Tax base elasticities: a multi-state analysis of long-run and short-run dynamics.
Tuttle, M.H.
1. Introduction
Generating sufficient revenue to finance government service
delivery is arguably the most important characteristic of state tax
systems because revenue collection is the primary purpose for most
taxation. Despite this obvious point, collections often remain in the
back seat of any economic analysis, with efficiency and equity
frequently receiving the most analytical attention. Revenue is
frequently introduced either as a constraint in maximization problems or
by assumption, while other aspects of the tax system are analyzed.
Further, the analyses are often static, meaning government revenue is
only considered in a single year, with no consideration given to the
dynamics of revenue performance.
The poor fiscal performance of most states from 2001 through 2003
has at least temporarily brought revenue issues to the forefront. States
have had difficulty in financing legislated budgets--or in some cases,
even maintaining past spending levels. (1) Unfortunately, the emphasis
of many political discussions has been on meeting current revenue goals
without considering whether the revenue system is structured to collect
sufficient revenue over the long term. (2) Much debate can be expected
during the next several years on the design of tax structures that can
best prevent recurrence of similar fiscal crises. A clear understanding
of the dynamic properties of revenue structures is necessary so that tax
structures can be adapted to ensure they generate appropriate revenue
growth in the future. (3) This paper fills this gap by analyzing the
factors that determine the dynamic performance of revenue systems. This
is achieved by estimating long-run and short-run income elasticities for
personal income taxes and general sales taxes for every state. Then, the
factors that explain the elasticity differences across states are
examined to discern the implications for tax policy.
The primary focus of this paper is on the income elasticities of
the two major tax sources relied upon by state governments, the sales
and the personal income taxes. Combined, these taxes generated 66.7% of
all state tax revenue in 2004.4 Reliance on these tax instruments varies
both over time and across states. In 2004, state sales taxes raised
between 14.5% of tax revenue in Vermont and 61.3% in Tennessee. (5) In
2004, state personal income taxes raised between 17.4% of revenue in
North Dakota and 70.0% in Oregon. Across all states, the income tax has
grown dramatically as a share of state tax revenue, rising from 17.3% in
1967 to 33.1% in 2004. The sales tax has also risen, although at a less
robust rate, growing from 28.6% of state tax revenue in 1967 to 33.6% in
2004.
State tax structures can be envisioned much like personal
portfolios. Revenue growth and volatility are parallels to the
risk-reward framework for the portfolio, but we have little information
on the way in which growth occurs. Current experience illustrates the
parallel, since many states have seen that an adequate long-term growth
rate is not necessarily sufficient to ensure that service delivery will
be properly financed on an annual basis. Further, depending upon the
particular economic environment, tax revenue growth may slow (or
accelerate) more radically than would appear consistent with long-run
relationships between personal income and revenue growth. Again, the
rapidity with which revenue growth slowed for the states during 2001
appeared to be radically different from the slow pace with which revenue
growth recovered in the 2003 to 2005 time period. Tax and financing
structures must be able to provide adequate revenues during the wide
array of different economic environments that may arise. Thus, this
paper not only investigates long-run elasticities but also estimates
short-run elasticities for every state and seeks to determine the
differences between the short- and long-run elasticities. Further, the
econometric specifications are designed to consider whether short-run
elasticities are asymmetric, since revenues may be more responsive in
certain economic environments. Based on this information, states can not
only enhance the design of their tax structures, but they can also use
careful resource planning, such as rainy day funds, to smooth
expenditures during downturns.
2. Literature Review
The literature on income elasticities and stability of state and
local taxes has a long history, though it is relatively sparse. In the
seminal paper in this literature, Groves and Kahn (1952) estimate state
and local revenue elasticities and recognize that elasticities need not
be constant over time. Fox and Campbell (1984) estimate the sales tax
elasticity for ten disaggregated taxable sales categories and find the
elasticities vary by sales category, average 0.59 over the long term,
and are widely variable on an annual basis. Variation occurs as the
income elasticity for taxable durable goods categories declines in
recessions and rises in expansions and moves in the opposition direction
for nondurable goods. Otsuka and Braun (1999) use a random coefficient model and generally confirm the Fox and Campbell results.
Dye and McGuire (1991) examine the elasticity and stability of both
the individual income and sales taxes. They conclude that the components
of both the income (by income class) and sales (by type of consumption)
tax structures vary significantly and that both flat and progressive
income taxes are likely to grow faster than either a broad or a
narrow-based sales tax.
Sobel and Holcombe (1996) build on the Dye and McGuire analysis
through the use of time series techniques and by examining more tax
instruments. A key limitation of both Dye and McGuire and Sobel and
Holcombe, however, is that their analyses rely on stylized rather than
actual tax structures. For example, Sobel and Holcombe proxy the sales
tax base with national total retail sales and nonfood retail sales.
However, retail sales differ dramatically from the sales tax bases
imposed by states. Several states exempt some retail purchases besides
food (such as gasoline and clothing), tax a varying number of services
and tax many business purchases. (6) Also, state income tax bases have
very different exemption and deduction structures and often exclude
certain forms of income. For example, pension income is exempt in many
states. Differences between the actual tax base used in a state and the
stylized tax bases seen by economists occur for many reasons, including
political, economic development, and administrative factors.
The rate structures also differ from those implicit in the analyses
of the earlier studies. Many states impose multiple sales tax rates and
complicated progressive income tax regimes. Thus, earlier research is
useful as exploratory steps, but fails to investigate how actual tax
structures respond to economic growth, how specific tax structure
characteristics alter the underlying elasticities, and how these
relationships change over time.
This paper extends the literature on state revenue elasticities in
three important ways. First, tax elasticities are estimated for each
state using actual tax base data. Thus, the estimated relationships
between bases and personal income result from the response of legislated
tax bases and rates to changing income, and the resulting wide
differences across states illustrate how important policy decisions are
to the final outcome. These estimates are much more useful for
understanding the underlying determinants of tax base growth. Second,
both short-run and long-run elasticities are measured, and the short-run
elasticities are allowed to be asymmetric based on the direction of
underlying disequilibrium. Third, the study directly examines the
determinants of the variation in elasticities across states. This allows
states to better understand what policy decisions affect revenue
responses and what state characteristics cause revenues to grow
differently across states.
3. Econometric Specification
Several steps are required to estimate the long-run elasticities,
short-run elasticities, and any asymmetries that may exist in the short
run. This section describes the econometric methods used to estimate the
tax elasticities. First, we estimate long-run elasticities using a
single-equation cointegration technique, namely Dynamic Ordinary Least
Squares (DOLS) (Stock and Watson 1993). (7) These estimated elasticities
measure the long-run, stable relationships between state tax bases and
state personal income. Next, we estimate short-run elasticities and
speed of adjustment parameters for each tax instrument via an error
correction model, which restricts the tax base to adjust toward the
estimated long-term relationship. This method follows that employed by
Sobel and Holcombe (1996). We further contribute to the current
literature by introducing a model that allows and tests for asymmetric
responses in both the short-run tax base elasticity and long-run speed
of adjustment for each state. Finally, we estimate cross-sectional
regressions to examine the possible determinants of these elasticities.
Long-Run Income Elasticities
Over long time periods, sales and personal income tax bases in each
state depend upon the level of state personal income as follows:
[B.sup.i.sub.t] = [f.sup.i] ([I.sup.i.sub.t]). (1)
In Equation 1, for state i in year t, B denotes the natural log of
the current period tax measure and I denotes the natural log of personal
income. Caution must be observed when using time-series data to estimate
relationships such as this, since the use of non-stationary time-series
observations may produce spurious results. (8) Augmented Dickey-Fuller
(ADF) tests (Dickey and Fuller 1981) suggest that the natural logs of
sales tax bases, personal income tax revenues, and personal income in
each state contain a unit root, or are non-stationary. (9) However, the
risk of spurious regression is eliminated if the variables in question
tend to move together over a long period of time (i.e., if they are
cointegrated). Although the presence of cointegration removes the
problem of spurious regression, several other problems can arise in the
context of time series regression via OLS. These problems include serial
correlation, non-normally distributed residuals, and endogeneity. (10)
Personal income shares a theoretical long-run relationship with both the
sales tax base and the personal income tax base, mitigating the
possibility of spurious regression. We further correct for the
deficiencies of OLS by using DOLS to estimate the long-run elasticity of
each tax base with respect to personal income. The DOLS specification,
which provides a correction for bias and serial correlation, is as
follows:
[B.sup.i.sub.t] = [[beta].sup.i.sub.0] +
[[beta].sup.i.sub.1][I.sup.i.sub.t] + [j.summation over (g = -j)]
[[gamma].sup.i.sub.g][DELTA][I.sup.i.sub.t+g] + [[theta].sup.i.sub.t].
(2)
Equation 2 is estimated separately for each tax base, and the
long-run elasticity of the specific tax base with respect to personal
income in state i is given by [[beta].sub.1]. (11) The j leads and lags of the change in personal income represent the DOLS correction to adjust
for possible endogeneity and autocorrelation. (12) We use standard delta
notation to denote first differences of our key variables.
