The political, economic, and social aspects of Katrina.
Boettke, Peter ; Chamlee-Wright, Emily ; Gordon, Peter 等
1. Introduction
Disasters, whether man-made or natural, represent a "natural
experiment" for social scientists. As one business leader put it to
us on one of our first research trips in February 2006 to New Orleans after the storm, "Heck, I understand it is not every day that you
can flood a city of half a million people and see what happens."
The tragic dimensions of the event in terms of lives lost and lives
disrupted must never be forgotten, but the opportunity to learn about
the resiliency of social systems also must not be lost. (1) Natural
disasters are the social scientist's equivalent to tests done by
engineers to learn about the strength of materials and machines. Much
can be learned about the political economy of everyday life when we
examine behavior under conditions of great stress.
John Stuart Mill, in fact, argued in his Principles of Political
Economy that it is a surprising fact of life how robust free economies
are in the wake of devastation.
This perpetual consumption and reproduction of capital affords the
explanation of what has so often excited wonder, the great rapidity
with which countries recover from a state of devastation; the
disappearance, in a short time, of all traces of the mischiefs done
by earthquakes, floods, hurricanes, and the ravages of war. An
enemy lays waste a country by fire and sword, and destroys or
carries away nearly all the moveable wealth existing in it; all the
inhabitants are ruined, and yet, in a few years after, everything
is much as it was before (Mill 1848, pp. 74-5).
Mill argued that the possibility of rapid recovery mainly depends
on whether or not the country has suffered massive depopulation or not.
But there are other issues involved as well as the human capital
embodied in the population. The free flow of labor and capital seems to
be an important aspect, as well. In addition, the ability to quickly
reestablish clearly defined and enforced property rights seems to be a
characteristic in common with rapid recoveries from disaster. Jack
Hirshleifer (2002) in his essay "Disaster and Recovery" states
clearly that: "Historical experience suggests that recovery will
hinge upon the ability of government to maintain and restore property
rights together with a market system that will support the economic
division of labor."
Hurricane Katrina offers us some unique challenges. First is the
magnitude of the storm. Katrina was estimated early on to have caused
between $100 billion and $125 billion worth of damage (more than half of
that attributed to the New Orleans flood), whereas the costliest
hurricane to that date in U.S. history was Hurricane Andrew (1993),
which cost roughly $44 billion. The massive amount of debris generated
by the storm--some 100 million cubic yards, or 35 times the rubble
generated by the September 11 attacks in Manhattan--made simply cleaning
up the Gulf Coast a uniquely Herculean task.
Second, problems associated with the state of affairs before the
storm could contribute to nonresiliency. New Orleans, for example, was
not a particularly good environment for business before Katrina. (2) In
fact, it ranked at the bottom on various measures of economic freedom
and the costs of doing business. As a result, few major businesses were
located in the city. Only one Fortune 500 company, Entegry, is
headquartered in the city. Taxes and regulations did not attract
businesses. New Orleans was instead an economy dominated by politics and
political connections. There is a reason why New Orleans was often
portrayed as the stereotypical corrupt southern city. Historically, New
Orleans and Louisiana were in fact extremely politicized environments
with numerous high-profile examples of graft and corruption. (3)
In addition, the population in Orleans Parish was poor and
undereducated compared with national averages (e.g., median household
income was roughly $27,000, whereas the national average was $42,000,
and roughly 28% of families in New Orleans were living below the poverty
line, whereas the national rate was 12.4%). The population was
particularly vulnerable to the effect of the storm because, in some
areas of the parish, vehicle ownership was very low and the population
was old and ill.
Finally, factors involved in the devastation of Katrina highlight
how the folly of man compounds the fury of nature. Government-subsidized
flood insurance led to excessive construction in areas most vulnerable
to flooding. This was not just limited to the low-income areas, but also
occurred in some of the higher income areas that were also devastated by
the storm and do not get discussed as much in the national press. Also,
government responses to the storms (and previous ones) might have
impeded the commercial sector response that is necessary to reconnect
the social-economic networks that are characteristic of a vibrant social
system of exchange and production.
In the aftermath of Katrina, a research team was assembled by the
Mercatus Center at George Mason University to study the political,
economic, and social aspects of Katrina and to test Mill's
hypothesis about "rapid recovery." The basic idea behind the
project is that a social system of exchange and production is analogous
to a three-legged barstool. The first leg represents the
economic/financial institutions in place, the second leg represents the
political/ legal institutions in place, and the third leg represents the
social/cultural institutions in place. The idea is that unless all three
legs are strong and sturdy, when weight is put on the seat the stool
will tumble. The system, in other words, will not be "robust"
and nonrobust systems are almost by definition not particularly
resilient; thus, Mill's hypothesis of speedy recovery in the wake
of a crisis must be qualified.
