Hurricane fatalities and hurricane damages: are safer hurricanes more damaging?
Sutter, Daniel
1. Introduction
Hurricanes have long threatened the coastal areas of the United
States. The nation has invested millions of dollars to understand and
forecast hurricanes. Research efforts led by the National Hurricane
Center (Simpson 1998) have succeeded in making land-falling hurricanes
less deadly. In the 1990s, the modernization of the National Weather
Service, featuring the installation of the Advanced Weather Interactive
Processing System to process data from radar, satellites, and surface
observations at high speeds and a nationwide network of Doppler weather
radars, contributed to improved forecasts of weather hazards (Friday
1994). Annual hurricane fatalities have fallen from 0.5 per million
residents nationally during the 1950s to 0.05 per million residents
during the 1980s and 1990s. Kunkel, Pielke, and Changnon (1999)
attribute the decline to improved hurricane forecasts. (1)
Although hurricanes have become less deadly over time, hurricane
damages have increased, particularly in recent years. By 1995, hurricane
damage in the 1990s had already exceeded total damage in the 1970s and
1980s combined. This escalation has led to interest among policy makers
and researchers regarding the causes of increasing hurricane damages.
Some observers attribute rising damages to an increase in the number and
severity of hurricanes; for instance, a 1995 congressional report
asserts that hurricanes "have become increasingly frequent and
severe over the last four decades as climatic conditions have changed in
the tropics" (cited in Pielke and Landsea 1998, p. 623). This
explanation, however, is simply false. Katz (2002) for instance finds no
statistically significant increase in the number of land-falling
hurricanes over time. (2) And the period from 1991 to 1994 had the
fewest tropical storms of any four-year period in the last 50 years.
Increasing societal vulnerability, that is, more people and wealth
along hurricane-prone coasts, seems to explain increasing hurricane
damages. Figure 1 illustrates the increase in coastal county populations
during the 20th century. The figure graphs the population growth rates by decade for 130 Atlantic and Gulf coast counties and for the United
States overall. As illustrated, the coastal counties grew faster than
the nation in each decade. A wealthier population will also have more
property vulnerable to destruction by a hurricane. Pielke and Landsea
(1998), Changnon and Hewings (2001), and Katz (2002) find no time trend
for hurricane damages after normalizing for changes in population and
wealth in addition to inflation.
An understanding of increasing hurricane losses requires an
explanation for the increase in coastal county populations, and several
have been advanced. One is the rising standard of living in the United
States: wealthier people will spend more on luxuries, such as living
near the ocean. Another possibility involves low-probability event bias.
Considerable evidence suggests that people do not behave according to expected utility theory with respect to low-probability,
high-consequence events like hurricanes. Instead of considering the
expected cost of these events, which is considerable, people act as if
such events "couldn't happen to me" and treat the low
probability as a zero probability (Kunreuther et al. 1978; Camerer and
Kunreuther 1989). Finally, a number of government policies, including
subsidized insurance, disaster assistance, and structural restoration
measures (e.g., rebuilding roads and restoring beaches after storms)
contribute to overbuilding on hurricane-prone coasts (Platt 1999). (3)
We consider an alternative explanation, one which, to our
knowledge, has not been widely discussed, namely the very reduction in
hurricane lethality. Through improved hurricane warnings, better
evacuation, and engineering advances, the probability of fatalities has
been reduced, thereby decreasing the expected cost of living along
hurricane-exposed coasts. The law of increasing demand consequently
explains at least a part of the increase in coastal populations. (4) We
provide evidence of the impact of reduced hurricane fatalities on
damages using a database of land-falling hurricanes in the United States
between 1940 and 1999. We do not argue that reduced lethality is the
exclusive cause of increasing hurricane damages, only that it is a
contributing and overlooked factor. Our explanation utilizes the concept
of offsetting behavior in response to an exogenous change in the
riskiness of an activity, first proposed by Peltzmaal (1975) for
automobile safety.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows: Section 2
presents an expected utility model of a household's location choice
and shows how a reduction in the probability of deaths from a hurricane
makes a household more likely to live along a hurricane-prone coast. In
particular, the effect of reduced fatalities will be greatest when the
probability of a hurricane is highest. Section 3 explains our
econometric model. We first estimate a time-varying measure of hurricane
lethality in a Poisson model of hurricane fatalities. We then use this
measure of lethality with a lag to explain hurricane damages. We also
interact this measure with the probability of a hurricane. Section 4
presents the empirical results, and Section 5 offers a brief conclusion.
