGURE 2a OMITTED]
To evaluate in a more precise manner whether the economies converge
toward equilibrium values, we estimate the model
[Y.sub.jt] = [[beta].sub.1j] 1/t + [[beta].sub.2j] t - 1/t +
[[epsilon].sub.jt] (12)
where [Y.sub.jt] is the value of a variable of interest, such as
economy-wide consumption, capital stock level, or average transaction
price, in period t of a horizon in session j. The [[beta].sub.1j] terms
have a natural interpretation as the point of origin of the time series
in period 1 of session j, since in that period t = 1 and (t - 1)/t = 0.
This means that [[beta].sub.1j] has full weight and [[beta].sub.2j] has
zero weight. The [[beta].sub.2j] coefficient can be interpreted as the
point to which the time series is converging, since as t [right arrow]
[infinity], (t - 1)/t [right arrow] 1, and 1/t converges to zero. If
[[beta].sub.2j] is not significantly different from the predictions of a
theoretical model, we will say that the time series is converging to the
model's prediction for the dependent variable. If [[beta].sub.2j]
is closer to the prediction of a model than the corresponding
[[beta].sub.1j] term, we will say that the time series is converging
toward the prediction of the model. The regression model described above
is used to establish Result 1 below.
[FIGURE 2b OMITTED]
RESULT 1. The economies of the Low Endowment treatment converge
toward, and in many cases to, the Pareto-inferior steady state.
SUPPORT FOR RESULT 1. The data are reported in Table 3. Each
session is estimated separately, and the data from all horizons of a
session are used in each estimation. The dependent variables are the
level of consumption in the economy, the level of capital stock, and the
price of capital. The first pattern that is apparent in each of the
equations is that the estimate of [[beta].sub.2j] is closer to the
Pareto-inferior equilibrium than the corresponding [[beta].sub.1j] term
in a majority of instances. This occurs in only three of seven cases for
consumption [C.sub.t], but in six of seven for capital stock [K.sub.t],
and five of seven for prices [P.sub.t]. The second pattern is that many
of the [[beta].sub.2j] coefficients are not significantly different from
the Pareto-inferior equilibrium. This is the case for four of seven
cases for consumption [C.sub.t], in four of seven for capital stock
[K.sub.t], and five of seven for prices [P.sub.t]. The third pattern is
that the direction of convergence is consistent. Consumption and capital
stock converge from above, in that [[beta].sub.1j] > [[beta].sub.2j]
in six of seven cases for consumption and in six of seven cases for
capital stock.
[FIGURE 3a OMITTED]
The economies in the High Endowment treatment tend to converge in
the direction of the optimal steady state equilibrium. However, this
convergence is not as strong as the tendency of the economies of the Low
Endowment treatment to converge toward the poverty trap, and the High
Endowment treatment is characterized by occasional episodes of falling
below the threshold level of capital, and subsequent declines of capital
toward the poverty trap level.
[FIGURE 3b OMITTED]
RESULT 2. Under High Endowment, behavior is less consistent across
economies than under Low Endowment. Consistent with convergence to the
optimal steady state, the economies typically exhibit increasing
consumption and capital stock over time. Consumption tends to converge
toward the optimal steady state and capital stock converges toward high
levels, which are at times in excess of the optimal steady state level.
Six of seven economies fall below the threshold level of capital at
least once, and after an economy does so, it usually converges toward
the inferior steady state.
SUPPORT FOR RESULT 2. Figures 1-3 illustrate the heterogeneity of
capital stock, consumption, and pricing patterns between sessions. To
show that, unless they fall below the threshold and dip into the
inferior steady state, economies under the High Endowment have a
tendency to converge toward the optimal steady state, we adopt the
regression model of Equation 12. Table 4 displays the estimates for six
of seven sessions of the High Endowment treatment. (10) The estimate of
[[beta].sub.2j] is closer to the optimal equilibrium than the
corresponding [[beta].sub.1j] estimate in five of six cases for
consumption, [C.sub.t], but in only two of six for capital stock,
[K.sub.t]. Four of six prices, [P.sub.t], are moving toward optimal
equilibrium levels. There are, however, a few cases in which the
[[beta].sub.2j] coefficients are not significantly different from the
optimal steady state. This occurs in three of six [C.sub.t], one of six
[K.sub.t], and one of six [P.sub.t]. The direction of movement is
consistent in that consumption and capital stock increase over time so
that [[beta].sub.1j] < [[beta].sub.2j] in five of six cases for
consumption and in all six cases for capital stock. Nonetheless, the
capital stock in six of the seven sessions falls below the threshold in
at least one horizon. In five of these six cases, as can be observed in
Figures 1-3, the subsequent behavior of the economy within the same
horizon is characterized by movement of consumption and capital stock
toward the inferior steady state.
There is evidence of more variability in outcomes across economies
under the High Endowment treatment than under Low Endowment. In other
words, the initial endowment of capital is associated with not only the
overall level of income our economies achieve, but also the variance of
income. This phenomenon can be seen from Table 5, which shows the
normalized variances, [[sigma].sup.2]/[micro], of several of the
endogenous variables in the economy. The value of the variable in the
last period of each horizon is used as an observation, and the mean and
variance of these observations are calculated. Then, for each treatment,
the variance is divided by the mean. The normalized variances of
consumption, capital stock, prices, and the utility of consumption are
all at least 40% higher under High than under Low Endowment. This
indicates that, even when the different magnitudes of the variables
between treatments are taken into account, more variability exists under
High than under Low Endowment. As another test, we calculate the
normalized variances of consumption, capital stock, prices, and the
utility of consumption within each session (for this calculation we use
the value of the variables in the last period of each horizon within
each session as an observation). Mann-Whitney tests, employing each
session as an observation, indicate that the normalized variances of
consumption, utility, and prices are significantly different from each
other at the 10% level.