We learned this lesson during our examinations of the difficult
post-Communist transitions during the 1990s and our studies of
developing economies in the early 2000s. (4) In short, politics,
economics, and society are embedded, and social scientists studying
transition and development problems are mistaken to focus on only one of
the factors to the exclusion of others if they hope to provide a full
understanding of the problems under investigation. (5) Post-Communist
transition was not as simple as just getting the prices right, and
solving the problem of underdevelopment is not just about getting the
right institutions. Of course, getting the right market prices and
establishing a rule of law are essential components to addressing these
problems, but simply stating that is not the same thing as addressing
that topic. (6) It is our conjecture that tackling the problems of
transition and development cannot proceed as if the economy, polity, and
society are disembodied from one another and thus that the problems are
technical in nature (analogous to engineering problems). Instead, in
dealing with social systems, the technical problems of economic life
find their solution within political and social "ecology" that
cannot be ignored if progress in the behavioral and social sciences is
going to be made on the questions of social change. (7)
The circumstances in a postdisaster situation, we conjecture, are
similar to those of the problems of transition and underdevelopment. As
Hirshleifer (2002) argues, "the subject of disaster and recovery
can be regarded as a special case within the general problem of economic
development." We follow him in that regard, and our research
project was designed to reflect that.
In what follows, we report some of our preliminary findings from
the project. In section 2 we look at the political/legal dimensions of
Katrina and its aftermath, with a particular focus on the Federal
Emergency Management Agency (FEMA) and the difficulties of government
planning for disaster recovery and rebuilding. In section 3 we discuss
the social/cultural dimensions and focus on the social networks and the
signals that are required for these social networks to reform after
devastation. In section 4 we discuss the economic/financial dimensions
and focus on how cities rebound (or not) in the wake of crises. Finally,
we conclude with a discussion of what we have learned so far and where
we are going with future research on this topic.
2. The Political/Legal Dimension
As the events of August and September 2005 unfolded along the Gulf
Coast, it became evident that government failures at the local, state,
and national level were compounding the situation. In the aftermath of
the storm, the extent of government failures became a topic of
newspapers and talk shows. The confusion of relief efforts was soon
followed by reports of misappropriated funds; the Government
Accountability Office now reports that the cost of fraud and abuse in
rebuilding could top $2 billion. With the Hurricane Katrina debacle
raising questions about public corruption's effect on disaster
relief, corruption has once again become an important issue in American
politics. (8) In our work, we attempt to address this issue not by
analyzing the effect of corruption on disaster relief, but rather by
analyzing the effect of natural disaster relief on public sector
corruption (see Leeson and Sobel 2007). Consider Figure 1, which plots
the raw relationship between natural disasters and public sector
corruption in the United States
On the vertical axis, we measure average annual federal corruption
convictions per 100,000 residents (1990-1999) in each of the U.S.
states. On the horizontal axis, we measure the total number of natural
disasters that have struck each state (1953-2006). The relationship is
clearly positive. States that have been hit by more natural disasters
are more corrupt. This relationship points to an important potential
connection between natural disasters and public sector corruption.
Although it does not seem likely that natural disasters per se could
affect corruption, it is not unreasonable to think that the
FEMA-provided relief funds that attend natural disaster could. The
economic intuition here is straightforward and parallels the reasoning
in the economic development literature, which suggests that rich natural
resources (the "natural resource curse") and foreign aid could
appreciably increase public sector corruption in resource-rich and
aid-recipient countries.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Recent research by Djankov, Montalvo, and Reynal-Querol (2005);
Leite and Weidmann (1999); and Svensson (2000) demonstrates that
resource windfalls generated by natural resources and foreign aid set in
motion rent-seeking activities that can lead to poor economic
performance and increased concentration of political power. Ades and Di
Tella (1999) and Leite and Weidmann (1999) show that resource windfalls
from natural resources or aid also tend to increase public corruption.
Resource windfalls increase rents to those in charge of the new
resources. This raises the value of controlling windfall resources,
which in turn leads to a flurry of rent-seeking activities that are
partly manifested in the form of greater corruption.
Natural disaster relief creates resource windfalls in essentially
the same way that natural resources and foreign aid do. The president
declares a natural disaster and FEMA relief flows to the affected area
to aid those in need and reconstruct what the disaster destroyed,
creating a windfall. This windfall creates new opportunities for
political corruption.
FEMA relief is especially corrosive in terms of corruption because
of the chaotic atmosphere in which it is unavoidably deployed. In the
case of a major disaster, the combination of billions of dollars of
relief being dumped onto one location in only a short period of time,
along with the confused and difficult-to-monitor environment in which
these windfalls are dispensed, create incredible temptation for public
officials to abuse their positions of power by corruptly appropriating
relief funds. Disaster-created conditions also make it exceedingly
difficult for government, preoccupied with the havoc of the disaster
itself, to effectively oversee into whose hands relief is going and
whether these hands are legitimate or not. These factors make
disaster-related windfalls especially damaging to public sector
corruption.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Consider Figure 2, which explores our core hypothesis in the raw
data. (9) The vertical axis in this figure measures average annual
corruption-related convictions per 100,000 residents in the states
between 1990 and 1999. The horizontal axis measures average annual
FEMAprovided disaster relief in the states over the same period. As in
Figure 1, the relationship here is strong and positive. States that
receive more FEMA-provided disaster relief are more corrupt.
This relationship withstands the test of econometric interrogation.
