Discounting according to output type.
Saving, Thomas R.
1. Introduction
Although the importance of discount rate choice for multiperiod
public project evaluation is well understood, the theoretical literature
on the appropriate discount rate is inconclusive. Specifically, what the
discount rate should be when corporate taxes and personal income taxes
create a wedge between gross (before tax) and net (after tax) rates of
return is unresolved. (1) For example, Baumol (1968), Usher (1969),
Sandmo and Dreze (1971), and Harberger (1973) suggested a "weighted
average" approach, in which they envisioned that the so-called
"social discount rate" was a weighted average of gross and net
rates of return, with weights determined by the fractions of resources
drawn from consumption and private investment, respectively. For the
special case in which the gross rate of return (the marginal
productivity of capital) is exogenous, public investment would come
entirely from the displacement of private capital, and the social
discount rate equals the gross rate of return. Diamond and Mirrlees
(1971) also concluded that the public sector discount rate should equal
the gross return. However, Diamond and Mirrlees made an important
assumption that the tax system is optimized (in the sense of the second
best) over a sufficiently rich set of tax instruments (say, a full range
of commodity taxes), an assumption that is not satisfied by most studies
on the public sector discount rate. On the other hand, Marglin (1963),
Feldstein (1964), Bradford (1975), and Lind (1982) proposed a
"shadow price of capital" approach, in which they insisted
that future benefits be discounted at the net rate of return, but that
costs be multiplied by a scale factor first, and then the resulting
consumption equivalent costs also be discounted at the net rate. (2)
Reflecting this lack of theoretical consensus, U.S. federal
government oversight agencies, in setting their respective discount rate
policies, do not seem to follow any particular theory. Two alternative
discount rates have emerged as policy recommendations by these agencies
(Lyon 1990). A high rate of 7%, approximating the marginal productivity
of capital, has been adopted by the Office of Management and Budget,
while a low rate of 2-3%, approximating the federal borrowing rate, has
been adopted by the General Accounting Office, the Congressional Budget
Office, and the U.S. Water Resources Council. These differential
discount rate policies could be inconsistent and biased in favor of a
certain project on which the lower discount rate is applied.
This paper provides a justification for the coexistence of
different discount rates by considering alternative types of project
outputs. We focus on two special types of public project outputs:
publicly provided goods that are perfect substitutes for private goods
and publicly provided goods that enter individual utility functions in a
separable fashion. Using a simple multiperiod project evaluation
framework, we show that the appropriate discount rate for a public
project depends on the nature of a project's outputs. If a
project's outputs are perfect substitutes for private goods, future
benefits should be discounted by the gross (before tax) rate of return.
However, if a project produces utility-separable outputs, future
benefits should be discounted by the net (after tax) rate of return.
2. A Simple Project Evaluation Framework with Two Types of Project
Outputs
Since our focus is efficiency rather than inter- or
intragenerational equity, we take the liberty of considering an economy
consisting of identical, forever-living individuals. In each period,
individuals consume a composite private good (treated as numeraire for
each period) and two types of publicly provided goods. The first type is
a perfect substitute for same-period private goods, and the second type
enters individual utility functions in a weakly separable way.
Therefore, individual utility functions can be written as
v(c, Q, G) [equivalent to] f [u(c + Q), G], (1)
where c = ([c.sub.0], [c.sub.1], ...), Q = ([Q.sub.0], [Q.sub.1],
...), and G = ([G.sub.0], [G.sub.1], ...) are, respectively, infinite
dimensional vectors of private good consumption and type-one and
type-two publicly provided goods.
For given Q and G, an individual's utility maximization
problem can be stated as
max v(c, Q, G)
s.t. [a.sub.t] = [a.sub.t-1] (1 + [r.sub.n]) + [y.sub.t] -
[L.sub.t] - [c.sub.t], t = 0,1, ..., (2)
where [a.sub.t] is the end-of-period t per capita wealth (including
both productive capital and government bonds) after wage and interest
income (net of taxes) have been earned and consumption has occurred,
[r.sub.n] is net (after tax) rate of return on productive capital, and
[y.sub.t] and [L.sub.t] are, respectively, period t wage earnings and
lump-sum taxes. We assume a world of certainty, so that the after-tax
bond interest rate is also [r.sub.n]. Let [a.sub.-1] be individual
wealth one period before the decision making period (which is period 0),
so that individual initial wealth is A = [a.sub.-1] (1 + [r.sub.n]).