Our study was not designed to generate data for direct comparison
to any previous studies. However, a rough comparison of the data
obtained here from the High Endowment treatment can be made with the
data from economies with a similar institutional structure, but a unique
optimal steady state, using the data from the study of LN. Comparison of
the two data sets suggests some basic differences between the behavior
of economies with single and with multiple steady states. The
comparisons are only suggestive since the two data sets were not
constructed to be compared to each other and differ from each other in
terms of underlying parametric structure, such as the discount rate, the
scale of the quantities of consumption and capital stock, as well as the
production technology available. We focus on the High Endowment
treatment because we believe that the most interesting comparison is
between an economy whose parametric structure places it in danger of
falling below a threshold and into a poverty trap and one in which no
such danger exists. The differences are summarized as Conjecture 1.
CONJECTURE 1. Relative to an economy with a unique steady state,
the economies with a poverty trap appear to be characterized by (a)
greater heterogeneity in outcomes between economies with identical
initial conditions, (b) greater volatility, particularly in consumption,
from one period to the next, and (c) more large single-period declines
in consumption and capital stock.
BASIS FOR CONJECTURE 1. In support of part (a), we note that in the
data from the LN study, all of the economies converge toward the unique
optimal steady state. In the High Endowment treatment here, outcomes
vary across the economies, even within restarts of the economy with the
same agents. To support part (b), we compare the average percentage
change in aggregate consumption, capital stock, and utility of
consumption, as well as prices, from one period to the next, as
described by the expression [absolute value of ([Y.sub.t+1 -
[Y.sub.t])/[Y.sub.t]] X 100, between LN and the High Endowment treatment
of the current study. These average percentage changes are interpreted
as measures of volatility. The data for all periods where t [greater
than or equal to] 5 are used in the estimation and are shown in Table 6.
The values in the table are those from period 5 and later pooled across
all horizons and all sessions of the treatment. The table shows that the
volatilities of all variables are greater in the High Endowment
economies with multiple steady states than in LN's economics with a
unique steady state. Mann-Whitney rank sum tests, taking the average
volatility over one horizon as an observation, indicate that only the
volatility of consumption in the High Endowment treatment here is
significantly different from that in LN (p-value = 0.0311). Finally, to
support part (c), we count the number of drops in consumption of more
than 50% from one period to the next. There are eight such decreases in
consumption in 222 periods of the High Endowment treatment compared to
three in 198 periods in the LN study.
The differences between the behavior of aggregate variables in the
economies studied here and those that LN investigate are presumably due
to the existence of a coordination problem. The heterogeneity in
outcomes in the economies with multiple steady states reflects the fact
that some groups are more effective in coordinating on Pareto-optima
than others. The greater volatility from one period to the next appears
to have several different sources. Some is directly associated with
surpassing or falling below the threshold, which causes large changes in
capital stock and consumption. Some additional volatility appears to be
associated with unsuccessful attempts to coordinate, either when
individuals invest large amounts in an attempt to surmount the
threshold, or consume large amounts, perhaps in response to a failure of
one's own earlier investment or when they believe that they are not
affecting the probability of crossing the threshold. High consumption in
a particular period on the part of too many members of the economy
causes capital stock to fall below the threshold and precipitates most
of the large sudden decreases in consumption that occur in the multiple
steady state economies.
The overall efficiency of the economy U([C.sub.t]), the actual
earnings realized divided by the maximum possible earnings that could be
realized along the economy's optimal trajectory, is reported in
Table 7 for each session. The efficiency attained is considerably less
than along the optimal trajectory in both treatments, but lower under
Low Endowment, an average of 0.273, than under High Endowment, an
average of 0.762. In fact, with p-value = 0.0017, a Mann-Whitney
nonparametric test, using each session as an observation, rejects the
hypothesis that the overall efficiencies under the two endowment
treatments are equal.
Besides the suboptimal level of investment in the economies, there
are two other potential contributors to inefficiency in our experiment.
We call these production inefficiency and consumption inefficiency.
Production inefficiency is the percentage of output that is forgone
because of misallocation of capital among producers. The value of the
measure is greater than zero if it would be possible for the economy to
realize greater output by transferring a unit of capital from one agent
to another just before production takes place. Consumption inefficiency,
on the other hand, is the percentage of the maximum possible utility of
consumption that is foregone because units are consumed by individuals
other than those who have the highest marginal utility of consumption.
Table 8 reports the production efficiency, defined as 1 minus the
production inefficiency, and consumption efficiency, defined as 1 minus
the consumption inefficiency, in all sessions under both endowment
treatments. The numbers are averaged across periods, and the data are
pooled over all of the horizons that make up each session.
The production efficiency averages are nearly identical under Low
(0.946) and under High (0.949) Endowment. A Mann-Whitney rank-sum test,
using each session as an observation, confirms that production
efficiencies are not significantly different from each other under the
two endowment treatments (p-value = 0.7483). Consumption efficiency, on
the other hand, appears to be higher under Low (0.860) than under High
(0.769) Endowment. A Mann-Whitney rank-sum test rejects the hypothesis
that consumption efficiencies under the two treatments are the same at
the 5% level (p-value = 0.0476). The fact that consumption efficiency is
higher under Low than under High Endowment appears to reflect the better
convergence toward equilibrium and the more stable prices that accompany
this convergence under the Low Endowment treatment. This convergence and
the resulting stability of prices allow better consumption decisions
(which involve comparing the price of capital to the marginal utility of
consumption) than if the price is unstable.