Symmetric Short-Run Elasticities
Changes in long-run equilibrium tax bases caused by changes in
personal income may not be fully realized until after an adjustment
period. More importantly, stability between tax bases and personal
income need not hold in the short run; any differences between short and
long-run income elasticities create deviations between the long-run
equilibrium base and the current period base. Therefore, actual bases
from either tax for state i (denoted by [B.sub.t]) may be above or below
the long-run equilibrium value (denoted by [B.sup.*.sub.t]) in any
period. In Equation 3, the current period value of e measures the
deviations of the respective actual tax base in period t from its
long-run equilibrium value. These short-run deviations occur when the
immediate effect of a change in personal income is different from the
long-run effect.
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3)
Thus, two short-run effects can exist in any time period: tax bases
can respond to changes in personal income and tax bases can adjust
according to the disequilibrium ([epsilon]) that exists at the beginning
of the period. The selected econometric approach must capture both of
these shortrun effects, and this is achieved with an error-correction
model (ECM):
[B.sup.i.sub.t] - [B.sup.i.sub.t-1] = [[alpha].sup.i.sub.0] +
[[alpha].sup.i.sub.1](I.sup.i.sub.t] - [I.sup.i.sub.t-1]) +
[[alpha].sup.i.sub.2][[epsilon].sup.i.sub.t-1] + [[mu].sup.i.sub.t]. (4)
The ECM involves separate regressors to measure each of these
effects. The [[alpha].sub.1] parameter in Equation 4 captures the
immediate, intra-period effects of a change in personal income; it is a
measure of the short-run income elasticity.
One point of interest is how the short-run tax base elasticities
differ from the long-run elasticities. The econometric specification
used here allows for direct comparison between the two. The short-run
tax base response to personal income changes is smaller or greater than
the long-run response according to whether [[alpha].sub.1] is less than
or greater than [[beta].sub.1]. Another interesting question is how fast
tax bases move toward a new long-run equilibrium brought about by
changes in personal income. The [[alpha].sub.2] parameter in Equation 4
measures the size of adjustment of the tax base to its long-run
equilibrium value, and gives the percentage of disequilibrium that is
removed in every period. (13) Therefore, the larger the absolute value
of this adjustment parameter, the faster the tax base moves toward its
long-run value.
Asymmetric Short-Run Income Elasticities
The short-run elasticity in Equation 4 is the same regardless of
whether the respective tax base measure is below ([[epsilon].sub.t] less
than zero) or above ([[epsilon].sub.t] at greater than zero) its
long-run equilibrium value. However, it is reasonable to expect that
either tax base could exhibit an asymmetric response as a result of
state structural considerations, differences in household behavior, or
other factors.
The ECM can be modified to allow for the presence of any asymmetry,
as shown in Equation 5:
[DELTA][B.sup.i.sub.t] = [[alpha].sup.i.sub.0] +
[[alpha].sup.i.sub.1][DELTA][I.sup.i.sub.t] +
[[theta].sup.i.sub.1]([DB.sup.i.sub.t] * [DELTA][I.sup.i.sub.t]) +
[[alpha].sup.i.sub.2] + [[epsilon].sup.i.sub.t-1] +
[[theta].sup.i.sub.2]([DB.sup.i.sub.t-1] * [[epsilon].sup.i.sub.t-1]) +
[v.sup.i.sub.t]. (5)
A dummy variable ([DB.sub.t]) is inserted to identify the tax
measure's position relative to its equilibrium value. (14) This
dummy equals zero if the respective tax measure is below its long-run
equilibrium value and one if it is above equilibrium. (15) The model
specification given by Equation 5 allows for separate measurement of an
asymmetric short-run elasticity and adjustment parameter.
The revised econometric method provides the ability to estimate
differences between shortrun and long-run elasticities and determine
whether the short-run elasticities vary according to the projected
future growth in taxes. For example, the respective tax base measure
will adjust upward in the future if it is below long-run equilibrium
([[epsilon].sub.t] less than zero). Examining whether [[theta].sub.1] is
statistically different from zero allows a test of whether this upward
adjustment is different relative to the downward future adjustment when
bases are above equilibrium. Asymmetry in the long-run adjustment of
either tax base is determined by the statistical significance of
[[theta].sub.2].
4. Data Issues
We use annual time series data for 1967 through 2000 to estimate
all long-run and short-run elasticities and adjustment parameters
separately for the sales and income tax for each state. Selection of the
dependent variables for the sales and income taxes is a key decision in
the analysis. As we have noted, much previous work has relied upon
national proxies for state tax bases. There are two main reasons why we
choose to use actual state data rather than national proxies. First, our
approach allows us to develop state-specific elasticity estimates and to
investigate the causes of the wide differences in estimated elasticities
across the states. It seems very likely that elasticities would vary
with state-specific tax base characteristics, such as progressive income
tax rates or the extent to which services are taxed by the sales tax.
Long-run elasticities may also be affected by the causes of economic
growth, which might be influenced by the state economic structure.
State-specific tax estimates are necessary to study issues such as how
the elasticity is affected by the interplay between the differing state
economies and tax performance. This would not be possible with national
proxies.
Second, and more importantly, extensive differences exist between
any possible proxies and the actual bases observed in each state. As a
result, state-specific data are necessary to measure elasticities in the
context of the actual tax institutions used across the United States.
State structures also differ so greatly that it is necessary to estimate
each state's elasticity independently. The most significant
difference is that approximately 40% of the sales tax is paid on
intermediate purchases (Ring 1999), and this portion of the base will
not be reflected in national consumption proxies used by other analysts.
Various components of retail sales or consumption (from national income
accounts) do not include these intermediate purchases, which are large
shares of the sales tax base in every state. 16 This is not to say that
taxation of intermediate purchases is good tax policy, but it is a large
part of actual tax bases, and it is not possible to examine actual sales
tax elasticities with this part of the base excluded.
State treatment of consumer purchases also differs widely from
measures of consumption in the economic data. For example, 30 states
exempt food for consumption at home, seven exempt some clothing, all but
one exempt prescription drugs, 10 exempt nonprescription drugs, and
states tax between 14 (Colorado) and 160 (Hawaii) of the 168 categories
of services enumerated by the Federation of Tax Administrators (FTA).
(17) The problem is exacerbated by the radical differences in state
definitions of taxable food, clothing, services, and other transactions.
Figure 1 illustrates the importance of the sales tax base choice.
(18) Personal consumption has risen during the time series, from about
62% to 70% of GDP. Retail sales have been slightly volatile but are
nearly the same share of GDP at the beginning and end of the panel. The
simple average of all states' actual sales tax bases, on the other
hand, is consistently much larger than retail sales (because the
taxation of business inputs and services exceeds exemption of goods) but
has declined from 53.2% of GDP in 1979 to 40.1% in 2003. Observation of
these data series evidences the definitional differences between actual
sales tax bases and economic data and how these series are diverging over time. (19) Differences in state definitions of the actual tax base
are even broader than the divergence from economic data. Hawaii's
tax base was 92.6% of GSP in 2000, while Rhode Island's base was
only 27.5% of GSP in the same year. Proxies cannot reasonably be used to
account for the differences arising from state-specific policy choices.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Similar cross-state differences exist for the income tax.
Twenty-seven states start calculation of the personal income tax with
federal adjusted gross income, leaving the state free to set deductions
and exemptions, if any are used at all, according to state preferences.
Ten states start with federal taxable income, meaning federal exemptions
and deductions are accepted. Four states do not explicitly start with a
federal definition of income. (20) In every case, states make
adjustments to income after the starting point. For example, all but
three states allow some personal exemption, but the amounts vary
significantly. Some states exempt all or part of pension income. States
do not allow deduction of state income taxes, but eight states allow
deduction of federal income tax paid. Tax structures in 14 states are at
least partially indexed for inflation. National proxies, such as
personal income or GSP, cannot allow for these cross-state differences,
and at best can be seen as some type of average income across states
that does not capture actual tax institutions. Further, these measures
often do not include capital gains and some other forms of non-labor
income that have been an important part of taxable income. National tax
measures, such as adjusted gross income or taxable income, are closer to
state tax measures. However, these proxies cannot account for the
differences in state practice.
State data on the income and sales tax bases, the preferred
dependent variables, are unfortunately not directly available. Actual
state sales tax bases are measured here as state sales tax revenue
divided by the general state sales tax rate. (21) While many states
impose rates that differ from the general rate on a narrow set of
transactions, the resulting difference between the estimated and actual
bases will be very small. In fact, the only variation from the actual
tax base could arise because tax credits could alter the timing of sales
tax receipts between fiscal years. The income tax is measured here using
actual revenues rather than the base because 35 states impose
progressive rates and the quotient obtained by dividing income tax
revenue by the maximum rate will differ significantly from the actual
income tax base. (22) Based on the significant limitations of
alternative tax base proxies, we believe that our resulting elasticity
estimates are much better measures of actual state relationships than
would be obtained using non-tax proxies for tax bases.
State tax revenue data are drawn from the U.S. Census, (23) with
each tax base measure adjusted for inflation using the GDP deflator.