After controlling for the standard determinants of public corruption
used in other studies, such as Glaeser and Saks (2006), as well as a
number of other potentially important variables that might influence the
level of corruption across the United States, including geography,
political institutions, and political history, FEMA-provided disaster
relief continues to produce a statistically and economically significant
increase in corruption in America.
Importantly, the effect of FEMA relief on corruption, we find, is
not due to reverse causality. One could imagine, for example, that more
corrupt states are capable of attracting more federal (disaster-related
and otherwise) funding in the first place, creating a positive
relationship between corruption and FEMA relief, but one that has
nothing to do with the latter leading to the former. To address this
econometrically, we instrument FEMA relief with private insurance claims
for natural disasters, which are the subject of political manipulation,
and find FEMA relief continues to be positively linked to increased
corruption.
Corruption not only hinders the effective management of disaster
relief; it also has long-term consequences for economic prosperity. More
corruption is associated with lower growth and investment, and states
that receive disaster relief often suffer from these effects.
When determining the best course of action, policymakers must
remember that increased corruption is an unintended consequence of
disaster relief. Increased oversight is unlikely to solve the problem of
corruption because of the circumstances surrounding disaster. The
time-sensitive nature of the disaster relief means that protocol will
take a backseat when disasters actually strike.
Policies that assume the federal government plays the primary role
in disaster response are the most susceptible to corruption. Total
elimination of public corruption generated by disaster relief will not
be possible so long as FEMA relief exists. Any plan to reform disaster
relief that intends to minimize corruption should recognize the role of
local actors, such as charities and businesses, and create space for
them to react in times of crisis. Policymakers should recognize the
consequences of disaster relief when dealing with urgent crises to make
sure that they do not hinder the long-term prosperity of a community.
The problem with disaster relief efforts is not just the incentive
that public officials face in the political game (see Sobel and Leeson
2006, 2007). Even if incentives were appropriately aligned so that
public officials wanted to allocate funds in the most effective way
possible, they would still need to know what the most effective way to
solve the problem at hand would be.
In other words, to successfully coordinate natural disaster relief,
the social system must solve Hayek's "knowledge problem"
at three critical information nodes: (i) identification of disaster,
(ii) determination of what relief is needed and who needs which relief
resources, and (iii) evaluation of ongoing relief efforts. We need to
know more about the comparative ability of government and the private
sector to do this. The market economy, with the incentives and
information generated by private property, relative prices, and profit
and loss accounting, tends to coordinate the actions of economic
decision makers in a manner in which the gains from trade are realized
and resources are allocated to their highest valued use. The information
used in the market economy is always contextual or, as Hayek (1945, p.
521) stressed, "knowledge of particular time and place." The
political process does not have access to that contextual knowledge, and
actors within the political context face different incentives than those
in the market. As a consequence, it should not be surprising that when
relief resources are allocated politically, the resulting allocation,
while "politically efficient" in the sense of maximizing the
political goals of government actors, is economically inefficient. Thus,
information problems are as severe for the public sector's response
to natural disaster as the incentive problems discussed above. These
dual obstacles, which political agents unavoidably confront when
attempting to manage natural disaster relief, should give pause to
arguments that would give government greater power to address the crisis
of natural disaster.
3. The Social/Cultural Dimensions
Since Katrina, federal, state, and local government officials have
debated what form government rebuilding assistance should take.
Meanwhile, private citizens in some communities have been successfully
executing their own redevelopment plans without the assistance of an
overarching government program. Church leaders, family members,
neighbors, nonprofit activists, and business owners have been deploying
the resources found within civil and commercial society to address the
devastation of the storm. We have examined the role social capital has
played in the post-Katrina recovery process and, in particular, how
social capital resources are being deployed to overcome the collective
action problem associated with postdisaster recovery (see Chamlee-Wright
2006a). The usual assumption is that large-scale government response
offers the only viable path toward successful recovery. In fact,
luminaries such as Thomas Schelling have argued that Katrina proves this
point. Schelling has said,
There is no market solution to New Orleans. It is essentially a
problem of coordinating expectations. If we all expect each other
to come back, we will. If we don't, we won't. But achieving this
coordination in the circumstances of New Orleans seems
impossible.... There are classes of problems that free markets
simply do not deal with well. If ever there was an example, the
rebuilding of New Orleans is it (Gosselin 2005).
And yet, communities such as those that surround the Mary Queen of
Vietnam (MQV) Catholic Church in New Orleans East make problematic the
bleak logic of the collective action problem as set out by Schelling.
Despite being told by city officials that his community would not be
allowed to rebuild, within weeks of the storm, Father Vien Nguyen of MQV
helped to organize crews of returning residents to assist one another,
particularly the elderly, in gutting and repairing homes. The early
return of large numbers of residents and the quick progress they made in
repairing their homes played a pivotal role in securing the return of
services from the power company Entergy. Father Vien:
[I]n order to justify [and] divert power out here, we must justify
that there are people here planning to receive it.... [Entergy]
needed paying customers.... I gave [them] pictures that we took of
our people in Mass, first Mass. First Mass was 300, second Mass was
800; third Mass we invited all the people from New Orleans, and we
had more than 2000. So I had those pictures to show him. He said,
'Those I get. But now we need a list [of people who have
returned].' And so we went and got what he asked. We called our
people to put their names down and their addresses.... So within
one week, I went back to Lafayette, we went back to his office; I
said, 'Well, the city has 500 petitioners.' So, the first week of
November, we had power. And we were the only people with power
(pets. comm.).