2. Hurricane Forecasts and Locational Choice
In this section we examine a simple model of household location
choice to derive testable predictions concerning hurricane lethality and
damages. Consider a representative household's choice to live on a
hurricane-exposed coast. Let [pi] be the probability of a hurricane and
let [sigma] be the probability that the household suffers a casualty
given that a hurricane strikes the household's residence on the
coast. Let I be the household's income, which we assume does not
depend on location decision, and let L be the dollar value of property
losses that occur if the household lives on the coast and their
residence is struck by a hurricane. The household can purchase insurance
against property damage. Let x be the dollar value of coverage purchased
and let p be the price per dollar of coverage. The household's
total premium is [p.sup.*]x, and the household receives a payment of x
if a hurricane loss occurs. Let y denote the disposable income spent on
consumption goods.
Household utility is a function of disposable income y, the
household's location, and the household's state of health. Let
[theta] denote the household's state of health, with
[[theta].sup.h] indicating full health and [[theta].sup.i] indicating
that the household has suffered a hurricane casualty. (5) We assume that
utility is lower (and the marginal utility of income higher) when the
household suffers a hurricane casualty. Let a superscript on the utility
function designate the household's location choice, with c
representing the hurricane-vulnerable coast and o the location away from
the coast. Let [U.sup.c] (y,[theta]) be the household's expected
utility if they choose to live on the coast, which can be written
(1) [U.sup.c](y, [theta]) = (1 - [pi]) x [U.sup.c](I - px,
[[theta].sup.h]) + [pi] x (1 - [sigma] x [U.sup.c](I - L - px + x,
[[theta].sup.h]) + [pi] x [sigma] x [U.sup.c](I - L - px + x,
[[theta].sup.i])
We assume that x is the household's expected
utility-maximizing insurance purchase. Utility if the household chooses
to live inland is [U.sup.o](y,[[theta].sup.h]), which is the
household's reservation utility level. The household will live on
the coast if [U.sup.c](y,[theta]) [greater than or equal to]
[U.sup.o](y,[[theta].sup.h]).
We examine the comparative statics of the household's location
decision. Consider first the effect of a change in the probability of a
casualty, [sigma]. Forecasts allow residents to evacuate in advance of
an approaching hurricane, so improved warnings will reduce [sigma], but
not the probability of a hurricane, [pi]. A change in [sigma] does not
affect the reservation level of utility, [U.sup.o](y,[[theta].sup.h]).
Thus, the effect on [U.sup.c](y,[theta]) is
(2) [differential][U.sup.c]/[differential][sigma] = [pi] x
[[U.sup.c](I - L - px + x, [[theta].sup.i] - [U.sup.c](I - L - px + x,
[[theta].sup.h]),
which is negative given that the marginal utility of income is
higher when the household suffers an injury,
[U.sup.c](y,[[theta].sup.i]) > [U.sup.c](y,[[theta].sup.h]) a typical
assumption. A reduction in the probability of injury from a hurricane
raises expected utility from living on the coast and will, ceteris
paribus, increase the population on the vulnerable coast. If all
households, including the new residents, suffer similar losses, L, the
increase in population will increase the property damage from a
hurricane. From Equation 2, we also see that the effect on utility of a
reduction in o depends on the probability of a hurricane. Thus, a
reduction in hurricane fatalities will have a greater impact in coastal
areas facing a greater risk of hurricane landfall. (6) This leads to our
main testable prediction.