Specifically, we estimate the relationships between inflation-adjusted
tax bases and inflation-adjusted personal income. Factors besides
personal income that can influence the pattern of tax bases, such as
legislated base changes, are taken into account in our cross-section analysis. (24)
5. Empirical Results
Long-Run Income Elasticities
We estimate Equations 2 and 5 separately for each state and provide
average parameter estimates across the states for the sales tax in Table
1 and the income tax in Table 2. State-specific estimates are shown in
Figures 2 and 3 and Tables 3 and 4. The average parameter estimates
appear very reasonable, but there are significant differences across the
states, as expected. The average long-run income tax elasticity is
1.832, which is more than twice the average sales tax elasticity. The
difference between the average long-run sales tax and income tax
elasticities is statistically significant at the 99% level of
confidence. Both are significantly different from one, with income tax
revenues growing significantly faster than personal income and sales tax
bases growing slower than personal income. The long-run income tax
elasticity estimate is greater than the long-run sales tax elasticity
estimate in every state that employs both taxes (see Tables 3 and 4).
(25,26) The relative sizes of the long-run elasticities are consistent
with the change in the share of revenues raised by these two taxes.
[FIGURES 2-3 OMITTED]
The highest sales tax elasticity, at 1.365, occurs in
Massachusetts, and the lowest, at 0.339, occurs in North Dakota (see
Table 3 and Figure 2). Only nine states have sales tax elasticities
above 1.0, and in four cases the difference from 1.0 is statistically
significant. Individual state income tax elasticities vary widely (see
Table 4 and Figure 3). The estimate for the income tax elasticity is
only below 1.0 in two states, North Dakota and Vermont, and is only
significantly below 1.0 in North Dakota. (27) Thirteen states have
income tax elasticities above two, and in five cases the elasticity is
significantly above two. As shown in Figure 4, the distribution of
income tax elasticities is much wider than for the sales tax.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
It is difficult to compare our results with earlier research
because those studies used different econometric methods and generally
relied on national proxies rather than state-level analysis. A
comparison with Dye and McGuire (1991) is particularly difficult because
they estimate growth rates for various tax alternatives and components
of the base rather than elasticities. Our income tax elasticity
estimates for the average state are higher than Sobel and Holcombe
(1996) find for the national proxies, and 34 of 40 states have a higher
long-run elasticity than their national estimate. This is expected given
our use of relatively more variable state-specific data. Our average
sales tax estimate, on the other hand, is in the middle of those
presented by Sobel and Holcombe. With that said, we find essentially no
state to have sales tax elasticity as high as their high-end estimate.
Short-Run Elasticities and Adjustment Parameters
Short-run estimates are generated using the error correction model
that allows for asymmetric income elasticities and rates of adjustment
when the above and below equilibrium estimates are significantly
different (Equation 5). Otherwise, the coefficients are from the
symmetric model (Equation 4). The primary focus from a policy
perspective is on the collection of revenues within a fiscal year rather
than on the more narrowly defined relationship between bases and income.
As previously described, the change in bases during any year is the net
of two effects: (1) the change in bases in response to any change in
personal income and (2) the adjustment to eliminate any existing
disequilibrium. Thus, it is important to evaluate both effects and how
they interact. As the results are discussed, each effect is considered
separately and then the net impact is evaluated.
Sales Tax Results
Consider sales tax effects arising from a change in personal income
(elasticity response). As shown in Table 1, the mean short-run sales tax
elasticity is much greater when the base is above equilibrium (1.80)
than when it is below equilibrium (0.15). Estimates for individual
states differ widely, and in most states, an asymmetric base elasticity
is found. Only 11 states have symmetric short-run sales tax
elasticities, with the other 33 states having different shortrun
elasticities depending on the direction of disequilibrium (see Table 3).
(28) The short-run above-equilibrium elasticity is only below the
long-run elasticity in three states: Illinois, Kansas, and South Dakota.
Tax bases respond slowly to an increase in personal income when they are
below the long-run level. The base (and tax revenues) is most likely to
be below equilibrium during a recession or sluggish economic growth
period, so the low elasticity suggests that the revenue rebound will not
be affected very much by whether personal income growth during the
recovery is rapid or slow. Yet, the high above-equilibrium short-run
elasticities provide evidence that the base is more responsive to a
change in personal income when it is adjusting downward toward its
long-run value.
Second, consider the adjustment to the long-run equilibrium. The
speed of adjustment coefficient is negative on average both when the
base is above and below expectations (Table 1), but the effect is to
reduce the base when it is above expectations and raise it when it is
below expectations (see Equation 3). (29) Of course, the effect of
adjustment on the actual base is greater when the base is farther from
equilibrium (since the effect is the coefficient times the
disequilibrium). The average below-equilibrium adjustment parameter is
greater in absolute value than the average above-equilibrium adjustment
parameter suggesting a greater response to disequilibrium below
expectations, but the two parameters are only significantly different in
nine states. Thus, the amount of disequilibrium eliminated in each year
is generally the same whether revenues are above or below equilibrium.
The below-equilibrium and above-equilibrium adjustment parameters
are not significantly different from - 1.0 for twelve and four states,
respectively, indicating that the disequilibrium is entirely eliminated
for these states in the following year. It takes more than one year to
eliminate disequilibrium in all other states. A relationship appears to
exist between the size of the short-run elasticity and the rate of
adjustment. The adjustment parameter and short-run elasticity are
positively correlated (0.362) when the base is below expectations and
are negatively correlated (-0.370) when the base is above expectations,
and both of these correlation coefficients are statistically
significantly different from zero at the 95% level.
The dynamic base change in any year is the combination of the
elasticity response and the adjustment to disequilibrium. Figure 5
illustrates the dynamic sales tax response in two states. (30) Panels A
and B show the simulated below-equilibrium response when the base begins
1% below equilibrium and when real personal income grows by 1%. The
long-run equilibrium base index rises by 0.712 in Alabama and by 0.833
in Arkansas because of the one-percent income growth. Yet, the actual
base grows slowly in Alabama because the short-run elasticity is very
small (0.05) and the adjustment coefficient is very low (-0.152),
meaning little of the preexisting disequilibrium is eliminated in each
year and much of the disequilibrium remains after ten years. Conversely,
Arkansas has a somewhat larger short-run elasticity (0.323) and adjusts
to disequilibrium more rapidly (-0.915). The entire disequilibrium is
nearly eliminated after two years. In the case of a similar income
increase when both states are above equilibrium (see Panels C and D),
both states overshoot the expected base increase, and neither fully
eliminates the disequilibrium after ten years.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
Several conclusions can be made about the dynamics of sales tax
base responses. First, states are affected very differently by cyclical and trend growth conditions, since the parameter estimates differ widely
by state. Second, tax bases grow less than would be expected from the
short-run elasticity when above equilibrium and faster than would be
expected when below equilibrium because of the adjustment to any
preexisting disequilibrium. Results for the shortrun below-equilibrium
elasticities and the adjustment parameters are consistent with the
response of durable goods purchases and business input purchases in the
early stages of economic recovery, depending more on the degree to which
expenditure levels have fallen below long-run equilibrium than on the
speed with which income recovers. Another conclusion is that the
relative size of the two effects can vary, depending on how fast
personal income changes and how far tax bases are from their long-run
equilibrium. This means the simple relationship between income and base
growth could take any sign. For example, the base could decline as
income rises (when above equilibrium) if the extent of disequilibrium is
large relative to the income growth or if the adjustment parameter is
large relative to the short-run elasticity. Further, the statistical
estimates indicate that the adjustment parameter is much greater
relative to the short-run elasticity when the base is below expectations
than when it is above expectations. Thus, revenues are much more likely
to rise noticeably above expectations (at least for a short time) than
to fall below them. This general logic applies to the income tax results
that follow.
Income Tax Results
The pattern of income tax responses is similar to the sales tax
(see Tables 2 and 4). Thirty states have statistically different
short-run elasticities depending on whether the base is above or below
equilibrium, while the remaining ten states have symmetric elasticities.
The mean above-equilibrium short-run elasticity (2.66) is much greater
than either the long-run elasticity (1.83) or the below-equilibrium
short-run elasticity (0.22). The short-run above-equilibrium elasticity
is below the long-run elasticity in 12 states.
The average short-run sales and income tax elasticities are very
similar and not significantly different when the bases are below their
respective long-run equilibrium values. (31) As noted above, both taxes
have short-run elasticities that are very small when the base is below
equilibrium. Further, while the average short-run elasticities differ by
nearly 0.9 when the base is above expectations, the standard deviations are relatively large, so this difference is not statistically
significant. One distinction between the income and sales tax results is
that the speed of adjustment is greater above equilibrium for the income
tax (i.e., the absolute value of the adjustment coefficient is greater
above equilibrium than below equilibrium).
Nonetheless, the adjustment parameters for the income tax are the
same for most states, with only 11 states having a different adjustment
parameter when above and below equilibrium. The above-equilibrium
adjustment parameter is not statistically different from -1.0 for 12
states and the below-equilibrium adjustment parameter is not
statistically different from -1.0 for nine states, suggesting that the
entire disequilibrium is eliminated in one year for these states.
Very different income tax responses are found across the states.
For example, Louisiana has a very high response to personal income
growth when the base is above equilibrium, but the entire disequilibrium
is eliminated in the following year. (32) On the other hand, New Mexico has very high elasticity without the rapid adjustment to equilibrium.