The government collects lump-sum taxes and taxes on capital income
to finance a preaccepted set of multiperiod public projects. These
projects combined require a stream of (per capita) investments
represented by the vector I = ([I.sub.0], [I.sub.1], ...) and generate a
stream of two types of output, Q and G. Revenue per capita collected in
period t is
[R.sub.t] = [b.sub.t-1]([r.sub.b] - [r.sub.n]) + [k.sub.t-1]
([r.sub.g] - [r.sub.n]) + [L.sub.t] (3)
where [b.sub.t-1] and [k.sub.t-1] are, respectively, end-of-period
t - 1 per capita government debt and private capital, and [r.sub.b] and
[r.sub.g] are, respectively, the before-tax interest rate on bonds and
the marginal productivity of capital, that is, the gross (before tax)
rate of return.
Since government can borrow, [R.sub.t] and [I.sub.t] need not be
equal. Government debt per capita at the end of period t, [b.sub.t],
evolves according to
[b.sub.t] = [b.sub.t-1] (1 + [r.sub.b]) + [I.sub.t] - [R.sub.t], t
= 0, 1, ..., (4)
where [b.sub.-1] is inherited per capita debt. Individual wealth
consists of government bonds and productive capital, so that
[a.sub.t-1] = [b.sub.t-1] + [k.sub.t-1]. (5)
Substituting Equations 3 and 5 into Equation 4, the
government's intertemporal budget constraints can be rewritten as
[b.sub.t] = [b.sub.t-1] (1 + [r.sub.g]) + [I.sub.t] - [L.sub.t] -
[a.sub.t-1] ([r.sub.g] - [r.sub.n]), t = 0,1, ..., (6)
which are equivalent to (3)
B + [[infinity].summation over t=0] [I.sub.t]/ [(1 +
[r.sub.g]).sup.t] = [[infinity].summation over t=0] [L.sub.t] +
[a.sub.t-1] ([r.sub.g] - [r.sub.n])/ [(1 + [r.sub.g]).sup.t] (7)
where B = [b.sub.-l] (1 + [r.sub.g]).
At the beginning of period 0, the government is committed to the
preaccepted public sector production plan (I, Q, G). The concern of this
paper is how a new, marginal project, denoted as ([DELTA]I, [DELTA]Q,
[DELTA]G), is evaluated such that the representative individual
experiences an increase in welfare. (4)
3. Differential Discount Rates Based on Project Output Type
According to the shadow price principle, the evaluation of a
marginal project ([DELTA]I, [DELTA]Q, [DELTA]G) that is consistent with
welfare maximization requires shadow prices for [I.sub.t], t [member of]
{0, 1, ...}, [Q.sub.t], t [member of] {0, 1, ...}, and [G.sub.t], t
[member of] {0, 1, ...}. Denoting these shadow prices, respectively, as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], and [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], a project that is generally represented by
([DELTA]I, [DELTA]Q, [DELTA]G) enhances welfare if and only if
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (8)
In the following paragraphs, we focus on the relationship within,
as well as among, these three sets of shadow prices. Our approach to the
discount rate issue is based on the relationship among shadow prices in
different periods. Since the shadow price of a public sector input
(output)--here, [I.sub.t] represents public sector inputs, whereas
[Q.sub.t] and [G.sub.t] are public sector outputs--is defined as the
welfare effect of a unit increase in the net demand (supply) of that
input (output) by the public sector, we must first know how individual
welfare is affected by various fiscal parameters representing taxation
and public sector inputs and outputs.
Expressing the constraints in Equation 2 equivalently as (5)
[[infinity].summation over t=0] [c.sub.t]/ [(1 + [r.sub.n]).sup.t]
= A + [[infinity].summation over t=0] [y.sub.t] - [L.sub.t]/[(1 +
[r.sub.n])].sup.t], (9)
the Lagrange function of the individual's problem is
[psi] = v(c, Q, G) + [lambda] [A + [[infinity].summation over t=0]
[y.sub.t] - [L.sub.t] - [c.sub.t]/ [(1 + [r.sub.n]).sup.t]].