An increase in income also affects the household's location
choice. An increase in income increases the household's reservation
level of utility, [differential][U.sup.o]/[differential]I > 0. The
effect of an increase in income on the utility of living on the coast
(ignoring the effect of the change in 1 on losses from a hurricane or
insurance purchase) can be written
(3) [differential][U.sup.c]/[differential]I = (1 -
[pi])[differential][U.sup.c](I - px, [[theta].sup.h])/ [differential]y +
[pi](1 - [sigma])[differential][U.sup.c](I - L - px + x,
[[theta].sup.h])/[differential]y + [pi][sigma][differential][U.sup.c](I
- L - px + x, [[theta].sup.i])/[differential]y.
An increase in income raises the utility of living on the coast.
With the standard assumptions of diminishing marginal utility of income
and higher marginal utility of income given a lower state of health,
then it follows that [differential][U.sup.c]/[differential]I, and an
increase in income will increase coastal populations and hurricane
property damage.
Finally, the effect of a change in the price of insurance, ignoring
the effect on the quantity of insurance purchased, is
(4) [differential][U.sup.c]/[differential]p = -(1
[pi])[differential][U.sup.c](I - px, [[theta].sup.h]/[differential]y -
[pi](1 - [sigma])[differential][U.sup.c](I - L - px + x,
[[theta].sup.h])/ [differential]y - [pi]
[sigma][differential][U.sup.c](I - L - px + x,
[[theta].sup.i])/[differential]y.
An increase in the price of insurance lowers the utility of living
on the coast, and the impact of the price change on the quantity of
insurance purchased does not alter this result. Consequently, a
reduction in the price of insurance because of a public subsidy or
cross-subsidization in regulated insurance rates also increases coastal
populations and hurricane damages. We lack a direct measure of insurance
subsidy over time in different coastal areas. States regulate insurance
companies, which suggests the value of including state fixed effects in
our analysis of hurricane damage.
We noted earlier the reduction in hurricane lethality apparent in
the raw time series of hurricane fatalities. We presume that improved
forecasts and better evacuations are responsible for declining
fatalities, but an improvement in construction techniques that allows
buildings to better withstand hurricanes could also produce lower
fatalities. Improved construction techniques would reduce both [sigma]
and L; more households would locate on hurricane exposed coasts but
lower losses per household imply that damages may not increase. Fronstin
and Holtman (1994), however, found that newer subdivisions suffered
greater damage in Hurricane Andrew, which indicates that construction
techniques have not improved significantly.
3. Econometric Specification and Data
We employ a two-stage estimation procedure. We first estimate
fatalities directly caused by a hurricane as a function of storm
strength and other control variables. We also include decade dummy
variables to capture changes in the lethality of hurricanes over time.
We then estimate the determinants of hurricane damages to find whether a
change in hurricane lethality affects damages.
Our data set is taken from the National Hurricane Center's
archive of land-falling hurricanes in the United States. (7) Damage
estimates are missing for a number of hurricanes prior to 1950, so we
use hurricanes during 1940-1999 in our fatalities regression and
1950-1999 in our damage regression. Table 1 reports the breakdown of
land-falling hurricanes by category on the Saffir-Simpson scale and by
decade. The Saffir-Simpson scale measures the intensity of the hurricane
and its destructive potential. Ratings on the scale are integer values
from 1 to 5, with a category 5 hurricane the most intense, and are based
on wind speed, storm surge, and potential damage. A category 1 storm is
a minimal hurricane and has sustained wind speeds of 74-95 miles per
hour and a 4-5 foot storm surge, while a category 5 hurricane has
sustained winds in excess of 155 miles per hour and a storm surge in
excess of 18 feet. Note that the damages corresponding to the five
categories do not increase in linear fashion; a category 4 hurricane
would be expected to cause 100 times the damage of a category 1
hurricane. (8) A total of 94 hurricanes made landfall between 1940 and
1999, with 73 striking between 1950 and 1999. Category 1 hurricanes (at
landfall) were most common (32 of 94); only 7 storms reached Category 4
and one was rated Category 5. Mean fatalities were 24, with a median of
3 and range of 0 to 394. Mean damages were $1.54 billion, with a median
of $242 million and range of $1.14 million to $28.8 billion (Hurricane
Andrew in 1992).