6. Which Tax Is More Volatile?
Overall, the estimates do not provide a firm conclusion as to
whether the sales or the income tax is more volatile, with the
conclusion depending upon the definition of volatility. The income tax
has a higher long-run elasticity, but that simply means that revenues
grow faster over long periods of time--it tells little about whether the
growth path is volatile. Nonetheless, discussions of volatility have
often focused on the long-run elasticity. Volatility is inherently a
short-run issue and is best considered in the context of how an actual
tax base (or revenue) performs relative to its long-run equilibrium
value and how much it fluctuates around the equilibrium during short
time periods or different segments of the business cycle.
Conditions when tax bases (and revenues) will be above or below
expectations can be parallel to specific economic environments, though
not precisely. Both sales tax bases and income tax revenues are likely
to be above long-run equilibrium during strong growth periods, such as
the late 1990s. The base and revenues are likely to be below long-run
equilibrium during the latter stages of a recession or economic
slowdown, as during the early years of the 2000s. Thus, both taxes will
respond gradually as income begins to grow more rapidly at the end of
the economic slowdown, but the total rise in the tax measure will be
larger in cases when the extent of disequilibrium has gotten to be
relatively large (because of the adjustment parameter).
Figure 6 illustrates dynamic responses of both the income and sales
tax bases for periods above and below equilibrium using average state
parameter estimates and similar assumptions to Figure 5. The long-run
income tax response to a one-percent income increase is twice as large
as for the sales tax, as determined by the long-run elasticities. Given
that the short-run below-equilibrium elasticities are approximately the
same, the income tax response will be much further below equilibrium
than the sales tax response (Panels A and B of Figure 6). In this sense,
the income tax is more volatile. However, adjustment to the new
equilibrium takes approximately the same time for both taxes (the income
tax takes slightly longer), leaving the question of relative volatility unanswered.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
Differences between the two taxes are also evident in the
above-equilibrium scenarios in Panels C and D of Figure 6. First, it
should be noted that the relative extent of disequilibrium will be
greater for the sales tax than for the income tax because the difference
between the short-run above-equilibrium elasticity and the long-run
elasticity is greater for the sales tax (1.804 vs. 0.811) than for the
income tax (2.663 vs. 1.832). However, the adjustment parameter is
larger for the income tax (-0.618 vs. -0.332), so the reaction to any
amount of disequilibrium will be greater for the income tax. As shown in
Figure 6, the sales tax has the greater increase relative to the new
equilibrium, suggesting that the sales tax can be the more volatile tax
in above-equilibrium scenarios. The sales tax base adjusts to the new
equilibrium more slowly than the income tax. In sum, the answer to the
question of relative volatility depends upon the particular economic
situation at hand.
7. Causes of State Variation in Base Elasticities
While the preceding analysis sheds important light on the
differences in tax base elasticities both across states and over time,
the chosen econometric methodology is not designed to explain the
resulting cross-state differences. Toward that end, we now turn to
estimates of cross-section OLS regressions to determine whether the
estimated cross-state differences in tax base elasticities can be
explained by observable factors. We estimate separate cross-section
regressions for each vector of estimated parameters (i.e., long-run
elasticities, short-run elasticities, and adjustment parameters for each
of the two taxes), but only provide detailed models of the long-run
elasticity models here.
Equation Structure
The regression structure is not drawn from a formal theoretical
framework, but is a policy experiment to provide greater relevance to
the findings by identifying features that are associated with
cross-state differences in the elasticities. Quite simply, we are
seeking to identify what factors are related to elasticity differences
using four categories of regressors: tax structure characteristics,
demographic factors, political characteristics, and measures of state
economic structures. (33) The variables are listed with summary
statistics in Appendix A.
An important issue is what values to use as regressors, since the
elasticities were estimated using 33 years of data. In order to make
these results as useful as possible in a policy context, our baseline analysis uses regressors defined mostly as of the most recent year
(1999) of our data. Our motivation for doing this is that states are
better able to make use of results drawn from recent data (most closely
related to the current environment) than if we were to explain
cross-sectional variation in elasticities using data from an earlier
period. Recognizing that this is temporally misaligned with the
underlying elasticities, we also provide results where most variables
are entered as changes between 1970 and 1999.
We include six characteristics of state income tax structures in
our income tax regressions: the income threshold at which the highest
marginal tax rate is imposed, a dummy variable for whether a state-level
earned-income tax credit exists, the share of the tax base represented
by capital gains, a series of four dummy variables to measure the
taxation of pensions, a measure of the overall progressivity of the
income tax rate schedule, and the average annual change in the highest
marginal income tax rate between 1970 and 1999. More specifically, our
pension taxability dummies control for the total or partial exemption of
government or private pensions. Our progressivity measure is calculated
as the change in the effective tax rate over an income range from
$10,000 below to $10,000 above the state's median income level. Our
inclusion of the average change over time in the highest marginal tax
rate is necessitated by our use of tax revenue rather than tax base as
the dependent variable in the income tax elasticity estimates, and the
coefficient is expected to have a positive sign. Including this variable
will allow us to essentially adjust our elasticity estimates for tax
rate changes during our period of analysis. We expect the income
threshold to be negatively associated and progressivity to be positively
related with the elasticity because these variables account for how
rapidly taxpayer liabilities grow as their incomes rise. The influence
of an earned income credit is less straightforward to predict, however,
as the relationship between income and tax liability varies depending on
shares of taxpayers in the phase-in and phase-out ranges of the credit.
Inclusions of pension income will be positively related to the
elasticity if pension income is growing faster than other forms of
income, and negatively related otherwise.
We include two separate tax variables in our regressions of sales
tax parameters. The first is the sales tax base as a percent of personal
income. The sign is expected to be positive because a broader tax base,
as given by a larger value of this variable, is an indicator that a
state relies more heavily on taxation of services. The second is a
measure of the extent to which the sales tax is levied on consumers,
drawn from the estimates developed by Ring (1999). We do not have an a
priori expectation on this coefficient. We do not include the change in
the sales tax rate over time because we use tax base rather than tax
revenue in our calculation of the sales tax elasticities. These
estimated elasticities are, therefore, immune to the effects of rate
changes (i.e., the elasticity of our tax base measure with respect to
the tax rate is, by construction of our base measure, zero).
Our list of demographic variables in all regressions includes
median income, the percentage of the population under 18 years of age,
and the percentage of the population over 65 years of age. We control
for political factors using a series of dummy variables for the
Governor's political party, as well as the majority party in the
state's legislature. State economic conditions enter the
regressions via measures of the share of Gross State Product (GSP) in
mining, in services, in agriculture, and in manufacturing; average
annual employment growth over the study period; and the standard
deviation of employment growth. It is generally difficult to impose a
priori expectations on many of these variables, so we use empirical
techniques to determine whether any relationships exist between these
variables and the elasticities.
Long-Run Income Tax Estimates
As shown in the first column of results in Table 5, many of the
variables are statistically significant at the 90% level in our baseline
long-run income tax elasticity model, revealing that the wide
differences in income tax elasticities can often be explained by
variation in the included regressors. For example, the long-run income
elasticity is higher in states where the maximum tax bracket occurs at
lower income levels (the coefficient is negative). Of course, like any
regression coefficient, this result holds the degree of progressivity
around median income (and all other variables in the model) constant.
Given a level of progressivity, our finding that states with lower
top-bracket thresholds have higher long-run income elasticities is
perhaps unsurprising, since an increase in income would lead to a
relatively larger increase in taxes paid in those states. This result is
seen only with the 1999 specification, and not with the 1970-1999
changes specification.
Failure to tax pensions generally lowers the elasticity, suggesting
that pension income is rising faster than other forms of income. The one
exception in both models is partial exemption of private pension income.
Some states have chosen to exclude pension income during the study
period, so the coefficient may be capturing both the fall in elasticity
as the base was narrowed and the effects that failure to tax pensions
has on the elasticity. The result cannot be interpreted to mean that the
elasticity going forward will be lower for states that have already
excluded pensions.
The change in tax rates is positively related to the long-run
elasticity in both models, providing the anticipated finding that
revenues grow faster when rates are increased and slower when rates are
decreased. Of the states that imposed an income tax throughout the
entire study period, 16 raised their maximum income tax rate and 14
decreased their rate, with the average annual change being an increase
of 0.3%. Thus, the average income tax elasticity was increased by 0.09
as a result of rate changes, leaving the average income tax elasticity
adjusted for rate changes still about twice as large as the average
sales tax elasticity. (34)
In terms of state demographic characteristics, our 1999
specification reveals that long-run income tax elasticities are higher
in states with a larger share of their population either under age 18 or
over age 65. Also, for the 1999 model, higher median incomes translate into lower long-run income elasticities for the personal income tax.
Moving to state economic factors, we find that long-run income tax
elasticities tend to be lower in states with significant resource-based
economies, whether agriculture or mining, but the coefficients are only
of marginal significance. A large agricultural sector results in a large
reduction in the elasticity, providing evidence that tax systems respond
slowly to economic expansion of this sector. This finding is consistent
with the propensity of states to allow specialized treatment and low
effective rates on income generated in the agriculture sector. (35) It
may also reveal that credits and loss carry-forwards from slow economic
periods allow taxable income in the agriculture sector to respond slowly
as the economy improves. In any event, if all else is equal, the
resource-intensive states have less revenue-elastic tax systems than
other states. More volatile employment growth, on the other hand, tends
to result in higher income tax elasticity in both models.