The successful return of the Vietnamese-American community in New
Orleans East, which represented much of the local business community,
enabled the return of non-Vietnamese residents as well. Thus, the
signaling effect generated by patterns of mutual assistance can help to
coordinate not only the expectations among people directly involved in
the exchange of services, but among unknown others as well.
Working from an extensive set of on-the-ground interviews, our
research team engaged in the qualitative analysis needed to understand
how some communities are successfully executing strategies for community
rebound, even in the absence of a large-scale government redevelopment
plan. We have identified four patterns by which residents and business
owners are creating and leveraging social capital assets in their
interactions with each other and other elements within civil society.
Our analysis concludes that government disaster response and
redevelopment policy should be crafted and executed in such a way that
it does not unduly inhibit civil society's ability to respond.
Although the signals emanating from civil and commercial society
are crucial to the recovery effort, these signals can be drowned out if
public policy distorts markets and the basic rules of the social order.
In another study, our social capital research team documents how
government assistance and development planning efforts can
unintentionally impede long-term recovery by retarding the swift return
of the social and economic systems that coordinate daily life (see
Chamlee-Wright 2006b). Government provision of goods and services long
after immediate needs have passed creates what one New Orleanian
referred to as a "FEMA economy," by which she means the
expansive and distortion effects of federal disaster relief on the local
economy, including its effects on local labor and housing markets.
Many businesses trying to reopen have found it difficult to attract
employees. Certainly this is in part because many people simply
haven't returned to the affected region. But the repeated extension
of unemployment benefits has exacerbated this problem. Furthermore, the
premium wages government relief agencies pay low-skilled workers crowds
out private employers from the labor market, stunting the speed of
recovery. For service-based companies, the labor shortages are
particularly daunting as they attempt to bring operations back on line.
As one business owner noted, "You're competing with FEMA,
you're competing with everybody. The contractors that are doing
debris pick up and stuff, they are paying big bucks. They are paying $12
[to $15] an hour to stand behind a truck with a little
['stop'] sign."
Redevelopment planning efforts are another source of signal
distortion as the basic rules of the game continue to shift under the
feet of residents and business owners hoping to return. To take but one
example, New Orleans is currently in its third discrete rebuilding
planning process since the storm. As each new planning process and the
commensurate rebuilding plan appear, residents are forced to change
their decisions about how and whether to rebuild. When a previously
announced plan is scrapped in favor of a new plan with different rules
for rebuilding, time is lost, progress made under the now-obsolete plan
is rendered useless, and residents are left wondering whether the next
plan will be "the one"--or just another aberration. These
multiple and varied signals that the city has sent to its residents have
left people making decisions about rebuilding without any consistent
knowledge of what and when policymakers will allow them to rebuild. This
in turn slows the rebuilding process and delays the recovery of key
commercial and civil society organizations and institutions. When
governments fail to establish the rules of the game for rebuilding, or
worse yet change the rules in mid-course, it becomes difficult for
victims to make vital decisions and get on with their lives.
Long-term relief efforts and large-scale recovery plans tend to
ignore the innate abilities of individuals, communities, and businesses
to use a variety of resources and sources of information to guide their
decisions about whether and how to rebuild. These decisions are not made
in isolation but, rather, depend substantially on the signals sent by
similarly situated people.
Recovery efforts guided by the signals that emerge from action on
the ground produce faster, more robust, and more sustainable
redevelopment than efforts stemming from a politically produced and
centrally executed recovery plan. Moreover, large-scale redevelopment
programs can overwhelm and obfuscate the signals created locally,
stalling and distorting the organic recovery that is crucial to
long-term sustainable development. The focus on the problem of signal
noise in the postcrisis situation that emerged in our work on the social
and cultural dimensions of recovery dovetails nicely with the work in
our political and legal research on the "knowledge problem"
that is confronted at each decision node in the public sector response
to crisis.
We argue that instead of top-down procedures of planning the
recovery, public policy can foster an environment that encourages
sustainable, organic recovery by
* providing quick, clear, and credible commitments about what goods
and services governments will provide and when;
* creating in advance alternative regulatory regimes specific to
postdisaster environments; and
* avoiding policies that distort local economies and hamper civil
society rebuilding.
Because policy mistakes can have serious retarding effects on
postdisaster rebuilding efforts, policymakers must understand the
systemic reasons why government help so often goes awry, why private
citizens with a stake in the outcome are best situated to lead their own
recovery, and how to craft policy responses in a way that keeps
"signal noise" to a minimum.
4. The Economic/Financial Dimensions
"Living cities" play a crucial role in the positive link
between economic freedom and prosperity. The first work we have engaged
in on the economic and financial dimensions address how commercial life
can lead a devastated city back to vibrancy (Ikeda and Gordon 2006).