We now consider general patterns in individual level investment
decisions. The first hypothesis is that an individual consumes a greater
share of his output at the end of the period, the more output he holds.
This is not an unambiguous prediction of the theoretical model, but a
statement that consumption is a "luxury" good, increasing more
rapidly than overall output as output increases. The second hypothesis
is that individuals consume less, the higher the price of capital. This
is a statement that the demand for the consumption good is downward
sloping. We estimate the following model:
[c.sub.it]/([c.sub.it] + [k.sub.i,t+1]) = [[alpha].sub.0] +
[[alpha].sub.1] ([c.sub.it] + [k.sub.i,t+1]) + [[alpha].sub.2][P.sub.t].
(13)
The hypotheses of the model are that [[alpha].sub.1] > 0 and
that [[alpha].sub.2] < 0. The results of the estimation are shown in
Table 9a for Low Endowment and Table 9b for High Endowment. The
estimates indicate that the [[alpha].sub.1] coefficient is positive and
significant at p < 0.01 for the pooled data from all of the sessions,
as well as in a majority (four of seven) of the individual sessions, of
the Low Endowment treatment. Here [[alpha].sub.2] is significantly
negative in the pooled data from all sessions for each treatment,
negative in sign for every session, and significantly negative for two
of the seven sessions in each treatment. Thus, there is some support for
the idea that consumption and investment decisions respond to income in
a simple, predictable manner, particularly in the Low Endowment
treatment. There is strong support for the idea that they respond to
prices.
Social Planner
Six more sessions were conducted in which groups of subjects were
placed in the role of Social Planners. These sessions are indicated as
the SP sessions in Table 2 and proceeded in the following manner. After
subjects arrived at the laboratory for the experiment, the instructions
were distributed to each of the five participants. The instructions
explained that the five subjects made up a committee that was given the
role of a social planner of an economy. They were required to choose as
a group the economy's level of consumption and investment over a
sequence of time periods, and their earnings for the experiment were
based on the value of the objective function that resulted from their
decisions. The experimenter read through the instructions, while
subjects were allowed to ask questions. The initial period was for
practice and did not count toward subject earnings.
As in the experiment with the decentralized economy described
earlier, there were two treatments, differing only in the initial level
of capital in the economy. Only one treatment was in effect in a given
session. In the Low Endowment treatment of SP, in effect in sessions
SpL1-SpL3, the economy began with 20 units of capital. In the High
Endowment treatment of SP, in effect in sessions SpH1-SpH3, the initial
capital stock level was 35. The values of the other parameters in the
Social Planner experiment were also identical to those in Table 1. The
production and utility functions were provided as public information to
all subjects. Each subject's earnings were proportional to the
value of the objective function (1) the group attained over the course
of their experimental session, so that the interaction between
participants was purely one of common interest. As in the decentralized
economies described earlier, the utility and production schedules
remained constant throughout the entire session.
A period within a session consisted of the following sequence of
events. At the beginning of each period t, production occurred,
transforming [K.sub.t] into output according to the production function
A * F([K.sub.t]). After production took place, each member of the
committee had two minutes to propose an allocation of the output between
consumption, [C.sub.t], and investment, [K.sub.t+1]. Their proposals
were restricted to those that satisfied (2) with equality for the
current level of capital stock, [K.sub.t]. Allocations could be made
only in integer quantities. [K.sub.t+1] would be available for
production in the subsequent period. After a two-minute time interval,
the proposals of four of the five members were collected and delivered
to the fifth member, who was designated as the spokesperson for the
committee for the current period. The spokesperson was then given one
minute to choose [C.sub.t] and [K.sub.t+1] on behalf of the whole group.
He was free to adopt one (or none) of the committee members'
proposals. After the minute had elapsed, the spokesperson informed the
experimenter of the official decision. The experimenter then recorded
[C.sub.t], [K.sub.t+1], and the realized utility of consumption
U([C.sub.t]) on the blackboard, so that all participants had full
information on how [C.sub.t] and [K.sub.t+1] evolved over time. The
payoff to each member of the committee in period t was equal to
U([C.sub.t]). The role of the spokesperson was rotated among the five
members from period to period.
The Social Planner data are reported here as a full information
benchmark. The Social Planner is not proposed as a competing institution
to the one described in section 2. Rather, the performance of the Social
Planner is intended to provide a measure of the complexity of the
environment by indicating the level of difficulty of the allocation
problem in the absence of a price system to coordinate the allocation.
There are four principal features making the decentralized and the
Social Planner economies noncomparable. The first is that under the
Social Planner system there is a total alignment of objectives of all
members of the committee directing the economy. In contrast, in the
decentralized economy each agent has his own private payoff and no
individual has an incentive to maximize social welfare. The second
feature is that the social planner has full information about the
structure of the economy, while in the decentralized economy each agent
knows only his own utility and production function. The third is that
under the Social Planner system, production is restricted to points
along the production possibility frontier. In other words, the
constraint (2) is always binding. Under the decentralized system, it is
possible for the economy to produce inside its frontier if units of
capital are not allocated optimally among producers. The fourth
difference is that, under the Social Planner system, all units are
automatically consumed for their highest possible value, whereas in the
decentralized economy, the agent who consumes the last unit may not be
the one who has the highest marginal valuation for it.