Our first-stage regression estimates the determinants of the number
of persons killed by a hurricane. We model the number of persons killed
by hurricane i as follows:
(5) [Fatalities.sub.i] = f([Category.sub.i], [Density.sub.i],
[D40.sub.i], [D50.sub.i], [D60.sub.i], [D70.sub.i], [D80.sub.i]).
Fatalities is the number of persons directly killed by hurricane i
and does not include deaths from inland flooding. Category is the rating
of the hurricane on the Saffir-Simpson Hurricane scale at the time of
landfall. Density is the average population density in persons per
square mile of the counties struck by the hurricane, as listed in the
National Hurricane Center's hurricane archive. The population for a
county in a given year was estimated using linear interpolation from the
decennial censuses. A higher population density of the storm path should
increase the number of fatalities. D40, D50, D60, D70 and D80 are dummy
variables that equal one if the hurricane occurred in the decades 1940s,
1950s, 1960s, 1970s or 1980s respectively, or zero otherwise, with the
1990s the omitted decade. Thus, we allow the lethality of hurricanes to
vary over the decades, with the decade dummies capturing the effects of
improved hurricane warnings and public dissemination of these warnings.
We expect that hurricanes have become less lethal over time, so we
expect positive coefficients on the decade dummy variables, with the
magnitude of the coefficients becoming smaller.
The number of fatalities produced by a hurricane is a count
variable, taking on integer values with a high proportion of zeros. Of
the 94 hurricanes in our sample, 23 produced no direct fatalities, and
the median number of fatalities is 3 compared with a mean of 24.3. Thus
we estimate the fatalities function using Poisson regression (Greene
2000, pp. 880-886). The Poisson model assumes that the number of persons
killed by hurricane i, [Y.sub.i], is distributed as a Poisson random
variable. The probability of a given number of fatalities is
(6) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
The parameter [[lambda].sub.i] depends on the vector of independent
variables [x.sub.i] described above.
Our second stage estimates the determinants of property damage
caused by a hurricane. We model damages as follows:
(7) [Damage.sub.i] = [[beta].sub.0] +
[[beta].sub.1]x[Category.sub.i] + [[beta].sub.1]x[Density.sub.i] +
[[beta].sub.3]x[Income.sub.i] + [[beta].sub.4]xYear +
[[beta].sub.5]xRF[R.sub.i] + [[beta].sub.6]xP[H.sub.i] +
[[beta].sub.7]RF[R.sub.i]*P[H.sub.i] + [[epsilon].sub.i].
Damage is the value of property damage caused by the hurricane in
millions of dollars, adjusted for inflation using the GDP deflator.
Category is the rating of the hurricane on the Saffir-Simpson scale; we
expect that stronger hurricanes will produce more damage, [[beta].sub.1]
> 0. Density is the population density of the counties affected by
the hurricane and is expected to increase damages, [[beta].sub.2] >
0. Income is the per capita income of the counties struck by the
hurricane. Because the value of real and personal property on a
high-income coastal area is higher, the dollar value of damage should be
higher, [[beta].sub.3] > 0. But higher-income individuals will also
spend more to protect themselves and their property against hazards,
which could reduce total damage. Thus, either a positive or a negative
value for [[beta].sub.3] could be observed. Year is a time trend
included to capture any effects of improved construction techniques or
changes in building codes over time that might affect property damage.