There is no upper bound on the size of living cities, and they appear to
recover effectively from disasters. Cities and their suburban
hinterlands form in ways that accommodate entrepreneurial activities.
(10) At the other end of the spectrum there are declining cities that
are less likely to recover. We follow Glaeser and Gyourko (2005) in
arguing that government programs that help to sustain poverty can
establish a lower bound by transforming a declining city into what could
be termed a "welfare city." New Orleans has, in fact,
experienced this fate and consequently was ill-prepared to recover
quickly from a large-scale natural disaster.
Louisiana presents an "underperformance puzzle" because
its actual economic performance ranks below what is predicted (via
cross-sectional statistical models) by its low ranking on popular
indices of economic freedom (e.g., Huang, McCormick, and McQuillan 2004)
and the even lower ranking of the state's actual entrepreneurial
performance (Garrett and Wall 2006). In other words, although the
economic policy rankings already predict a low performance, the actual
economic performance is worse. We contend that this is because the
statistical methodology used in the creation of the indices does not
capture all of the relevant variables and does not pay sufficient
attention to the central role that cities play in this nexus, both as
the principal hosts of economic freedom and as engines of economic
growth. The explanation of the underperformance lies in the character of
Louisiana's primary economic engine, New Orleans, as a welfare city
instead of a modern living city. It does not incite innovation and
growth. Rather, it persists in a declining state, mostly propped up by
government programs, and it holds much of the rest of the region down
with it.
For instance, a common index of economic development is the
historical trend in population growth. Although we observe that at the
Metropolitan Statistical Area level (New Orleans--Metarie--Bogalusa)
population growth slowed dramatically between 1980 and 2000, averaging
1.5% per decade compared with an average growth rate per decade of 18.8%
between 1900 and 1960 and 14.5% between 1960 and 1980, these data and
rankings are revealing when placed in the context of relevant
comparative trends. The U.S. Commerce Department's Regional
Economic Information System includes the most detailed county-level
employment and population files for the United States. The South
outperforms the rest of the U.S., but the Orleans Parish and the
surrounding metro area perform worse. Although other areas of the South
are thriving, the New Orleans area has been declining as an economic
force.
However, our research team argues that with time and the right
institutions in place, New Orleans can re-emerge as a living,
entrepreneurial city. As a way forward, we have examined the concept of
"private neighborhoods," which enables local communities to
choose the thickness of their own rules, as one such enabling
institution. (11) At first the idea of entrusting local neighborhoods
with governance powers might sound radical and unrealistic. But as
Nelson (2005) points out, roughly half of all new housing built in the
U.S. in the 1980s and 1990s is governed by private neighborhood
associations (PNAs). He estimates that 52 million Americans live in such
housing arrangements. Moreover, with respect to the New Orleans case, we
have to recognize that the argument that large urban governments possess
economies of scale in providing public goods is unconvincing when we
consider the evidence on schooling and policing in the area before
Katrina. (12) The status quo is not working on a variety of measures of
economic performance and governance capabilities. Something has to
change. (13) Not only would the establishment of PNAs devolve governance
to the very local level, taking collective decision making out of the
hands of a notoriously corrupt political culture, but by establishing
stronger links within, and among, various surviving and newly
established neighborhoods, a network of PNAs would tend to promote the
emergence of networks of commercial and civic relationships that could
serve as the social infrastructure that would serve New Orleans, with or
without future natural disasters.
Our working hypothesis is that the region does not lack
entrepreneurial spirit; what is lacking is the directing of that
entrepreneurial spirit into wealth-creating activities. (14) That is a
function of the rules in which individuals find themselves playing the
economic game. Currently, the rules of the economic game are not
conducive to wealth creation; rather than a living and vibrant
entrepreneurial city, New Orleans is a declining city because of the
regulations and taxation that raise the costs of doing business and the
policies that subsidize counterproductive behaviors. Change the rules of
the game and with that the structure of payoffs for different behaviors;
if the rewards are greater for productive entrepreneurship than either
unproductive or destructive entrepreneurship, then New Orleans can be
transformed into a living city in which the commercial life is as
vibrant as the cultural life we associate with the city.
5. Conclusion
The Mercatus Center project on "Crisis and Response in the
Wake of Hurricane Katrina" is a five-year study that addresses the
political, economic, and social aspects of the storm and its aftermath.
We are exploring Mill's hypothesis about the rapidity with which
regions can come back from devastation. In so doing, we are hoping to
make progress in political economy on the issues of
"robustness" and "resiliency."
The evidence to date is mixed. On one hand, we have seen the
vibrancy of civil society in the wake of the crisis, the clumsiness of
governmental decision making, and the great initiative of both private
sector and public sector actors to get around the system to get things
done during the initial period of rescue and recovery, as well as during
the rebuilding phase. In his Memoirs of an Unregulated Economist, George
Stigler (1985, p. 61) recounts a story about how he as a young man
working during WWII was accused of holding the outrageous position that
the price system would be the best way to allocate resources during an
evacuation of New York City. As Stigler tells the story, he first
clarified that he had never advocated the use of the price system to the
U.S. government, but on second thought he should have. As he says, in
the wake of a bombing of New York City, any system of resource
allocation will be imperfect. But in the case of repeated bombings, the
price system will prove to be more resilient and guide the adjustments
quicker than any other system of resource allocation.