[FIGURE 4a OMITTED]
The differences listed above present clear advantages for the
social planner that place it in a less challenging environment to
achieve a high level of welfare than the decentralized economies.
Nevertheless, if the decentralized economy could achieve an outcome at
least as efficient as the social planner, it would signal that the
market system using prices is more than able to compensate for all of
the individual incentive misalignments and informational imperfections
in the economy. Differences between High and Low Endowment in realized
efficiency would give a measure of the relative difficulty of the two
optimization problems, even when losses due to coordination failure,
misaligned incentives, and production and consumption inefficiency are
removed. The outcomes from the Social Planner economies are summarized
in Result 3.
[FIGURE 4b OMITTED]
RESULT 3. The Social Planner reaches neither an optimal outcome nor
a steady state. There are two principal points to which the economies
converge. These are focal rather than equilibrium or optimal outcomes.
One attractor is the minimum capital stock level required to exceed the
threshold. The other attractor is the golden rule level of capital stock
and consumption, an outcome consistent with the Social Planners ignoring
the possibility that the economy will terminate. Efficiency is higher
when initial endowment is High than when it is Low.
SUPPORT FOR RESULT 3. The evolution of capital stock levels over
time in the Social Planner treatment is displayed in Figure 4. We first
consider the Low Endowment sessions. The capital stock level in session
SpL1 exhibits wide swings early in the horizon, and then stabilizes at
56, the golden rule level of capital stock, which generates the maximum
level of consumption of 70 (the level that would be optimal if agents
treated the discount rate p as equal to zero). In session SpL2, there is
a tendency for capital stock to track (though often to slightly exceed)
the threshold capital stock of 31. In the first four horizons of session
SpL3, capital stock converges to the threshold value of 31. In horizon 5
the economy overaccumulates its capital stock up to a level of 80.
Under High Endowment, the Social Planner exhibits similar
properties. In session Spill, there is a strong tendency for convergence
to the threshold capital stock level of 31. In session SpH2, the Social
Planner is converging to near the golden rule in the first two horizons.
During the last horizon, the economy's capital stock is near the
threshold level throughout, although slightly exceeding the minimum
needed to remain above the threshold. Session SpH3 shows a similar
pattern. Capital stock tends to be slightly above the threshold and is
close to the optimal steady state level in horizon 4. However, horizon 5
reverts to a level just above the threshold, indicating that the optimum
was not a powerful attractor.
The efficiency in each session of the Social Planner treatment is
shown in Table 7. It shows that average efficiency is 72% under Low
Endowment and 95.7% under High Endowment. Low Endowment appears to be a
more difficult optimization problem, even relative to its own optimal
trajectory. This inherent difficulty may be due to the fact that a
greater percentage of output must be invested (more consumption as a
percentage of output must be foregone) under Low than under High
Endowment. If agents are myopic and thus unaware that they benefit from
or unwilling to undertake a sacrifice in current consumption,
inefficiencies will arise. The difference between the parameters of the
two optimization problems is responsible for the nearly 24% difference
in efficiency between the Low and High Endowment Social Planner
treatments, as the structure and framing is identical in the two
treatments. This is almost 50% of the difference in efficiency in the
decentralized economies between the High and Low Endowment conditions
and thus may account for some of the difference in outcomes between the
two treatments of the decentralized economies. In particular, when the
optimal trajectory involves accumulating capital, it may be less likely
to be attained than when it involves capital depletion.
5. Conclusion
The data in this study support the idea that a decentralized market
price system is effective in leading the economy to one of its steady
states. LN have already established that in a dynamic experimental
macroeconomy in which there is a unique steady state that is optimal,
the price system has excellent allocation properties, both
intertemporally as well as in allocating production between producers
and output among consumers (LN 2002). However, environments with
multiple equilibria appear to present a considerable challenge for the
price system in terms of leading the economy to a global optimum. The
simple price system of the sort we have constructed here gets the
economy to a steady state, a local optimum. However, it does not appear
very effective at getting an economy out of an inferior steady state and
into a better one, or at consistently avoiding an inferior steady state.
In our Low Endowment treatment in particular, the Pareto-inferior
equilibrium was a very powerful attractor for the economy.
The existence of multiple steady states gives this economy the
flavor of a coordination game, although obviously different equilibrium
concepts apply than in a normal form game. Experimental evidence
indicates that individuals will often select Pareto-dominated equilibria
(Cooper et al. 1990; Van Huyck, Battalio, and Beil 1990) in normal form
games. The authors of these studies, although they reduced the
interaction to a normal form game, motivated their research inquiry in
part with coordination issues in macroeconomics. In this paper we
consider parallel questions within the context of a laboratory
experiment with the actual structure of a canonical macroeconomic model.
We obtain similar results to the previous studies of coordination games,
in particular that inferior equilibria are frequently attained under
certain parametric structures. The results underscore the relevance of
the possibility of coordination failure in macroeconomics.
An extensive and well-known literature has been concerned with the
factors that influence economic growth. If the world is indeed one in
which basic economic principles apply so that economies operate close to
equilibrium, then an important empirical issue is to identify the
factors that might tend to lead a country to reach a better equilibrium.