Long-Run Sales Tax Elasticities
Unlike the analysis of the long-run personal income tax
elasticities, most variables are not statistically significant in the
sales tax elasticity regressions, as shown in the second and fourth
columns of Table 5. One likely explanation is that the range of sales
tax elasticities is much smaller than for the income tax, meaning there
is less variation to be explained (see Figure 4). Also, it is more
difficult to summarize important sales tax base differences
quantitatively.
Despite this general lack of statistical significance, we find in
our 1999 specification that a broader sales tax base results in higher
sales tax elasticity. Given the rapid growth in the service sector as a
share of personal income during the study period, and the fact that
greater taxation of services is responsible for much of the state
variation in base breadth, this finding suggests that taxation of more
services results in a higher elasticity. (36) Quite simply, consumption
of services has been more elastic than consumption of goods over the
past several decades. Alternatively, our 1970-1999 changes model reveals
that states in which the change in sales tax base breadth has been most
extensive between 1970 and 1999 tend to have lower elasticities. The
sales tax base in every state declined relative to personal income
during our study period, meaning that states with the greatest base
decline tend to have a more elastic sales tax. (37) Decisions by many
states during our study period to exempt food for consumption at home
are probably the largest policy-driven narrowing of the bases. Thus, the
finding can be interpreted to mean that exemption of relatively
slow-growing food from the base is likely to increase the sales tax
elasticity.
States where a higher share of the sales tax is incident on
consumers tend to have higher elasticities in the 1999 model. One
possible explanation for this is that states have high consumer shares
because they have exempted a significant amount of business transactions
during the study period. (38) The only other statistically significant
result from our regressions of long-run sales tax elasticities is that
median income is found to have a significant and positive influence on
the long-run sales tax elasticity, again only in the 1999 model.
We also estimate similar regressions of all short-run parameters,
with the only difference being our inclusion of the corresponding
long-run elasticity as a regressor. To summarize the many findings of
this exercise, we are largely unable to identify many policy variables
that are associated with short-run elasticities and adjustment
parameters.
8. Conclusions
As states continue to experience financial hardship due to the
flagging revenue performance of major state taxes, many are tempted to
adjust their revenue structure in order to stave off future instability.
In such a policy environment, it is important to understand the
comparative dynamics of various taxes. States' failure to consider
such dynamics in the mid-1990s helped create their subsequent problems,
as a number of states reduced their tax rates or bases during the robust
revenue growth years of the late 1990s, apparently believing that the
existing short-run revenue conditions reflected the underlying long-run
revenue environment.
Our research expands upon the earlier literature by estimating
long-run income elasticities of the two major state taxes (personal
income and sales), by separately identifying short-run elasticities, and
by allowing variation in the dynamic adjustment of the tax base in
response to personal income changes. Further, we examine the various
determinants of the cross-state variation in all estimated parameters.
These results allow for a more in-depth understanding of state revenue
performance and much better insight into the relationship between
short-run and long-run revenue fluctuations.
To summarize the many results of this empirical exercise, we first
find that the average long-run income elasticity of state personal
income tax bases is more than double that for sales taxes. Short-run
elasticities are found to exhibit asymmetry in most states.
Specifically, they are higher than long-run elasticities when the
current tax base is above the long-run equilibrium, and lower when the
current tax base is below equilibrium. Estimated adjustment parameters
indicate that any short-run disequilibrium is quickly alleviated for
both taxes in many states.
Contrary to conventional wisdom, neither the personal income tax
nor the sales tax emerges as the universally more volatile tax. While
income elasticities are generally larger for the income tax in both the
long run and the short run, a careful assessment of relative volatility
must consider the interaction of long-run elasticities, short-run
elasticities, the extent of preexisting disequilibrium, and the relative
speed of adjustment toward the new equilibrium. The sales tax can
actually be the more volatile tax in certain scenarios.
After controlling for state demographic and economic
characteristics, we find that a number of state-specific policy elements
are important factors of state variation in estimated elasticities. Over
the long run, personal income taxes are more income-elastic in states
where the maximum tax bracket occurs at lower income levels, pensions
are taxed, the rate structure is more progressive around the median
income level, and the top rate has increased by a larger percentage. In
terms of the sales tax, states with broader bases and with larger shares
being paid by consumers have higher income elasticities.
Consequently, these results indicate that states have a number of
options for increasing the overall income elasticity of their tax
structures. They can simply shift away from lower-elasticity taxes
(e.g., the sales tax) toward higher-elasticity taxes (e.g., the personal
income tax), or they can work within their existing tax portfolio by
adjusting these policy elements. However, increasing a revenue
system's elasticity does not necessarily increase its volatility.
Appendix A
Summary Statistics and Source Notes for Cross-Sectional Regression
Variable Mean Std. Dev.
ST base/personal income 0.463 0.153
Consumer share of ST 59.422 8.892
Lowest income in highest PIT bracket 59,344 78,977
EITC dummy 0.220 0.418
Capital gains/personal income 0.060 0.020
Progressivity at median income 0.003 0.002
Partial exemption for government pensions 0.463 0.505
Total exemption for government pensions 0.268 0.449
Partial exemption for private pensions 0.488 0.506
Total exemption for private pensions 0.073 0.264
Percentage of population under 18 years of age 0.257 0.017
Percentage of population over 65 years of age 0.125 0.019
Median income 58,500 7,701
Republican legislature 0.400 0.495
Democratic legislature 0.380 0.490
Republican governor 0.620 0.490
Mining share of GSP 0.017 0.034
Average annual employment growth (1970-1999) 0.035 0.023
Standard deviation of employment growth
(1970-1999) 0.026 0.011
Manufacturing share of GSP 0.162 0.064
Services share of GSP 0.160 0.027
Agriculture share of GSP 0.015 0.011
Average change in top PIT rate (1970-1999) 0.003 0.012
Variable Minimum Maximum
ST base/personal income 0.252 1.108
Consumer share of ST 28.000 89.000
Lowest income in highest PIT bracket 0 300,000
EITC dummy 0 1
Capital gains/personal income 0.026 0.123
Progressivity at median income 0 0.008
Partial exemption for government pensions 0 1
Total exemption for government pensions 0 1
Partial exemption for private pensions 0 1
Total exemption for private pensions 0 1
Percentage of population under 18 years of age 0.223 0.322
Percentage of population over 65 years of age 0.057 0.176
Median income 44,947 75,505
Republican legislature 0 1
Democratic legislature 0 1
Republican governor 0 1
Mining share of GSP 0 0.161
Average annual employment growth (1970-1999) 0.006 0.129
Standard deviation of employment growth
(1970-1999) 0.015 0.061
Manufacturing share of GSP 0.030 0.316
Services share of GSP 0.085 0.240
Agriculture share of GSP 0.003 0.055
Average change in top PIT rate (1970-1999) -0.025 0.032
Variable Source
ST base/personal income U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis
Consumer share of ST Ring (1999)
Lowest income in highest PIT State Tax Handbook, Commerce
bracket Clearinghouse
EITC dummy Center for Budget and Policy Priorities
Capital gains/personalx Internal Revenue Service and Bureau of
over Economic Analysis
Progressivity at median Authors' calculations based on median
income income and tax rates
Partial exemption for Federation of Tax Administrators at
government pensions http://assets.aarp.org/rgcenter/
econ/ib55_sstax.pdf
Total exemption for Federation of Tax Administrators at
government pensions http://assets.aarp.org/rgcenter/
econ/ib55_sstax.pdf
Partial exemption for Federation of Tax Administrators at
private pensions http://assets.aarp.org/rgcenter/
econ/ib55_sstax.pdf
Total exemption for private Federation of Tax Administrators at
pensions http://assets.aarp.org/rgcenter/
econ/ib55_sstax.pdf
Percentage of population U.S. Bureau of the Census
under 18 years of age
Percentage of population U.S. Bureau of the Census
over 65 years of age
Median income Statistical Abstract of the United
States, U.S. Bureau of the Census
Republican legislature Statistical Abstract of the United
States, U.S. Bureau of the Census
Democratic legislature Statistical Abstract of the United
States, U.S. Bureau of the Census
Republican governor Statistical Abstract of the United
States, U.S. Bureau of the Census
Mining share of GSP Authors' calculations based on Regional
Accounts Data, Bureau of Economic
Analysis
Average annual employment Bureau of Labor Statistics
growth (1970-1999)
Standard deviation of Bureau of Labor Statistics
employment growth
(1970-1999)
Manufacturing share of GSP Authors' calculations based on
Regional Accounts Data, Bureau of
Economic Analysis
Services share of GSP Authors' calculations based on Regional
Accounts Data, Bureau of Economic
Analysis
Agriculture share of GSP Authors' calculations based on Regional
Accounts Data, Bureau of Economic
Analysis
Average change in top PIT Authors' calculations based on data
rate (1970-1999) from State Tax Handbook, Commerce
Clearinghouse
Appendix B
Long-Run PIT Elasticities Adjusted for Rate Changes
Unadjusted Adjusted
Alabama 1.82 1.82
Arizona 1.14 1.55
Arkansas 2.10 1.79
California 1.75 1.82
Colorado 1.26 1.17
Georgia 1.69 1.69
Hawaii 1.32 1.41
Idaho 1.57 1.65
Illinois 1.57 1.40
Indiana 2.44 1.95
Iowa 2.35 1.86
Kansas 2.26 2.27
Kentucky 2.60 2.60
Louisiana 2.27 2.27
Maine 2.87 2.55
Maryland 1.18 1.21
Massachusetts 1.42 1.05
Michigan 1.88 1.40
Minnesota 1.32 1.64
Mississippi 1.91 1.71
Missouri 2.29 1.92
Montana 1.60 1.60
Nebraska 2.49 3.10
New Jersey 2.02 1.16
New Mexico 3.02 3.11
New York 1.30 1.95
North Carolina 1.55 1.45
North Dakota 0.81 0.59
Ohio 3.98 3.38
Oklahoma 2.61 2.47
Oregon 1.44 1.54
Pennsylvania 1.43 1.25
Rhode Island 1.76 1.22
South Carolina 1.56 1.56
Utah 1.48 1.41
Vermont 0.97 0.97
Virginia 1.47 1.35
West Virginia 2.57 2.42
Wisconsin 1.22 1.57
Average 1.85 1.76
Std. Dev. 0.648 0.611
Unadjusted elasticities are taken from Table 4.