Optimization requires
[differential]v/[differential[c.sub.t] = [lambda]/ [(1 +
[r.sub.n]).sup.t], t = 0, 1, ..., (10)
where [lambda] is the marginal utility of initial wealth A. Noting
the weak separability of G in v and letting L = ([L.sub.0], [L.sub.1],
...) be the infinite dimensional vector of lump-sum taxes, we can
express the solution to the individual's problem as [c.sub.t](Q,
L), t = 0, 1, ..., so that, from Equation 2, we have [a.sub.t](Q, L), t
= 0, 1, .... (6) Denoting the value function (indirect utility)
resulting from the individual's maximization problem as M(Q, G, L),
we have, from the Envelope Theorem,
[differential]M/[differential] [Q.sub.t] = [differential]v/
[differential][Q.sub.t] = [differential]v/[differential][c.sub.t],
[differential]M/[differential][G.sub.t] = [differential]v/
[differential][G.sub.t], [differential]M/[differential][L.sub.t] =
-[lambda]/ [(1 + [r.sub.n]).sup.t]. (11)
For a preexisting public sector production plan (I, Q, G) to be
fiscally feasible, the stream of lump-sum taxes L must satisfy the
government intertemporal budget constraint (Eqn. 7). When consideration
is given to adding a new marginal project ([DELTA]I, [DELTA]Q, [DELTA]G)
to the public sector's production plan, one of the [L.sub.t]'s
or some combination of them must be increased to satisfy the government
budget constraint. The particular values of these shadow prices depend
on the form of marginal financing and the measuring unit. (7) Assuming
[L.sub.i], i [member of] {0, 1, ...} is increased to meet any additional
project revenue requirement and using the numeraire good in period 0 as
the measuring unit, we can calculate the three sets of shadow prices as
follows:
First, the impact of a marginal increase in [I.sub.t] on [L.sub.i]
is obtained by differentiating both sides of Equation 7 with respect to
[I.sub.t], taking [L.sub.i] as a function of [I.sub.t]. The impact of a
marginal increase in [Q.sub.t] and [G.sub.t] on [L.sub.i] can be
obtained in a similar way. Therefore, we have, for any t,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (12)
where
[OMEGA] = [(1 + [r.sub.g]).sup.-i] + [[infinity].summation over
(j=0)] ([r.sub.g] - [r.sub.n]) [differential][a.sub.j-1]/[differential]
[L.sub.i][(1 + [r.sub.g]).sup.j].
Note that [differential][L.sub.i]/[differential][G.sub.t] = 0,
since utility-separability implies that G does not directly affect
individual consumption decisions and therefore also leaves unaffected
the government budget constraint (Eqn. 7).
The shadow prices of [I.sub.t], [Q.sub.t], and [G.sub.t] measured
in terms of the numeraire good in period 0 when the marginal financing
features an increase in [L.sub.i] are, respectively,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (13)
The last equality in each of the equations of Equation 13 is
obtained by substituting relevant expressions from Equations 10, 11, and
12. In Appendix II, we prove the following lemma:
LEMMA. [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
The lemma indicates that the welfare effect of increasing
government's investment in a period is equivalent to reducing the
publicly provided private good in the period by the same amount. This
result is intuitive for the following reason. Note first that the lemma
is the same as saying that there is no net welfare effect by increasing
both [I.sub.t] and [Q.sub.t] by one unit. With no loss of generality,
suppose that the one-unit increase in [I.sub.t] is realized through an
increase in period t lump-sum tax, [L.sub.t]. By how much should
[L.sub.t] be increased? The answer is exactly one unit because, along
with the one-unit increase in [Q.sub.t], the one-unit increase in
[L.sub.t] will cover the one-unit increase in [I.sub.t] without
generating revenue externalities in any other periods. Of course,
increasing both [L.sub.t] and [Q.sub.t] by one unit does not have any
net welfare effect since both are perfect substitutes for income.
Using the lemma and the shadow price expressions of Equation 13, we
can see how future costs and benefits of public projects should be
discounted, with an emphasis on the type of project outputs.
The [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] expression
in Equation 13 indicates that the ratio of the shadow price of public
investment in period t+1 to that in period t is [(1 +
[r.sub.g]).sup.-1]. This implies that the appropriate discount rate for
future project costs is the gross rate of return. The appropriate
discount rate for future project benefits depends on the nature of
project outputs. Specifically, if a project's outputs are perfect
substitutes to private consumption goods, then project benefits in
period t--directly measured by project outputs [DELTA][Q.sub.t] because
they are perfect substitutes for period t private consumption [c.sub.t],
which is the period's numeraire--should be discounted at the gross
rate of return. This is the implication of the lemma and the above
conclusion that the gross rate of return is right for the discounting of
future costs. In addition, the lemma implies that the project benefits
[DELTA][Q.sub.t] can be "netted out" against same-period
investments [DELTA][I.sub.t]. On the other hand, if a project's
outputs are separable in individual utility functions, then project
benefits, conventionally measured by individual willingness to pay ([differential]v/ [differential][G.sub.t]/[differential]v/[differential][c.sub.t]) [DELTA][G.sub.t], should be discounted at the net rate of
return. This is the implication of the [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] expression in Equation 13. Since costs and
benefits are discounted at different rates of return for a project that
produces utility-separable outputs, project benefits cannot be netted
out against same-period investments. Moreover, for a project producing
utility-separable outputs, the present value of its costs must be
multiplied by [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] before
it is compared with the present value of the project's benefits.