The experimental data from our decentralized economy under the High
Endowment treatment illustrate that the mere heterogeneity of
individuals that populate markets can lead an economy to reach different
equilibria from identical initial conditions, and the tendency of this
population heterogeneity to do so depends on initial conditions. The
economies that converge to the poverty trap and those that find their
optimum have no difference in policies, institutions, or underlying
parametric structure. The differences in outcomes can only be due to
heterogeneity in the characteristics of the individual agents and in the
endogenous dynamics their interaction creates. Thus, the incomes of the
"countries" we have created in the High Endowment treatment
differed considerably from each other but not for any structural,
parametric, or institutional reason. We also obtain some suggestive
evidence that economies with multiple equilibria are more likely than
economies with a unique competitive equilibrium to be characterized by
instability of the variables in the economy, as well as sudden rapid
drops in capital and output.
A challenging institutional design question is posed by the data
from this experiment. In this very simple economy, even when the social
planner is endowed with the entire structure of the economy and has no
incentive problems, the social planner uses simple rules of thumb in
choosing consumption and investment sequences. The two outcomes we
observed predominantly in our Social Planner data were (1) the golden
rule level of consumption and (2) the minimum investment required to
realize the threshold externality. Since these outcomes do not generally
correspond to optimal behavior, their use may entail substantial
opportunity cost. The solution to the selection problem for the
decentralized economies may lie in the addition of a missing market, or
in a voting institution that facilitates coordination. We believe that
the issue of the design of the appropriate institutions to both avoid
and escape from a poverty trap is a tantalizing one for future research,
and economies of the type constructed here provide a simple arena in
which to study this issue.
We are grateful to the College of Letters and Science and Ccnter
for Research on International Economics at the University of
Wisconsin-Milwaukee for financial support. We thank Colin Camerer,
Katarina Kellar, Lutz Hendricks, Nazrul Islam, Tomomi Tanaka, Filip
Vesely, and two anonymous referees for helpful comments.
Received December 2004; accepted October 2006.
References
Azariadis, Costas. 1993. Intertemporal macroeconomics. Cambridge,
MA: Blackwell.
Azariadis, Costas, and Allan Drazen. 1990. Threshold externalities in economic development. Quarterly Journal of Economics 105:501-26.
Banerjee, Abhijit, Dilip Mookherjee, Kaivan Munshim, and Debraj
Ray. 2001. Inequality, control rights, and rent seeking: Sugar
cooperatives in Maharashtra. Journal of Political Economy 109:138-90.
Barro, Robert, and Xavier Sala-i-Martin. 1995. Economic growth. New
York: McGraw-Hill.
Baumol, William J. 1986. Productivity growth, convergence, and
welfare: What the long-run data show. American Economic Review
76:1072-85.
Camerer, Colin, and Keith Weigelt. 1993. Convergence in
experimental double auctions for stochastically lived assets. In The
double auction market: Institutions, theories, and evidence, edited by
D. Friedman and J. Rust. New York: Addison-Wesley, pp. 355-96.
Cass, David. 1965. Optimal growth in an aggregative model of
capital accumulation. Review of Economic Studies 32:233-40.
Cooper, Russell. 2005. Estimation and identification of structural
parameters in the presence of multiple equilibria. Eastern Economic
Journal 31: 1070-130.
Cooper, Russell, Douglas DeJong, Robert Forsythe, and Thomas Ross.
1990. Selection criteria in coordination games: Some experimental
results. American Economic Review 80:218-33.
Durlauf, Steven, and Danny Quah. 1999. The new empirics of economic
growth. In Handbook of macroeconomics, edited by John Taylor and Michael
Woodford. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, North-Holland, pp. 235-308.
Fischbacher. Urs. 2007. Z-Tree--Zurich Toolbox for Readymade
Economic Experiments. Experimental Economics 10:171-8.
Galor, Oded, and Joseph Zeira. 1993. Income distribution and
macroeconomics. Review of Economic Studies 60:35-52.
Islam, Nazrul. 2003. What have we learned from the convergence
debate? A review of the convergence literature. Journal of Economic
Surveys 17:309-62.
Koopmans, Tjalling C. 1965. On the concept of optimal economic
growth. Pontificiae Academiae Scientiarum Sceipta Varia 28:225-300.
Lei, Vivian, and Charles Noussair. 2002. An experimental test of an
optimal growth model. American Economic Review 92:549-70.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr. 1988. On the mechanics of development
planning. Journal of Monetary Economics 22:3-42. Marimon, Ramon, and
Shyam Sunder. 1993. Indeterminacy of equilibria in a hyperinflationary
world: Experimental evidence. Econometrica 61:1073-107.
Murphy, Kevin M., Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny. 1989.
Industrialization and the big push. Quarterly Journal of Economics
106:503-30.
Noussair, Charles N. 2003. Innovations in the development of
bundled-item auctions. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 100:10590-1.
Noussair. Charles N., and Kenneth Matheny. 2000. An experimental
study of decisions in dynamic optimization problems. Economic Theory
15:389-419.
Plott, Charles, and Glen George. 1992. Marshallian vs. Walrasian
stability in an experimental market. Economic Journal 102:437-60.
Ramsey, Frank P. 1928. A mathematical theory of saving. Economic
Journal 38:543-59.
Romer, David. 1996. Advanced macroeconomics. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Romer, Paul. 1986. Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal
of Political Economy 94:1002-37. Rosenstein-Rodan, Paul. 1943. Problems
of industrialization of eastern and southeastern Europe. Economic
Journal 53:202-11.
Sala-i-Martin, Xavier. 2002. 15 years of new growth economics: What
have we learnt? Journal Economia Chilena 5:5-15.