The authors thank Mohammed Mohsin, Robert Ebel, Robert Strauss,
John Mikesell, and three anonymous referees for very helpful comments
and John Deskins for very valuable research assistance.
Received September 2004; accepted February 2006.
References
Cook, Steven, Sean Holly, and Paul Turner. 1999. DSHY revisited:
The role of asymmetries. Applied Economics 31:775-8.
Dickey, David A., and Wayne A. Fuller. 1981. Likelihood ratio
statistics for autoregressive time series with a unit root. Econometrica 49:1057-72.
Dye, Richard F., and Therese J. McGuire. 1991. Growth and
variability of state individual income and general sales taxes. National
Tax Journal 44:55-66.
Enders, Walter, and Pierre L. Siklos. 2001. Cointegration and
threshold adjustment. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics
19:166-76.
Fox, William F., and Charles Campbell. 1984. Stability of the state
sales tax income elasticity. National Tax Journal 37:201-12.
Granger, Clive W. J., and Tae-Hwy Lee. 1989. Investigation of
production, sales, and inventory relationships using multicointegration
and non-symmetric error correction models. Journal of Applied
Econometrics 4:S145-S159.
Granger, Clive W. J., and Paul Newbold. 1974. Spurious regression
in econometrics. Journal of Econometrics 2:111-20.
Groves, Harold M., and C. Harry Kahn. 1952. The stability of state
and local tax yields. American Economic Review 42:87-102.
Jenny, Nicholas W. 2002. State tax revenue decline accelerates.
State Tax Notes 26:169.
Ludvigson, Sydney, and Charles Steindel. 1999. How important is the
stock market effect on consumption? Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review 5:29-51.
Mikesell, John L. 2004. State retail sales tax burdens, reliance,
and breadth in fiscal 2003. State Tax Notes 33:125.
Newey, Whitney K., and Kenneth D. West. 1987. A simple, positive
semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorretation consistent
covariance matrix. Econometrica 55, 1987:703-08.
Otsuka, Yasuji, and Bradley M. Braun. 1999. The random coefficient
approach for estimating tax revenue stability and growth. Public Finance
Review 27:665-76.
Ring, Raymond J., Jr. 1999. Consumer's share and
producer's share of the general sales tax. National Tax Journal
52:79-90.
Schwarz, Gideon. 1978. Estimating the dimension of a model. The
Annals of Statistics 6:461-4.
Sobel, Russell S., and Randall G. Holcombe. 1996. Measuring the
growth and variability of tax bases over the business cycle. National
Tax Journal 49:535-52.
Stock, James H., and Mark W. Watson. 1993. A simple estimator of
cointegrating vectors in higher order integrated systems. Econometrica
61:783-820.
U.S. Bureau of the Census. State Tax Collections. Various years.
(1) See Jenny (2002) for an example of the problems that states
have confronted.
(2) One example is the strong tendency for states to partially
correct their revenue shortfalls with increases in specific taxes on
tobacco products. Forty states have raised their cigarette tax rates a
total of 63 times since 2000. See http://
www.taxadmin.org/fta/rate/cig_inc02.html.
(3) There is no intent in this study to identify the appropriate
size of government. Revenue growth is deemed appropriate if it is
sufficient to fund the publicly desired level of expenditures as
determined through the political process.
(4) U.S. Bureau of the Census, State Tax Collections, 2004. See
also http://www.census.gov/govs/www/statetax.html.
(5) All percentages in this paragraph refer to states that impose
the tax being discussed. State tax shares are taken from information
provided by the Federation of Tax Administrators at
http://www.taxadmin.org/fta/rate/04taxdis.html.
(6) The actual tax structures differ widely by state from the very
broad base used by Hawaii, representing 108.2% of state personal income,
to the narrow base imposed in states such as Massachusetts and New
Jersey, representing about 30% of personal income. Values are drawn from
calculations prepared by the authors using data from State Government
Finances, U.S. Bureau of the Census and tax rates obtained from various
sources. See Ring (1999) for state estimates of the extent to which
business purchases are included in the base. An overview of state
taxation of services as well as exemptions for certain categories of
tangible goods is provided by the Federation of Tax Administrators at
http:// www.taxadmin.org/fta/rate/tax_stru.html. We return to these
issues below.
(7) See Ludvigson and Steindel (1999) for an example of the use of
this technique.
(8) See Granger and Newbold (1974).
(9) From the ADF tests, all series appear to be integrated of order
one and first-difference stationary. All ADF results are available from
the authors upon request.
(10) While the lack of a suitable instrumental variable precludes
thorough testing for endogeneity, we provide evidence of serial
correlation in the analysis that follows.
(11) In Equations 2-5, B denotes the natural log of the current
period tax measure and I denotes the natural log of personal income.
(12) The appropriate number of leads and lags varies between states
and is determined using the Schwarz Bayesian Criterion (1978). Standard
errors in this paper are calculated using the method of Newey and West
(1987).
(13) The total disequilibrium removed after t periods is given by 1
- [(1 + [[alpha].sub.2]).sup.t].
(14) Here a modified version of the method developed by Granger and
Lee (1989) is employed. Granger and Lee separate the error-correction
term into its positive and negative elements. Here, a dummy is added to
signify the positive and negative elements of the error-correction term
to measure any asymmetries in the short-run adjustment and to allow for
the measurement of any asymmetries in the short-run elasticity. See
Cook, Holly, and Turner (1999) for another application. For an
additional method, see Enders and Siklos (2001).
(15) Specifically, [DB.sub.t] takes the value of zero when
[[epsilon].sub.1] is less than zero and one when it is above zero. While
this strategy identifies asymmetry on the basis of base/revenue growth
relative to personal income growth, a potentially more easily
interpretable approach would define asymmetry on the basis of income
fluctuations in isolation. Experimentation with such approaches (e.g.,
where [DB.sub.t] takes the value of one in times of recession or
relatively slow income growth) left us unable to identify any asymmetry
at all. This is likely because there were not enough recession or slow
growth years with which to identify asymmetric responses.
(16) As a general rule, states exempt goods purchased for resale and goods that become component parts of other goods. This means that
states frequently tax a range of intermediate purchases including
computers, software, cash registers, services, packaging and many other
items.
(17) See the wealth of state tax rule information provided by the
FTA at http://www.taxadmin.org/fta/rate/tax_stru.html.
(18) Data in Figure 1 are taken from: retail sales, U.S. Department
of Commerce, Advanced Monthly Sales for Retail and Food Services;
consumption, National Income Accounts, Bureau of Economic Analysis; and
state sales tax bases are drawn from calculations prepared by the
authors using data from State Government Finances, U.S. Bureau of the
Census and tax rates obtained from various sources.
(19) Likely causes of the decline in state sales tax bases over
time include policy decisions to narrow the base (such as new exemptions
of food for consumption at home), different growth rates of taxable and
nontaxable transactions, and inability of states to collect the tax on
rapidly growing remote sales.
(20) Again, see the FTA resources at
http://www.taxadmin.org/fta/rate/inc_stp.html.
(21) This approach has been used in a number of other papers. See
Mikesell (2004) for an example.
(22) The resulting coefficient estimates from these types of
regressions are often termed buoyancy measures rather than elasticities
because the relationship between the dependent variable revenues--and
personal income includes influences from rate and base changes. However,
in our cross-section analysis we separate out the effects of base and
rate changes on the elasticity estimates and simulate the elasticities
for each state net of rate changes.
(23) Tax revenue data used in this paper are taken from U.S. Bureau
of the Census, State Government Finances, annual. See also
http://www.census.gov/govs/www/state.html.
(24) Another important issue that we are not able to explore in
this framework is the possible spatial relationships between state tax
base elasticities, or the notion that one state's elasticities are
related to those in similar or surrounding states. Such an analysis
would be a worthwhile addition to the literature but is left for future
research.