Another interesting implication of our analysis is that the
government borrowing rate [r.sub.b] is irrelevant for discount rate
choice, regardless of the type of project outputs. In our model, the
borrowing rate is determined by the tax policy given to bond returns.
For example, [r.sub.b] = [r.sub.g] if bond returns are taxed as heavily
as the returns on physical capital, but [r.sub.b] = [r.sub.n] if bond
returns are tax exempted. However, how much the government decides to
tax bond returns, and therefore the borrowing rate, has no real
implication for the intertemporal trade-off in either the individual
budget constraint 9 or the government budget constraint 7.
The above results can be summarized into the following proposition:
PROPOSITION. Given the assumptions in our simple multiperiod
framework for project evaluation, (i) future costs should be discounted
at the gross rate of return; (ii) for a project that produces outputs
that are perfect substitutes to private goods, future benefits should be
discounted at the gross rate of return, and benefits can be netted out
against costs in the same period; (iii) for a project that produces
outputs that are (weakly) separable in the individual utility function,
future benefits should be discounted at the net rate of return, and
benefits cannot be netted out against costs in the same period; and (iv)
government borrowing rate per se has no role to play in discount rate
choice.
Some intuitive explanations for our main result, which is that the
appropriate discount rate for a project's future benefits depends
on the type of project output, may be helpful. First, if a project
produces outputs that are perfect substitutes for private consumption in
various periods, then it can be generally represented by
([{[DELTA][I.sub.t]}.sup.[infinity].sub.t=0],
[{[DELTA][Q.sub.t]}.sup.[infinity].sub.t=0]). Now, let us compare this
target project with a hypothetical project that has the same output
stream as the target project and an investment stream that is identical
to the output stream, which can be represented by
([{[DELTA][Q.sub.t]}.sup.[infinity].sub.t=0],
[{[DELTA][Q.sub.t]}.sup.[infinity].sub.t=0]). For the same intuitive
argument we gave after the lemma, the hypothetical project is
welfare-neutral. The only difference between the target project and the
hypothetical project is that they have different investment streams
-[{[DELTA][I.sub.t]}.sup.[infinity].sub.t=0] for the target project and
[{[DELTA][Q.sub.t]}.sup.[infinity].sub.t=0] for the hypothetical
project. Between the target and the hypothetical projects, the one with
the lower present value of investment stream at the gross rate of return
(the discount rate in the government budget constraint) is
welfare-dominant. In other words, the target project is welfare
enhancing if and only if [[infinity].summation over (t=0)]
[DELTA][Q.sub.t][(1 + [r.sub.g]).sup.-t] > [[infinity].summation over
(t=0)] [DELTA][I.sub.t] [(1 + [r.sub.g]).sup.-t]. Therefore, for a
project that produces perfect substitutes for private consumption, its
future benefits [{[DELTA][Q.sub.t]}.sup.[infinity].sub.t=0] should be
discounted at the gross rate of return. Second, if a project produces
outputs that are separable in the utility function, then it can be
generally represented by ([{[DELTA][I.sub.t]}.sup.[infinity].sub.t=0],
[{[DELTA][G.sub.t]}.sup.[infinity].sub.t=0]). Outputs
[{[DELTA][G.sub.t]}.sup.[infinity].sub.t=0] do not have any effects on
individual behaviors and, as a result, leave unaffected tax revenues in
each and every period. Therefore, the only welfare effects from these
project outputs are an individual's willingness to pay in various
periods, ([differential]v/[differential][G.sub.t]/[differential]v/
[differential][c.sub.t]) [DELTA][G.sub.t] in period t in terms of units
of [c.sub.t]. Optimization by the individuals means that the
intertemporal trade-off of private good is the net-of-tax interest rate
[r.sub.n]. Therefore, for a project that produces utility-separable
outputs, its future benefits
[{([differential]v/[differential][G.sub.t]/[differential]v/
[differential][c.sub.t]) [DELTA][G.sub.t]}.sup.[infinity].sub.t=0]
should be discounted at the net rate of return.