Smith, Vernon. 1962. An experimental study of competitive market
behavior. Journal of Political Economy 70:111-37. Temple, Jonathan.
1999. The new growth evidence. Journal of Economic Literature 37:112-56.
Van Boening, Mark, and Nathaniel Wilcox. 1996. Avoidable cost: Ride
a double auction roller coaster. American Economic Review 86:61-88.
Van Boening, Mark, and Nathaniel Wilcox. 2005. A limit of bilateral
contracting institutions. Economic Inquiry 43:840-54.
Van Huyck, John, Raymond Battalio, and Richard Beil. 1990. Tacit
coordination games, strategic uncertainty, and coordination failure.
American Economic Review 80:234-48.
(1) A property of the optimal growth model is that it implies that
growth rates will converge to zero. This is obviously inconsistent with
the empirical evidence. Endogenous growth models (see, e.g., Romer 1986
or Lucas 1988) generate permanent growth.
(2) There has been previous experimental research that is similar
to ours in spirit, in the sense that it uses experiments to consider
which of multiple equilibria is more likely to be reached. For example,
Marimon and Sunder (1993) explore an economy with multiple equilibrium
inflationary paths, depending on whether expectations are adaptive or
rational. A large literature has investigated normal form games with
Pareto-rankable equilibria (see, e.g., Cooper et al. 1990 or Van Huyck,
Battalio, and Bell 1990). Plott and George (1992) study one-period
markets with multiple competitive equilibria with a focus on the
appropriate concept of stability of equilibrium to predict market
outcomes. Our paper differs from previous studies in that our focus is
mainly on the impact of institutions on equilibrium selection.
(3) Van Boening and Wilcox (1996) study the behavior of double
auction markets in environments with non-convex production technologies.
They consider an environment in which sellers have a cost structure with
avoidable costs. They investigate environments with and without a
competitive equilibrium. They find that prices and quantities traded
vary erratically in all of their treatments, but particularly when there
is no competitive equilibrium. They devise a "bundled unit double
auction" to address the problem (Van Boening and Wilcox 2005). An
interesting issue for future research would be to consider which types
of market mechanisms can successfully and consistently select the
optimal from multiple Pareto-ranked competitive equilibria. The
literature on combinatorial auctions (see Noussair 2003 for a review)
considers the behavior of market mechanisms in environments with
non-convex buyer preferences rather than seller costs.
(4) To eliminate additional "nearby" steady states that
would arise from the rule used to allocate production capability among
agents, we slightly adjusted agent l's production schedule. After
the adjustment, agent 1 could produce 28 units of output rather than 29
with 6 units of [k.sup.i.sub.t]. With 8 units of [k.sup.i.sub.t], he
could produce 31 units rather than 32. These adjustments ensured that
the average marginal products of capital between the 5th and the 7th and
between the 7th and the 9th unit of [k.sup.i.sub.t] were equal to 3/2,
and the average marginal product of capital between the 9th and the 12th
unit of [k.sup.i.sub.t] was 4/3. Since the marginal product of each unit
of capital after the 12th unit of [k.sup.i.sub.t] equaled to 1, our
adjustments ensured that there was a unique equilibrium capital stock
holding, 12, for agent 1 in the region where [K.sub.t] [greater than]
31. The adjustments ensured that there was no unilateral deviation from
the steady state in the form of a multi-unit depletion or accumulation
of capital stock that was profitable.
(5) Individuals did not know the precise current level of aggregate
capital stock. It is possible, but not obvious, that this made the
coordination problem more difficult, because individuals might be more
willing to increase investment in situations in which they are aware
that the current level of economy-wide capital stock is close to the
threshold. On the other hand, a lack of information about current
capital stock may lead to more investment when the level is considerably
below the threshold, if individuals overestimate the investment needed.
(6) Other authors have used a similar rule to create the incentives
of infinite horizon models in the laboratory. See for example Camerer
and Weigelt (1993) or Noussair and Matheny (2000). Noussair and Matheny
explore the implications of the random ending rule in dynamic
optimization problems in detail. They compare decisions between a
setting with a random ending rule, such as that used here, and a fixed
ending rule in which capital could be redeemed for a fixed value at a
predetermined terminal period of the decision horizon. They did not find
any significant differences between investment and consumption levels in
the economies under the two ending rules.
(7) To calculate the optimal sequence of decisions given the
initial capital stock, we wrote a computer program to compare the
present discounted utility of all possible integer-valued decision
sequences. Under our Low Endowment parameters, where [K.sub.0] = 20, the
present discounted value of lifetime utility is maximized by increasing
capital stock by 11 units in period 1 to 31 units. In the next period,
it is optimal to increase capital by five units. The optimal time path
of aggregate capital stock under Low Endowment is [K.sub.1] = 31,
[K.sub.2] = 36, [K.sub.3] = 39, [K.sub.4] = 42, [K.sub.5] = [K.sub.6] =
[K.sub.7] = ... = 45. The optimal sequence of aggregate capital stock
holdings under High Endowment where [K.sub.0] = 35 is [K.sub.1] = 39,
[K.sub.2] = 42, [K.sub.3] = [K.sub.4] = ... = 45.
(8) Although the total capital stock in the Pareto-optimal
equilibrium of the decentralized economy is equal to that in the social
planner optimum, the equilibrium output level is two units higher in the
competitive equilibrium. The difference is a consequence of the rule we
used to allocate the aggregate production capability among the five
agents, which in the decentralized economy created a possibility of
reallocations of capital between agents that could increase total
output.