(25) No sales tax elasticity is calculated for Indiana because
personal income and sales tax revenues are not cointegrated. No income
tax elasticity is calculated for Connecticut because the tax was only
introduced in 1991, leaving only a short time series of revenue data.
(26) This result continues to hold for all states except
Massachusetts when we adjust the income tax elasticities for rate
changes using the cross-section results. Adjusted elasticities are
provided in Appendix B.
(27) The North Dakota elasticity is not significantly different
from zero.
(28) The revenue elasticity for the sales tax in North Dakota is
excluded here.
(29) Positive adjustment parameters are estimated for several
states for both the income and sales taxes but the parameters
(30) These simulations examine the effect of a one-time increase in
personal income.
(31) The associated p-value is 0.79.
(32) The point estimate for the adjustment parameter is not
significantly different from -1.0.
(33) Note that we have not included controls for spatial
correlation in these regressions, although we suspect that a
state's elasticity estimates might be related to the economic and
policy environments in other states. Such an analysis, while
interesting, relevant, and fruitful, is again left for future research.
(34) The effect of rate changes can be very important to some
states and the adjusted elasticities for each state are presented in
Appendix B. This calculation uses the coefficient on the tax rate change
variable in Table 5 with the change in tax rates for each state to
estimate the income tax base elasticity holding all else constant. The
general finding is that elasticities moved closer to the mean. but they
are still statistically different from the mean long-run sales tax
elasticity.
(35) The authors thank John Mikesell for making this observation.
(36) This result was confirmed in a separate regression where we
measured base breadth via the number of taxable services in each state.
(37) The difference in these results highlights the policy
applicability of the 1999 model. While the sales tax base breadth
variable (along with other variables entered as changes over the 30-year
span) serves as more of a control variable in the 1970-1999 changes
model, it functions as a policy variable in the 1999 model in that
states can broaden their sales tax bases in order to increase the
elasticity of the tax.
(38) One reviewer observed that a higher consumer share might
translate into lesser taxation of business, which could stimulate
economic growth.
Donald Bruce, Center for Business and Economic Research, 105 Temple
Court, University of Tennessee, Knoxville, TN 37996-4334, USA; E-mail
dbruce@utk.edu; corresponding author.
William F. Fox, Center for Business and Economic Research, 101
Temple Court, University of Tennessee, Knoxville, TN 37996-4334, USA;
E-mail billfox@utk.edu.
M. H. Tuttle, Department of Economics and International Business,
237A Smith-Hutson Building, Sam Houston State University, Huntsville, TX
77341, USA; E-mail mht001@shsu.edu.
Table 1. Average State Sales Tax Elasticities
Mean Variance
Long-run sales tax elasticity 0.811 0.048
Short-run sales tax elasticity above equilibrium 1.804 7.179
Short-run sales tax elasticity below equilibrium 0.149 0.880
Sales tax adjustment parameter above equilibrium -0.332 0.054
Sales tax adjustment parameter below equilibrium -0.513 0.150
Table 2. Average State Income Tax Elasticities
Mean Variance
Long-run personal income tax elasticity 1.832 0.427
Short-run personal income tax elasticity above
equilibrium 2.663 5.014
Short-run personal income tax elasticity below
equilibrium 0.217 2.180
Personal income tax adjustment parameter above
equilibrium -0.618 0.192
Personal income tax adjustment parameter below
equilibrium -0.411 0.090
Table 3. Sales Tax Elasticities
Short-Run Elasticities
Long-Run When Current When Current
Elasticity Revenue Value is Revenue Value is
below Long-Run above Long-Run
Equilibrium Equilibrium
Alabama 0.712 ** 0.050# 1.120# **
Arizona 0.744 ** -1.232 ** 1.452#^ **
Arkansas 0.835 ** 0.323 1.398#^ **
California 0.833 ** -1.408 ** 1.146# **
Colorado 0.781 ** 1.869^ ** 1.869^ **
Connecticut 1.242 ** 1.152# ** 2.781^~ **
Florida 0.926 ** -0.049 1.445#^ **
Georgia 0.708 ** 0.171 1.209# **
Hawaii 1.110 ** 0.629 ** 1.285# **
Idaho 0.847 ** 0.665# ** 1.456#^ **
Illinois 0.871# ** 0.028# 0.028#
Indiana -- 0.723 * 0.723 *
Iowa 0.374 ** -0.056 0.853# **
Kentucky 0.654 ** 0.826# ** 0.826# **
Kansas 0.630 ** 0.466# * 0.466# *
Louisiana 0.514 ** -0.347 1.531#^ **
Maine 0.904 ** -0.857 1.047^
Maryland 0.767 ** 1.162# ** 1.162#^ **
Massachusetts 1.365 ** 0.354# 2.375^~ **
Michigan 0.772 ** -0.017 1.713#^ **
Minnesota 0.876 ** -0.226 0.903# **
Mississippi 0.486 ** -0.188# 1.340#^ **
Missouri 0.639 ** -2.192 ** 0.907# *
Nebraska 0.431 * 0.191 18.779 **
Nevada 0.781 ** -0.500 1.600#^ **
New Jersey 1.049# ** -0.297 1.552#^ **
New Mexico 0.924# ** -0.628# 3.070^~ **
New York 0.750 0.128 1.571 **
North Carolina 0.874 0.501# 1.820^ **
North Dakota 0.339 0.256^ -0.506 *
Ohio 1.033# ** 1.802^ ** 1.802^ **
Oklahoma 0.695 ** 1.890^ ** 1.890^ **
Pennsylvania 1.069# ** 1.504#^ ** 1.504#^ **
Rhode Island 0.531 ** 0.515# 1.848 **
South Carolina 0.773 ** -1.150# 1.143# **
South Dakota 1.145 ** 0.471 ** 0.471# **
Tennessee 0.716 ** 0.308 1.271# **
Texas 0.997# ** 1.580 ** 1.580#^ **
Utah 0.873 ** -1.544 1.780^ **
Virginia 0.800 ** -0.645 0.826# **
Vermont 0.735 ** 0.779#^ 2.289^~ **
Washington 0.740 ** 0.045# 1.722#^ **
West Virginia 1.013# ** -1.146#^ 3.295#^ **
Wisconsin 1.113# ** -0.623# 1.373^~
Wyoming 0.720# ** 1.443#^ ** 1.443#^ **
Speed of Adjustment
When Current When Current
Revenue Value is Revenue Value is
below Long-Run above Long-Run
Equilibrium Equilibrium
Alabama -0.152 -0.152
Arizona -0.742@ ** -0.742@ **
Arkansas -0.915@ ** -0.113
California -1.874@ ** -0.193
Colorado -0.183 * -0.183 *
Connecticut -0.168 * -0.168 *
Florida -0.528 ** -0.528 **
Georgia -0.263 ** -0.263 **
Hawaii -0.476 ** -0.476 **
Idaho -0.246 ** -0.246 **
Illinois -0.226 -0.226
Indiana -- --
Iowa -0.850@ ** -0.850@ **
Kentucky -0.255 ** -0.255 **
Kansas -0.119 -0.119
Louisiana -0.182 -0.182 *
Maine -0.380 ** -0.380 **
Maryland -0.154 -0.154
Massachusetts -0.320 ** -0.320 **
Michigan -0.511 ** -0.511 **
Minnesota -1.082@ ** -0.409 *
Mississippi -0.262 * -0.262 *
Missouri -0.612 ** -0.612 **
Nebraska -0.905@ ** -0.905@ **
Nevada -0.506 ** -0.506 **
New Jersey -0.601 ** -0.601 **
New Mexico -1.188@ ** -0.399 *
New York -0.438 ** -0.438 **
North Carolina -1.045 ** -0.124
North Dakota -0.483 ** 0.260
Ohio -0.357 ** -0.357 **
Oklahoma -0.124 * -0.124 *
Pennsylvania -0.216 ** -0.216 **
Rhode Island -0.124 -0.124
South Carolina -0.510 ** -0.510 **
South Dakota -0.562 ** -0.562 **
Tennessee -0.240 * -0.240 *
Texas -0.749@ ** -0.749@ **
Utah -0.234 ** -0.234 **
Virginia -0.293 ** -0.293 **
Vermont -0.840@ ** -0.061
Washington -1.404@ ** -0.546 **
West Virginia -0.829@ ** -0.106
Wisconsin -0.289 ** -0.289 **
Wyoming -0.134 -0.134
Bold, italicized, and underlined type indicate statistically
significant differences from one, two, and three, respectively,
at the 5% level. Bold type for speed of adjustment results indicates
that the coefficient is not statistically different from -1.0.
* Statistically significant differences from zero at the 10% level.
** Statistically significant differences from zero at the 5% level.
Note: Indicate statistically significant differences from one at the
5% level indicated with #.
Note: Indicate statistically significant differences from two at the
5% level ^.
Note: Indicate statistically significant differences from three at
the 5% level ~.
Note: Speed of adjustment results indicates that the coefficient is
not statistically different from -1.0 indicated with @.