The results in the proposition show that the discount rate for
evaluating the benefits of a public project can vary systematically with
the type of output it produces. Indeed, the results are so clear-cut
that the appropriate discount rates are the gross and net rates of
return, respectively, for the two output types considered in this paper.
A query may arise as to which assumptions are responsible for the
results being so clear-cut and how the results would be modified if
restrictive assumptions were relaxed. (8)
The first major assumption we have made is that the outputs of any
public project fall into one of two categories: outputs that are perfect
substitutes for private goods and outputs that are separable in the
utility function. While utility-separable publicly provided goods and
publicly provided private goods are the two most often used
specifications in literature, there also exist projects whose outputs
cannot be classified into either of these two categories. What can be
said about how future benefits from these more general project outputs
should be discounted? Liu (2003) advocates an approach that proposes
discounting all future benefits of a project--regardless of the type of
the project's outputs--at the net rate of return and incorporating
any effects on tax revenues from the project's outputs into
analysis as negative costs in various periods. Therefore, the output
type also matters in Liu (2003), but its effects are included in
analysis through the revenue effects rather than manifested in
differential discount rates. Since the approach in Liu (2003) can be
applied to any type of project output, it is more general than the
approach presented in our study. However, that more general approach
would require project-specific information (on revenue effects) above
and beyond the conventional cost and benefit measurements. By focusing
on two specific types of project outputs, this paper shows how
differential discount rates can coexist. Importantly, our approach
requires only traditional cost-benefit information: project costs and
consumer willingness to pay in various periods.
The second major assumption is that marginal projects are financed
by the lump-sum tax along with government borrowing, whereas the capital
income tax policy is taken as fixed. Although this assumption is typical
in the social discount rate literature, Pestieau (1975) has shown that
different tax structures may call on different discount rates. While the
appropriate discount rates to use will not change with the tax structure
or the marginal tax instrument in Liu (2003), the marginal cost of funds
parameter in Liu's rule is determined by the tax structure and the
marginal tax instrument. (9) Allowing a more complicated tax structure
(that is, a distortionary tax system with both capital and labor income
taxes, along with variable labor supply) alone would not alter our
clear-cut quantitative results as long as marginal projects are financed
by changes in lump-sum taxes along with government borrowing. However,
marginal lump-sum tax financing is a critical assumption underlying our
quantitative results. Nevertheless, our qualitative conclusion, which is
that the type of public project outputs affects the discount rate for
evaluating future benefits in a systematic way, remains the same.
The third major assumption is that the before-tax rate of return to
capital is exogenous. This assumption is, of course, quite restrictive.
However, it is very hard to deal with interest rate endogeneity in a
multiperiod environment in which there is more than one interest rate.
(10) Importantly, this simplifying assumption does not make the debate
over the choice between the net and the gross rates disappear. For
example, the weighted average approach would generate the gross rate of
return as the correct discount rate when interest rates are exogenous,
because public funds are obtained entirely from the displacement of
private capital in this situation. On the other hand, the shadow price
of capital approach would still recommend using the net rate of return
for evaluating future benefits.
4. Conclusion
In this paper, we justify the use of different discount rates in
evaluating government projects on the basis of the type of output
produced. The marginal productivity of capital (the gross rate of
return) is appropriate for discounting future benefits when project
outputs are perfect substitutes to private consumption goods. In
contrast, the net rate of return (which is also the government borrowing
rate if bond yields are tax exempt) is appropriate for discounting
future benefits if project outputs are utility-separable. The output
type also has implications for whether project benefits can be netted
out against same-period project costs.
Utility-separable publicly provided goods and publicly provided
goods that are perfect substitutes for private goods are the two
dominant specifications in the (static) literature of public good
provision. A critical concept in that literature is the marginal cost of
funds. It has been shown that the value of the marginal cost of funds
for a given tax instrument depends on whether the public goods are
separable or perfect substitutes for private goods. (11) Using a dynamic
(multiperiod) framework, this paper shows that such a distinction
between the two output types is also critical to the choice of the
appropriate discount rate for the evaluation of a project's future
benefits. Then, of course, there is a question of how to decide whether
a particular project will generate a perfect substitute for private
consumption or an output that is separable in the utility function. We
suggest that if an output can also be bought by individuals from market,
it can be regarded as a perfect substitute of private consumption. On
the other hand, if an output does not seem to affect an
individual's choices, such as savings, labor supply, and
consumption (that is, outputs generated by space exploration projects),
then it can be regarded as separable in the utility function.