Crises of the magnitude of a bombing of New York City that require
evacuation will inevitably lead to grotesquely confused situations, but
"the market system's flexibility, adaptability and
resourcefulness in finding new ways to make money" will ensure that
the confused situation is as orderly as it could be.
This is what underlies Mill's hypothesis on the great rapidity
of recovery after devastation. The free flow of labor and capital and
the lure of profit guide this process of recovery. But if labor and
capital flows are restricted or profits are outlawed, the recovery
process will lag behind, and the affected area will linger in its
misery. The voluntary sector, as reflected in both the market economy
and civil society, possesses great resiliency, but not unlimited
resiliency. Adam Smith (1776, book V, chapter 5, pp. 49-50) pointed out
that,
... the natural effort of every individual to better his own
condition, when suffered to exert itself with freedom and security,
is so powerful a principle, that it is alone, and without any
assistance, not only capable of carrying on the society to wealth
and prosperity, but of surmounting a hundred impertinent
obstructions with which the folly of human laws too often encumbers
its operations; though the effect of these obstructions is always
more or less either to encroach upon its freedom, or to diminish
its security.
As our work to date suggests, unfortunately, many of the
governmental policies adopted to deal with the crisis and that guide the
rebuilding effort along the Gulf Coast have had the unintended and
undesirable consequence of slowing the process of recovery. It is not
just a matter of "a hundred impertinent obstructions," but an
intricate network of regulations and restrictions on economic life. A
behemoth bureaucracy has proven to be ineffective, whereas the pockets
of nimble entrepreneurial responses by actors across the region have
often been more effective in rebuilding lives, neighborhoods, and
communities. Rather than creating bureaucracies to deal with crises, as
a matter of public policy, there is a need for enabling entrepreneurship
in the economic and social dimensions.
Our research recognizes the interaction thesis that Pejovich (2003)
has argued explains the transaction costs of transitions. The economy,
polity, and society are interwoven with one another. We do not deny that
for many questions we can isolate and address technical issues in
economics, politics, and sociology. But when dealing with questions of
social change, we contend that a thorough understanding will only come
from examining the interaction and nested nature of the economy, polity,
and society in addition to the technical issues. Political and legal
structures determine relative payoffs for entrepreneurial behavior, and
a vibrant civil society enables individuals to realize gains from trade
from extended networks by allowing them to benefit from the strength of
weak ties, instead of relying exclusively on the strong ties of family
and friends. Social cooperation consistent with an ever-expanding
division of labor requires not only a legal system that clearly defines
and enforces property rights, and a political system that constrains
predation, but a set of cultural beliefs and attitudes that legitimate
the contractual society as opposed to the connection-based society. The
ability to realize the gains from trade among strangers has been a major
puzzle in political economy from the time of Adam Smith to today and is
at the core of our understanding of the developmental process in
economics. (15)
An intricate matrix of political, legal, economic, and social
institutions are required for individuals to realize the full extent of
the gains from trade in an economy. Olson (1996) argued that the
existence or absence of this matrix explained why some nations were rich
and others poor and why it was so difficult to transition from poor to
rich. As we have argued, our approach to the problem of the recovery of
a region in the wake of a natural disaster is to treat the problem as a
subset of the broader question of underdevelopment. Mill's
hypothesis about the speedy recovery of regions in the aftermath of war,
famine, hurricane, fire, etc., was predicated on the existence of
institutions that did not hinder the entrepreneurial spirit of
enterprise and the free flow of labor and capital into the affected
regions. Moreover, unproductive and destructive entrepreneurial
behaviors were discouraged and not rewarded. If not, Mill's
hypothesis about the rapid recovery in the wake of a crisis would be
hard, if not impossible, to maintain.
Present and future research in the Mercatus project is focusing on
the responses of civil society among immigrant populations in New
Orleans; comparative historical research on cases in the United States
and abroad on recovery after floods, earthquakes, fires, war, etc.;
detailed microeconomic analysis of insurance policy and its effect on
construction along the flood plain; electoral politics in the aftermath
of crises; and the nature of entrepreneurial development of cities, just
to name a few, are already scheduled and under way. Our goal is to learn
from the natural experiment of Hurricane Katrina and specifically to
learn about what constitutes a robust political economy and help to
solve the problems of economic development.
Daniel Rothschild at the Mercatus Center has been an invaluable
project manager and partner in the coordination of research since the
inception of our five-year project.
References
Ades, Alberto, and Rafael Di Tella. 1999. Rents, competition, and
corruption. American Economic Review 89:982-93.
Baumol, W. 1993. Entrepreneurship: Productive, unproductive, and
destructive. In Entrepreneurship, management and the structure of
payoffs. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, pp. 25-47.