(9) The power of the Pareto-inferior steady state as an attractor
in the Low Endowment treatment is particularly evident in session MktL6.
Out of the first eight horizons, capital stock was above the threshold
level seven times. Nevertheless, despite this prior experience and the
resulting relatively high group earnings, in the last two horizons the
economy operated close to the inferior steady state.
(10) Only those horizons that did not experience a plunge to the
inferior steady state are included in the regression analysis. As a
result, Session MktH3 is excluded in the estimation.
Vivian Lei * and Charles N. Noussair ([dagger])
* Department of Economics, University of Wisconsin-Milwaukee,
Milwaukee, WI 53201, USA; E-mail vlei@uwm.edu; corresponding author.
([dagger]) Department of Economics, Faculty of Economics and
Business, Tilburg University, P.O. Box 90153, 5000 LE Tilburg, The
Netherlands; E-mail C.N.Noussair@uvt.nl.
Table 1. Parameters of the Experimental Economies
U([C.sub.t]): Economy-wide utility function 4000[C.sub.t] -
2[C.sup.2.sub.t]
F([K.sub.t]): Economy-wide production function [K.sup.0.5.sub.t]
A: Production-efficiency parameter [A.bar] = 7.88; if
[K.sub.t] < 31
[bar.A] = 16.771; if
[K.sub.t] [greater
than or equal to] 31
K: Threshold level of capital stock 31
[rho]: Discount rate 0.25
[delta]: Depreciation rate 1
[K.sub.0]: Initial capital stock 20 (Low Endowment) or
35 (High Endowment)
Table 2. The Sessions, Treatment in Effect, Number of Horizons, and
Horizon Lengths
Session Endowment Number of Horizons (Number of Periods within
Horizon)
MktL1 Low 1(7), 2(6)
MktL2 Low 1(5), 2(7), 3(7)
MktL3 Low 1(3), 2(1), 3(3), 4(1), 5(4), 6(9)
MktL4 Low 1(9), 2(9), 3(5), 4(2)
MktL5 Low 1(1), 2(1), 3(6), 4(1), 5(5), 6(22)
MktL6 Low 1(5), 2(4), 3(1), 4(1), 5(2), 6(1), 7(2), 8(4),
9(1), 10(9)
MktL7 Low 1(3), 2(2), 3(6), 4(1), 5(3), 6(5), 7(2), 8(18)
MktH1a High 1(19)
MktH1b High 1(7), 2(3), 3(17)
MktH2 High 1(1), 2(6), 3(4), 4(6)
MktH3 High 1(20)
MktH4 High 1(1), 2(1), 3(4), 4(3), 5(4), 6(1), 7(11), 8(6),
9(6)
MktH5 High 1(7), 2(2), 3(4), 4(6), 5(11), 6(8)
MktH6 High 1(2), 2(2), 3(4), 4(4), 5(1), 6(13), 7(5)
MktH7 High 1(8), 2(4), 3(4), 4(13), 5(6)
SpL1 Low 1(37)
SpL2 Low 1(2), 2(10), 3(3), 4(4), 5(1), 6(5)
SpL3 Low 1(3), 2(2), 3(8), 4(13), 5(4)
SpH1 High 1(1), 2(2), 3(3), 4(19)
SpH2 High 1(8), 2(3), 3(8), 4(4), 5(7)
SpH3 High 1(2), 2(8), 3(5), 4(7), 5(3)
Table 3. Estimates of Model of Convergence, Low Endowment,
All Horizons
MktL1 MktL2 MktL3
[[beta]. [[beta]. [[beta]. [[beta]. [[beta]. [[beta].
sub.1] sub.2] sub.1] sub.2] sub.1] sub.2]
[C.sub.t] 18.7 14.2 17.9 15.0 18.2 11.8
(4.3) (3.4) (3.5) (2.8) (3.0) (2.9)
[K.sub.t] 19.8 9.8 20.0 12.6 19.9 14.7 ***
(3.5) (2.7) (2.9) (2.3) (2.0) (2.1)
[P.sub.t] 581.3 336.9 356.6 346.6 393.2 346.0
(74.6) (62.3) (60.9) (51.6) (52.8) (52.4)
MktL4 MktL5 MktL6
[[beta]. [[beta]. [[beta]. [[beta]. [[beta]. [[beta].
sub.1] sub.2] sub.1] sub.2] sub.1] sub.2]
[C.sub.t] 18.5 9.0 *** 17.5 13.4 9.7 24.2 ***
(3.0) (2.4) (3.4) (1.8) (2.5) (2.5)
[K.sub.t] 20.2 12.8 ** 19.9 11.0 20.4 33.8 ***
(2.5) (1.9) (2.0) (1.6) (1.6) (1.7)
[P.sub.t] 232.3 200.6 *** 348.4 367.1 474.6 301.7
(52.8) (44.3) (60.6) (35.9) (43.1) (45.2)
MktL7
Pareto-
[[beta]. [[beta]. Inferior
sub.1] sub.2] Equili. N
[C.sub.t] 18.6 12.5 ** 16 174
(2.3) (1.8)
[K.sub.t] 19.9 7.0 9 223
(1.8) (1.5)
[P.sub.t] 107.7 225.3*** 334 172
(39.9) (36.2)
Standard errors are in parentheses. ***, **: significantly different
from Pareto-inferior equilibrium at 1% and 5% levels. respectively.