Although this paper provides a justification for the coexistence of
different discount rates by resorting to different types of project
outputs, it does not provide a rationale for existing differences in
government discount rates. (12) The two rates described as main
alternatives in U.S. government practice are not the two rates
identified in our theoretical analysis. Risk has a lot to do with the
difference between the 7% high discount rate and the 2% low discount
rate used by the federal oversight agencies. Only the differences due to
taxes are relevant to the argument of this paper. Then, what are the
risk-free gross and net rates of return, [r.sub.g] and [r.sub.n]? The
Trustees of the Social Security System currently use 2.8% for their
long-term estimate of real returns (6.3% of special-issue U.S. Treasury obligations minus 3.5% long-term inflation rate). To arrive at the
risk-free gross rate of return, the 2.8% bond rate must be adjusted
upward to incorporate the corporate income tax effect. The corporate
income tax rate must reflect levies on corporations at the federal,
state, and local levels. Feldstein (1998) suggests that the total
corporate income tax rate is about 40%, implying a risk-free gross rate
of return of [r.sub.g] = 4.7%. Using the 40% corporate income tax rate
and the 20% personal income tax rate, the total levy on capital income
is 52%. This, together with [r.sub.g] = 4.7%, implies that [r.sub.n] =
2.3%.
Appendix I: A Formal Demonstration of the Equivalence between the
Government Budget Constraints 6 and 7
Consider the first t + 1 equations of those represented by Equation
6:
[b.sub.0] = [b.sub.-1](1 + [r.sub.g]) + [I.sub.0] - [L.sub.0] -
[a.sub.-1] ([r.sub.g] - [r.sub.n]), [b.sub.1] = [b.sub.0](1 + [r.sub.g])
+ [I.sub.1] - [L.sub.1] - [a.sub.0]([r.sub.g] - [r.sub.n]),
...
[b.sub.t-1] = [b.sub.t-2](1 + [r.sub.g]) + [I.sub.t-1] -
[L.sub.t-1] - [a.sub.t-2] ([r.sub.g] - [r.sub.n]), [b.sub.t] =
[b.sub.t-1](1 + [r.sub.g]) + [I.sub.t] - [L.sub.t] - [a.sub.t-1]
([r.sub.g] - [r.sub.n]).
First, divide the equation (both sides of it) beginning with
[b.sub.0] by [(1 + [r.sub.g]).sup.0], the equation beginning with
[b.sub.1] by [(1 + [r.sub.g]).sup.1].... Then, add the left sides and
the right sides of the resulting equations, respectively. Noting that
the intermediate b items ([b.sub.0], [b.sub.1], ..., [b.sub.t-1]) on the
both sides of the final equation cancel out, we have
[b.sub.t]/[(1 + [r.sub.g]).sup.t] = [b.sub.-1] (1 + [r.sub.g]) +
[t.summation over(k=0)] [[I.sub.k] - [L.sub.k] - [a.sub.k-1]([r.sub.g] -
[r.sub.n])/ [(1 + [r.sub.g]).sup.k]].
Under the condition [lim.sub.t [right arrow] [infinity]] [b.sub.t]
[(1 + [r.sub.g]).sup.-t] = 0 (no Ponzi Game), we have
[b.sub.-1](1 + [r.sub.g]) + [[infinity].summation over (k=0)]
[[I.sub.k]/[(1 + [r.sub.g]).sup.k] = [[infinity].summation over (k=0)]
[[L.sub.k] + [a.sub.k-1] ([r.sub.g] - [r.sub.n])/ [(1 +
[r.sub.g]).sup.k],
which is Equation 7.
Appendix II: Proof of Lemma
From Equation 13 and using [differential]
[a.sub.j-1]/[differential][Q.sub.t] = -[differential][a.sub.j-1]/
[differential][L.sub.t], we can see that [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] is equivalent to
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (A1)
To verify Equation A1, it is critical to express
[differential][a.sub.j-1]/[differential][L.sub.i] and
[differential][a.sub.j-1]/[differential][L.sub.t] in comparable terms.