Boettke, P. 1993. Why perestroika failed: The politics and
economics of socialist transformation. New York: Routledge.
Boettke, P., ed. 1994. The collapse of development planning. New
York: New York University Press.
Boettke, P. 2001. Calculation and coordination: Essays on socialism
and transitional political economy. New York: Routledge.
Boettke, P., and Christopher Coyne. 2003. Entrepreneurship and
development: Cause or consequence. Advances in Austrian Economics
6:67-87.
Boettke, P., Christopher Coyne, Peter T. Leeson, and Frederic
Sautet. 2005. The new comparative political economy. Review of Austrum
Economics 18:281-304.
Boettke, P., and Peter T, Leeson. 2004. Liberalism, socialism and
robust political economy. Journal of Markets & Morality 7:99-111.
Boettke, P., and Virgil Storr. 2002. Post classical political
economy. American Journal of Economics & Sociology 61:161-91.
Chamlee-Wright, E. 2006a. After the storm: Social capital
regrouping in the wake of Hurricane Katrina. Arlington, VA: Mercatus
Center at George Mason University Working Paper.
Chamlee-Wright, E. 2006b. The long road back: Signal noise and
rebuilding after Katrina. Arlington, VA: Mercatus Center at George Mason
University Working Paper.
Corporate Crime Reporter. 2004. "Public Corruption in the
United States" A Report Released by the Corporate Crime Reporter,
January 16, 2004, at the National Press Club, Washington DC. Accessed 20
August 2007. Available
http://www.corporatecrimereporter.com/corruptreport.pdf.
Djankov, Simeon, Jose Montalvo, and Marta Reynal-Querol. 2005. The
curse of aid. Working paper, Universitat Pompeu Fabra.
Garrett, T., and Howard Wall. 2006. Creating a policy environment
for entrepreneurs. The CATO Journal 26:525-52.
Glaeser, E., and Joseph Gyourko. 2005. Urban decline and durable
housing. Journal of Political Economy 113:345-75.
Glaeser, Edward, and Raven Saks. 2006, Corruption in America.
Journal of Public Economics 90:1053-72.
Gosselin, P. 2005. On their own in battered New Orleans. Los
Angeles Times, 4 December (online). Accessed 31 July 2007. Available
http://www.latimes.com/news/nationworld/nation/la-na-orleansrisk4dec04.0, 7970585.full.story?coll=la-home-headlines.
Hayek. F. A. 1945. The use of knowledge in society. American
Economic Review 35:519-30.
Hirshleifer, Jack. 2002. Disaster and recovery. In The concise
encyclopedia of economics, edited by David Henderson. Accessed 16
February 2007. Available
http://www.econlib.org/LIBRARY/Enc/DisasterandRecovery.html.
Huang, Y., Robert McCormick, and Lawrence McQuillan. 2004. U.S.
economic freedom index: 2004 report. San Francisco: Pacific Research
Institute.
Ikeda, S., and Peter Gordon. 2006. The gales of creative
destruction. Arlington, VA: Mercatus Center at George Mason University
Working Paper.
Jacobs, J. 1985. Cities and the wealth of nations. New York:
Vintage.
Jones, E. 2006. Cultures merging. A historical and economic
critique of culture. Princeton, N J: Princeton University Press.
Leeson, Peter T., and Russell S. Sobel. 2007. Weathering
corruption. Arlington, VA: Mercatus Center at George Mason University
Working Paper, Mimeo.
Leite, Carlos, and Jens Weidmann. 1999. Does mother nature corrupt?
Natural resources, corruption, and economic growth. International
Monetary Fund (IMF) Working Paper 99/85.
Levy, David. 2002. Robust institutions. The Review of Austrian
Economics 15:131-42.
Mill, J. S. 1848. Principles of political economy. New York:
Augustus M. Kelley.
Nelson, R. 2005. Private neighborhoods and the transformation of
local government. Washington, DC: Urban Institute Press.
Olson. M. 1996. Big bills left on the sidewalk: Why some nations
are rich and others poor. Journal of Economic Perspectives 10:3-22.
Pejovich, S. 2003. Understanding the transaction costs of
transition: It's the culture stupid. Review of Austrian Economics
16:347-61.
Seabright, P. 2004. The company of strangers: A natural history of
economic life. Princeton, N J: Princeton University Press.
Smith, A. 1776. An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth
of nations. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Smith, V. 2003. Constructivist and ecological rationality. American
Economic Review 93:465-505.
Sobel, Russell S., and Peter T. Leeson. 2006. Government's
response to Hurricane Katrina: A public choice analysis. Public Choice
127:55-73.
Sobel, Russell S., and Peter T. Leeson. 2007. The use of knowledge
in natural disaster relief. Independent Review 11:519-32.
Stigler, George. 1985. Memoirs of an unregulated economist. New
York: Basic Books.
Svensson, Jakob. 2000. Foreign aid and rent seeking. Journal of
International Economics 51:437-61.
Wallis, J. 2004. The concept of systemic corruption in American
political and economic history. NBER Working Paper No. W10952.