Table 4. Personal Income Tax Elasticities
Short-Run Elasticities
When Current When Current
Revenue Value is Revenue Value is
Long-Run Below Long-Run Above Long-Run
Elasticity Equilibrium Equilibrium
Alabama 1.823 ** 1.393#^ ** 3.009^~ **
Arizona 1.140#^ ** 0.768# ** 0.768# **
Arkansas 2.102 ** 0.833# 0.833#
California 1.749 ** -1.536# 3.223~ **
Colorado 1.256 ** -1.040 0.962#^ *
Delaware 1.018# ** -0.885 1.088#^ *
Georgia 1.690 ** 0.130# 1.199#^ **
Hawaii 1.320 ** -0.786 2.013^ **
Idaho 1.565 ** -0.001 2.382^~ **
Illinois 1.565 ** 0.298# 2.882^~ **
Indiana 2.435 ** -0.783 1.702#^ **
Iowa 2.349 ** 1.176#^ ** -2.679#
Kentucky 2.600 ** 0.465# 0.465#
Kansas 2.260 ** 0.461# 6.223^~ **
Louisiana 2.272 ** 1.123#^~ 8.938 **
Maine 2.873~ ** 0.403# 2.639^~ **
Maryland 1.183 ** 0.510# * 1.986^ **
Massachusetts 1.415 ** 0.538# 1.660#^ **
Michigan 1.879^ ** 0.570 3.210^~ **
Minnesota 1.320 ** -0.128 2.300#^ **
Mississippi 1.910 ** 2.400#^~ ** 2.400#^ **
Missouri 2.292 ** 0.046# 6.242 **
Montana 1.604 ** -0.486#^ 2.313^~ **
Nebraska 2.491 ** 1.170#^ * 1.170#^ *
New Jersey 2.016^ ** -0.195# 2.031#^~ **
New Mexico 3.024^~ ** -6.223#^~ 8.370#^~ *
New York 1.295 ** -1.169 * 2.160^~ **
North Carolina 1.545 ** 0.767# ** 2.505^~ **
North Dakota 0.809#^ 0.197# 0.197#
Ohio 3.983~ ** -2.479 2.529#^~ *
Oklahoma 2.613 ** 1.731#^ ** 4.250~ **
Oregon 1.440 ** 0.100# 4.333^~ **
Pennsylvania 1.431 ** 2.042#^ ** 5.736 **
Rhode Island 1.756 ** 2.344^ ** 2.344^~ **
South Carolina 1.564 ** 1.536#^ ** 1.536#^ **
Utah 1.477 ** 1.379#^ ** 1.379#^ **
Virginia 1.474 ** 0.140# 1.775^ **
Vermont 0.974# ** 0.218#^ 0.218#^
West Virginia 2.569 ** 1.681#^~ * 4.770~ **
Wisconsin 1.215 ** 0.186# 2.534^~ **
Speed of Adjustment
When Current When Current
Revenue Value is Revenue Value is
Below Long-Run Above Long-Run
Equilibrium Equilibrium
Alabama -0.221 -1.216@ **
Arizona -0.271 ** -0.271 **
Arkansas -0.508 ** -0.508 **
California -0.718 ** -0.718 **
Colorado -0.181 * -0.181
Delaware -0.174 * -0.174 *
Georgia -0.172 ** -0.172 **
Hawaii -0.667 ** -0.667 **
Idaho -0.683@ ** -0.683@ **
Illinois -1.017@ ** -1.017@ **
Indiana 0.445 -0.611@ **
Iowa -0.256 ** -0.256 **
Kentucky 0.015 0.015
Kansas -0.609 ** -0.609 **
Louisiana -0.292 * -1.176@ **
Maine -0.051@ -1.638 **
Maryland -0.814 ** -0.814 **
Massachusetts -0.248 ** -1.548@ **
Michigan -0.366 ** -0.366 **
Minnesota -0.262 -0.930@ **
Mississippi -0.563 ** -0.563 **
Missouri -0.370 ** -1.784 **
Montana -0.392 ** -0.392 **
Nebraska -0.811@ ** -0.811@ **
New Jersey -0.470 ** -0.470 **
New Mexico -0.207 ** -0.207 **
New York -0.309 ** -0.309 **
North Carolina -0.265 ** -1.181@ **
North Dakota -0.298 ** -0.298 **
Ohio -0.956@ ** -0.136
Oklahoma -0.434 ** -0.434 **
Oregon -0.991@ ** -0.991@ **
Pennsylvania -0.312 ** 0.064
Rhode Island -0.841@ ** -0.311 *
South Carolina -0.550 ** -0.550 **
Utah -0.827@ ** -0.827@ **
Virginia -0.655@ ** -0.655@ **
Vermont -0.549 ** -0.549 **
West Virginia -0.296 ** -0.296 **
Wisconsin -0.485 ** -0.485 **
Bold, italicized, and underlined type indicate statistically
significant differences from one, two, and three, respectively,
at the 5% level. Bold type for speed of adjustment results indicates
that the coefficient is not statistically different from -1.0.
* Statistically significant differences from zero at the 10% level.
** Statistically significant differences from zero at the 5% level.
Note: Indicate statistically significant differences from one at the
5% level indicated with #.
Note: Indicate statistically significant differences from two at the
5% level indicated with ^.
Note: Indicate statistically significant differences from three at the
5% level indicated with ~.
Note: Speed of adjustment results indicates that the coefficient is
not statistically different from -1.0. indicated with @.
Table 5. Cross-Sectional Analysis of Long-Run Elasticities
1999 Values
Variable Income Sales
Lowest income in highest
PIT bracket
($ thousand) (a) -0.003 ** (0.001)
EITC dummy -0.273
Capital gains/personal
income 17.253
Progressivity at median
income 87.567
Partial exemption for
government pensions -0.920 ** (0.392)
Total exemption for
government pensions -0.656 * (0.314)
Partial exemption for
private pensions 0.792 ** (0.294)
Total exemption for private
pensions -0.768 * (0.398)
Average change in top PIT
rate (1970-1999) 25.723 * (12.132)
ST base/personal income 0.952 ** (0.451)
Consumer share of ST 0.012 * (0.006)
Percentage of population
under 18 years of age (a) 33.490 ** (7.856) 0.477 (2.913)
Percentage of population
over 65 years of age (b) 27.771 ** (8.233) 1.854 (3.030)
Median income
($ thousands) (a) -0.052 ** (0.021) 0.017 ** (0.007)
Republican legislature 0.660 * (0.353) 0.119 (0.128)
Democratic legislature -0.284 (0.262) 0.180 (0.121)
Republican governor -0.329 (0.300) 0.026 (0.078)
Mining share of GSP (b) -9.560 (7.270) 3.677 (2.398)
Average annual employment
growth (1970-1999) -4.808 (9.670) 0.471 (2.010)
Standard deviation of
employment growth
(1970-1999) 23.860 ** (10.624) 0.548 (4.486)
Manufacturing share of
GSP (b) -1.065 (2.689) 1.768 (1.347)
Services share of GSP (b) -18.081 (17.737) 5.585 (3.966)
Agriculture share of
GSP (b) -35.335 (21.218) 4.669 (6.815)
Constant -4.657 (4.140) -3.220 (1.903)
N 35 43
[R.sup.2] 0.601 0.060
1970-1999 Changes
Variable Income Sales
Lowest income in highest
PIT bracket
($ thousand) (a) 1.935 (359.289)
EITC dummy -0.395 (0.275)
Capital gains/personal
income -739.067 ** (289.629)
Progressivity at median
income 433.921 (1916.552)
Partial exemption for
government pensions -1.039 ** (0.447)
Total exemption for
government pensions -0.306 (0.374)
Partial exemption for
private pensions 0.576 (0.350)
Total exemption for private
pensions -0.557 (0.420)
Average change in top PIT
rate (1970-1999) 30.602 ** (12.405)
ST base/personal income -1.967 ** (0.836)
Consumer share of ST -0.006 (0.005)
Percentage of population
under 18 years of age (a) -2.785 (3.787) 0.386 (1.103)
Percentage of population
over 65 years of age (b) -0.334 (0.983) -0.070 (0.304)
Median income
($ thousands) (a) -15.467 (12.968) 1.730 (4.460)
Republican legislature 0.515 * (0.254) -0.047 (0.108)
Democratic legislature -0.136 (0.289) 0.021 (0.125)
Republican governor 0.011 (0.333) 0.007 (0.086)
Mining share of GSP (b) -5.313 (3.592) 0.738 (1.360)
Average annual employment
growth (1970-1999) -8.002 (8.158) 0.972 (2.234)
Standard deviation of
employment growth
(1970-1999) 26.263 * (12.747) -2.25 (6.265)
Manufacturing share of
GSP (b) 38.594 (105.490) -24.319 (31.092)
Services share of GSP (b) -45.028 * (23.391) -4.984 (5.645)
Agriculture share of
GSP (b) 0.738 (22.500) 1.806 (4.705)
Constant 5.343 ** (1.869) 1.288 ** (0.618)
N 35 43
[R.sup.2] 0.517 0.047
Entries are ordinary least-squares regression coefficients with White
(1980) standard errors in parentheses.
(a) Variable enters 1970-1999 Changes specifications as the change
from 1970 to 1999.
(b) Variable enters 1979-1999 Changes specifications as the average
change from 1970 to 1999.
* Statistically significant at 10% and above.
** Statistically significant at 5% and above.