Substituting the optimal levels of consumption and wealth into
(individual) budget constraints 2 and differentiating both sides of each
constraint with respect to [L.sub.i], we have
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (A2)
Similarly,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (A3)
Substituting Equations A2 and A3 into A1, the left-hand side of A1
becomes
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (A4)
From the integrated (individual) budget constraint 9, we have that
[differential][c.sub.h]/ [differential][L.sub.i] =
[differential][c.sub.h]/[differential][L.sub.t] [(1 +
[r.sub.n]).sup.t-i],
and A4 can be simplified to
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (A5)
which equals the right-hand side of Equation A1. QED.
We want to thank several anonymous referees for very helpful
comments and suggestions. We also thank The Lynde and Harry Bradley
Foundation and the National Center for Policy Analysis (NCPA) for
financial support.
Received February 2004; accepted November 2004.
(1) Intergenerational equity has also been used to justify the use
of a social discount rate (SDR). For the SDR issue motivated by the
consideration of equity across generations, see Intergovernmental Panel
on Climate Change (1996) and Liu, Rettenmaier, and Saving (2004).
However, the SDR issue that arises from the distortionary taxes on
capital income is believed to be the most basic one and has drawn the
most attention in the literature. The SDR issue in a tax-distorted
closed economy is the concern of this paper.
(2) To obtain the scale factor in the shadow price of capital
approach, a shadow price of capital must be calculated (hence, the name
of the approach). Liu (2003) summarizes the practical difficulties of
the existing views and proposes a new approach to the discount rate
issue that is based on the (multiperiod) concept of the marginal cost of
funds.
(3) The equivalence, which is formally established in Appendix I,
holds under the "no Ponzi Game" condition that
[lim.sub.t[infinity]] [b.sub.t] [(1 + [r.sub.g]).sup.-t] = 0. Note that
this widely used condition does not require that government debt ever be
fully paid off. It only requires that debt not permanently grow faster
than the interest rate.
(4) This paper follows the tradition in the literature of
cost-benefit analysis to focus on marginal project evaluation. See Dreze
and Stern (1987) for an excellent demonstration of the basic theory and
results in cost-benefit analysis.
(5) The equivalence between Equation 9 and the constraints in
Equation 2 holds for the same reason and under the same (parallel)
condition as the equivalence between Equations 7 and 6. See Footnote 3
and Appendix I.
(6) Strictly speaking, consumption in each period should also be a
function of the vector of income y = ([y.sub.0], [y.sub.1], ...) and the
interest rate [r.sub.n]. However, we do not include them as arguments
since we treat them as exogenous in our simple framework.
(7) Shadow prices depend on both marginal financing and measuring
unit. However, as long as the marginal financing is given, the
evaluation result does not depend on the measuring unit, as the use of
an alternative measuring unit would simply scale all shadow prices up or
down by a common factor. We will use the numeraire good in period 0 as
the measuring unit. For some interesting discussion of the implications
of numeraire good choice for cost-benefit analysis in a heterogeneous
environment, see Brekke (1997), Snow and Warren (1997), Dreze (1998),
and Johansson (1998).
(8) We would like to point out that the result of the government
borrowing rate being irrelevant to the discount rate choice does not
hinge on any of the following assumptions. The reason is that how a
government chooses to tax interest earnings on government bonds has no
implications for the real economy.
(9) Another problem with the fixed capital market (tax) distortion in an economy with a representative individual is how the existence of
the capital income taxes can be justified--see Wilson (1991).
(10) Note that previous studies allowing endogenous interest rates,
such as those of Sandmo and Dreze (1971) and Harberger (1973), were all
conducted in a two-period environment in which there was only one
endogenous interest rate.
(11) For some well-known estimates of marginal costs of funds, see
Stuart (1984), Ballard, Shoven, and Whalley (1985), and Browning (1987).
For a reconciliation of divergent marginal cost of fund estimates that
are based on the nature of public goods, see Wildasin (1984), Mayshar
(1991), Ballard and Fullerton (1992), and Snow and Warren (1996).
(12) Also note that the discount rate required by each federal
agency's discounting policy is supposed to be applied to all
projects regardless of project type. Using one set of discount rates,
rather than another, produces biases for some projects and biases
against others.
References
Ballard, Charles L., and Don Fullerton. 1992. Distortionary taxes
and the provision of public goods. Journal of Economic Perspectives
6:117-31.
Ballard, Charles L., John B. Shoven, and John Whalley. 1985.