(1) Robustness and resiliency as welfare criterion in assessing
political-economic systems moves the discussion from ideal allocative
efficiency within a clearly defined institutional structure to a focus
on the character of the institutional structure itself. For a discussion
of the implications for political economy of moving the analytical focus
from ideal efficiency to the robustness of institutions and the strategy
for doing so, see Levy (2002) and Boettke and Leeson (2004).
(2) In the Pacific Research Institute's Economic Freedom of
the States Index, Louisiana ranks 40th out of 50 states in terms of
economic freedom (see Huang, McCormick, and McQuillan 2004).
(3) According to one study published in 2004 ranking U.S. states by
measures of corruption, Louisiana was ranked the third most corrupt.
Mississippi was ranked the most corrupt (Corporate Crime Reporter 2004).
(4) The Mercatus Center's "Global Prosperity
Initiative" conducted a series of U.S. Agency for International
Development--sponsored forums on the role of institutions in economic
development analysis and sponsored field research in political economy
in countries such as Romania, the Czech Republic, Botswana, China, Costa
Rica, the Dominican Republic, and the Philippines. In addition, the
Mercatus Center has for the past three years been leading a research
project titled "Enterprise Africa," which examines private
sector initiatives at poverty alleviation. See www.mercatus.org for a
discussion of these various projects as well as the work on Katrina.
(5) Boettke and Storr (2002) developed this thesis of the
"triple embeddedness" of economy, society, and polity and
demonstrated its intellectual roots in 19th and early 20th century
writers (see also Boettke et al. 2005).
(6) See Boettke (1993, 2001) for an examination of the political
economy of post-communism. Boettke (1994) provides a critique of
development planning.
(7) This was the theme of Vernon Smith's Nobel address titled,
"Constructivist and Ecological Rationality" (see Smith 2003).
As Smith argues, even with respect to the theory of choice in economics,
mistakes in analysis are inevitable when the choice analysis fails to
specify the context of choice and instead attempts to analyze decisions
against some abstract standard of efficiency and rationality. Also see
Jones (2006), where he argues that culture matters to economic outcomes,
but that culture also never stops responding to market forces and is
thus constantly evolving--even if stubbornly. Pejovich (2003) refers to
this as the "'interaction thesis" and challenges
economists to deal with cultural constraints if they want to understand
the transaction costs of transition.
(8) For a thorough understanding of corruption and its effect on
political and economic life, see Wallis (2004). In this paper, Wallis
examines the concept of "systemic corruption," by which he
means the political manipulation of the economy by political actors in
order to secure "economic rents" that they can use to gain
control of the government.
(9) North Dakota did not fit on the scale and is therefore excluded
from Figure 2.
(10) On the relationship between the vibrancy of cities and the
wealth of nations, see Jacobs (1985).
(11) The concept of "private neighborhoods" and how they
have the power to transform local government is developed by Nelson
(2005).
(12) In 2003, for example, the murder rate in New Orleans was eight
times the national average.
(13) During one of our first field trips (February 2006), we spoke
with a youth minister who said that before Katrina, any discussion of
redevelopment would have led him to organize his youth groups to protest
the unwarranted intrusion of capitalism into his community. But after
Katrina, the initial reaction that New Orleans must be rebuilt to be
exactly where it was before the storm caused him and his colleagues to
question their previous position. To rebuild New Orleans as it was
(especially the center city where he worked) would entail accepting
substandard schooling, violent gangs, and drug addiction that destroyed
lives. No, he argued, New Orleans needs a fresh start to give the
families and youth in the city the opportunity to construct a meaningful
future. He argued that "redevelopment with justice" was what
was needed. It is not quite clear what all that would entail, but PNAs
might be a decentralized vehicle for the needed experimentation.
(14) Baumol (1993) argues that entrepreneurship can be directed in
productive, unproductive, and destructive directions because of
different rules of the game that determine the relative payoffs of types
of entrepreneurial behavior (see also Boettke and Coyne 2003).
(15) As Smith (1776, p. 18) put it: "In civilized society he
stands at all times in need of the cooperation and assistance of great
multitudes, while his whole life is scarce sufficient to gain the
friendship of a few persons." For a modern attempt to grapple with this central mystery of modern economic life, see Seabright (2004).
Peter Boettke, * Emily Chamlee-Wright, ([dagger]) Peter Gordon,
([double dagger]) Sanford Ikeda, ([section]) Peter T. Leeson,
([parallel]) and Russell Sobel (#)
* Department of Economics, George Mason University, MSN 3G4
Fairfax, VA 22030, USA; E-mail pboettke@gmu.edu; corresponding author.
([dagger]) Department of Economics, Beloit College, Campbell Hall,
700 College Street, Beloit, WI 53511, USA. ([double dagger]) School of
Public Policy, Planning, and Development, University of Southern
California, Los Angeles, CA 90089-0626, USA.
([section]) Department of Economics, Purchase College, State
University of New York, 735 Anderson Hill Road, Purchase, NY 10577, USA.
([parallel]) Department of Economics, West Virginia University,
Morgantown, WV 26506-6025, USA.
(#) Department of Economics, West Virginia University, Morgantown,
WV 26506-6025, USA.