Table 4. Estimates of Model of Convergence,
High Endowment, All Horizons (a)
MktH1 MktH2
[beta. [beta. [beta. [beta.
sub.1] sub.2] sub.1] sub.2]
[C.sub.t] 53.0 66.2 * 58.8 48.9 ***
(5.1) (2.0) (5.4) (4.6)
[K.sub.t] 37.0 50.6 ** 33.9 48.7
(6.2) (2.9) (5.5) (6.4)
[P.sub.t] 134.5 115.2 141.6 160.7 **
(17.7) (13.6) (18.7) (19.4)
MktH4 MktH5
[beta. [beta. [beta. [beta.
sub.1] sub.2] sub.1] sub.2]
[C.sub.t] 52.4 63.1 45.5 72.5
(5.4) (4.6) (4.7) (3.9)
[K.sub.t] 33.8 60.6 *** 35.6 83.6 ***
(4.6) (6.3) (5.4) (5.5)
[P.sub.t] 115.6 153.5 * 184.4 157.6 **
(18.7) (19.4) (16.1) (17.1)
MktH6 MktH7
[beta. [beta. [beta. [beta.
sub.1] sub.2] sub.1] sub.2]
[C.sub.t] 52.6 61.3 * 38.1 65.0
(4.3) (5.1) (4.7) (3.9)
[K.sub.t] 35.4 58.1 * 34.0 109.5 ***
(4.5) (7.3) (5.4) (5.5)
[P.sub.t] 66.0 85.3 ** 68.3 77.7 ***
(14.7) (17.2) (16.1) (16.7)
Parcto-
Optimal
Equili. N
[C.sub.t] 70 138
[K.sub.t] 45 170
[P.sub.t] 118 138
Standard errors are in parentheses. ***, **, *: significantly
different from Pareto-optimal equilibrium at 1%. 5%, and 10%
levels, respectively.
(a) All horizons in which no plunges toward the Pareto-inferior
equilibrium occur.
Table 5. Normalized Variance in the Last Period, All Horizons
Low Endowment High Endowment
C 6.00 9.79
U(C) 1502.71 2126.44
K 8.27 12.54
P 44.84 77.09
Table 6. Average Volatility in Percent,
for t [greater than or equal to] 5
High Endowment LN (2002)
C 18.87 8.90
U(C) 14.97 8.17
K 11.41 9.54
P 15.10 8.55
Table 7. Overall Efficiency in Each Session, All Horizons
Decentralized Economy Social Planner
Session Low High Low High
1 0.305 0.935 0.935 0.966
2 0.317 0.747 0.592 0.957
3 0.240 0.548 0.634 0.948
4 0.264 0.736
5 0.260 0.827
6 0.256 0.758
7 0.268 0.785
Average 0.273 0.762 0.720 0.957
Table 8. Production and Consumption Efficiency in Each Session,
All Horizons
Production Efficiency Consumption Efficiency
Session Low High Low High
1 0.949 0.974 0.937 0.928
2 1.000 0.963 0.992 0.759
3 0.961 0.911 0.842 0.548
4 0.867 0.939 0.747 0.715
5 0.961 0.961 0.844 0.809
6 0.929 0.925 0.878 0.673
7 0.956 0.969 0.782 0.753
Average 0.946 0.949 0.860 0.769
Table 9a. Estimates of Individual Behavior, Low Endowment, All Horizons
MktL1 MktL2 MktL3 MktL4
[[alpha].sub.0] 0.47 *** 3.22 *** 0.85 * 0.57 ***
-0.09 -0.78 -0.5 -0.11
[[alpha].sub.1] 0.02 * -0.004 0.04 *** -0.0001
-0.01 -0.007 -0.01 -0.009
[[alpha].sub.2] -0.0001 -0.01 *** -0.002 -0.0004
-0.0001 (0.00) (0.001) (0.0004)
N 63 95 91 106
MktL5 MktL6 MktL7 All
[[alpha].sub.0] 0.70 * 0.79 *** 0.36 *** 0.45 ***
-0.41 -0.11 -0.05 -0.04
[[alpha].sub.1] 0.04 *** -0.0007 0.02 *** 0.02 ***
-0.01 -0.004 -0.01 -0.003
[[alpha].sub.2] -0.001 -0.001 *** -0.00008 -0.0003 ***
(0.001) (0.0002) (0.0002) (0.00008)
N 162 127 156 800
Standard errors are in parentheses. ***, **, *: significant at 1%, 5%,
and 10% levels, respectively.
Table 9b. Estimates of Individual Behavior, High Endowment, All Horizons
MktH1 MktH2 MktH3 MktH4
[[alpha].sub.0] 1.34 *** 0.61 *** 0.41 *** 0.59 ***
-0.13 -0.11 -0.50 -0.08
[[alpha].sub.1] -0.01 *** 0.004 0.009 ** 0.0003
0.00 -0.002 -0.005 -0.0003
[[alpha].sub.2] -0.01 *** -0.0008 -0.00008 -0.0002
0.00 -0.0006 -0.00004 -0.0003
N 230 80 100 159
MktH5 MktH6 MktH7 All
[[alpha].sub.0] 0.87 *** 0.51 *** 0.55 *** 0.61 ***
-0.05 -0.07 -0.07 -0.03
[[alpha].sub.1] -0.006 *** 0.004 -0.001 -0.0005
-0.001 -0.003 -0.002 -0.0008
[[alpha].sub.2] -0.001 *** -0.0004 -0.0006 -0.0005 ***
-0.0002 -0.0003 (0.0005) (0.0001)
N 184 147 172 1072
Standard errors are in parentheses. ***, **, *: significant at
1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.