General equilibrium computations of the marginal welfare costs of taxes
in the United States. American Economic Review 75:128-38.
Baumol, William J. 1968. On the social rate of discount. American
Economic Review 58:788-802.
Bradford, David F. 1975. Constraints on government investment
opportunities and the choice of discount rate. American Economic Review
65:887-99.
Brekke, Kjell Arne. 1997. The numeraire matters in cost-benefit
analysis. Journal of Public Economics 64:117-23.
Browning, Edgar K. 1987. On the marginal welfare cost of taxation.
American Economic Review 77:11-23.
Diamond, Peter A., and James A. Mirrlees. 1971. Optimal taxation
and public production I: Production efficiency and II: Tax rules.
American Economic Review 61:8-27 and 261-78.
Dreze, Jean. 1998. Distribution matters in cost-benefit analysis.
Journal of Public Economics 70:485-8.
Dreze, Jean, and Nicholas H. Stern. 1987. The theory of
cost-benefit analysis. In Handbook of public economics, Volume 2, edited
by A. J. Auerbach and M. Feldstein. Amsterdam: North-Holland, pp.
909-89.
Feldstein, Martin. 1964. Net social benefit calculation and the
public investment decision. Oxford Economic Papers 16:114-31.
Feldstein, Martin, ed. 1998. Privatizing social security. NBER.
Chicago, IL: The University of Chicago Press.
Harberger, Arnold C. 1973. Project evaluation: Collected essays.
Chicago, IL: Markham.
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC). 1996. Climate
change 1995: Economics and social dimensions of climate change:
Contribution of working group III to the second assessment report of the
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge
University Press.
Johansson, Per-Olov. 1998. Does the choice of numeraire matter in
cost-benefit analysis? Journal of Public Economics 70:489-93.
Lind, Robert C. 1982. A primer on the major issues relating to the
discount rate for evaluating national energy options. In Discounting for
time and risk in energy policy, edited by R. C. Lind. Washington, DC:
Resources for the Future, pp. 21-94.
Liu, Liqun. 2003. A marginal cost of funds approach to multi-period
public project evaluation: Implications for the social discount rate.
Journal of Public Economics 87:1707-18.
Liu, Liqun, Andrew J. Rettenmaier, and Thomas R. Saving. 2004. A
generalized approach to multi-generation project evaluation. Southern
Economic Journal 71:377-96.
Lyon, Randolph M. 1990. Federal discount rate policy, the shadow
price of capital, and challenges for reforms. Journal of Environmental
Economics and Management 18:S-29-S-50.
Marglin, Stephen A. 1963. The opportunity costs of public
investment. Quarterly Journal of Economics 77:274-89.
Mayshar, Joram. 1991. On measuring the marginal cost of funds
analytically. American Economic Review 81:1329-35.
Pestieau, Pierre. 1975. The role of taxation in the determination
of the social discount rate. International Economic Review 16:362-8.
Sandmo, Agnar, and J. H. Dreze. 1971. Discount rates for public
investments in closed and open economies. Economica 38:395-412.
Snow, Arthur, and Ronald S. Warren, Jr. 1996. The marginal welfare
cost of public funds: Theory and estimates. Journal of Public Economics
61:289-305.
Snow, Arthur, and Ronald S. Warren, Jr. 1997. On the general
relevance of choice of numeraire in public economics. Working Paper No.
97-466. Department of Economics, University of Georgia.
Stuart, Charles. 1984. Welfare cost per dollar of additional tax
revenue in the United States. American Economic Review 74:352-61.
Usher, Dan. 1969. On the social rate of discount: Comment. American
Economic Review 59:927-9.
Wildasin, David E. 1984. On public good provision with
distortionary taxation. Economic. Inquiry 22:227-43.
Wilson, John D. 1991. Optimal public good provision with limited
lump-sum taxation. American Economic Review 81:153-66.
Liqun Liu, * Andrew J. Rettenmaier, ([dagger]) and Thomas R. Saving
([double dagger])
* Private Enterprise Research Center, Texas A&M University,
College Station, TX 77843-4231, USA; E-mail lliu@tamu.edu.
([dagger]) Private Enterprise Research Center, Texas A&M
University, College Station, TX 77843-4231, USA; E-mail
a-rettenmaier@tamu.edu.
([double dagger]) Private Enterprise Research Center, Texas A&M
University, College Station, TX 77843-4231, USA; E-mail
t-saving@tamu.edu; corresponding author.