RFR is our time-varying measure of the deadliness of hurricanes, based
on the coefficient point estimate of the decade dummy variable from our
first stage estimation. A decline in hurricane fatalities reduces the
cost of living on a hurricane-prone coast, so we expect that this will
increase coastal population and damages. Clearly a lag is required for
people to recognize that hurricanes have become less deadly and move
into hurricane-exposed coasts. Consequently, we use the coefficient from
the previous decade's dummy variable as the RFR for a hurricane in
year t. Thus, the coefficient on D70 in the fatalities regression is the
value of RFR for any hurricane occurring during the decade of the 1980s.
We follow Sobel and Nesbit's (2002) investigation of offsetting
behavior in NASCAR racing. They use the number of fatalities divided by
the number of accidents for the previous 110 races as a measure of the
recent fatality rate. We must control for the strength of the hurricane
and set some time limit for recent hurricanes because of the randomness
in the occurrence of land-falling hurricanes. PH is an estimate of the
annual probability of a major hurricane at different points along the
coastline. This variable was taken from estimates for various cities
along the Atlantic and Gulf coasts contained in Sheets and Williams
(2001). In the expected utility model, an increase in [pi] ceteris
paribus reduces the utility of living on the coast, but we observe
different [pi]'s at different locations, so the utility of living
on these different stretches of coast may differ, rendering a prediction
for PH difficult. The expected present value of hurricane loss reduction
mechanisms, for instance, will depend on the annual probability of a
hurricane. If more hurricane-prone areas employ better building
techniques or other loss-reduction mechanisms, PH will have a negative
value. Alternatively, if hurricane-prone states subsidize or
cross-subsidize hurricane insurance, PH could have a positive value.
RFR*PH is an interaction term capturing the combined effect of the
recent fatality rate and probability of a hurricane. (9) A decrease in
hurricane lethality will have its greatest impact on damages in the most
hurricane-prone coastal areas. A negative value on this interaction
term, [[beta].sub.7] < 0, provides the sharpest test of the damage
augmenting effect of hurricane forecasts and warnings.
4. Results
Table 2 presents our first-stage Poisson estimates of hurricane
fatalities. Not surprisingly, Category is a positive and highly
significant determinant of fatalities; a one-category increase in the
strength of a hurricane almost triples expected casualties. Density is
also positive and significant at better than the 1% level. As expected,
hurricanes that strike more highly populated coastal areas are more
deadly. The decade dummy variables are all statistically significant at
better than the 1% level, except D70, which is significant at only the
10% level. All of the decade dummies are positive except D80, which is
negative and significant. Roughly speaking, a downward trend in
hurricane lethality is evident, because the coefficients on D40 and D50
are the largest, whereas the 1980s and 1990s are the least lethal
decades. The differences between the decade dummy variables are
significant at the 5% level as well, so from the 1950s through 1980s we
see consistent and statistically significant reductions in lethality
each decade.
Table 3 presents our second-stage ordinary least squares estimation
of hurricane damages. (10) The first column displays estimates using the
point estimates of the dummy variables from Table 2 as the RFR variable.
All of the control variables are significant at the 10% level or better.
Category and Density have positive values, so a stronger hurricane
striking a more densely populated coast will cause greater damage, as
expected. A one-category increase in the strength of a land-falling
hurricane increases expected damages by about $1.4 billion, which is
just less than the mean damage of all hurricanes in the sample of $1.54
billion. Income has a negative association with damages. Although the
value of real and personal property is higher in higher income areas,
wealthier residents seem to take more precautions to mitigate hurricane
losses. Because windborne debris is a major contributor to structural
damage, destruction of poorly constructed homes can damage other
structures in the neighborhood. The negative sign on Income is actually
consistent with Fronstin and Holtman's (1994) result that
subdivisions with higher average home prices suffered less damage in
Hurricane Andrew. Year has a positive coefficient, so, ceteris paribus,
more recent hurricanes have been causing greater damage, which is also
consistent with Fronstin and Holtman's (1994) finding that newer
subdivisions suffered greater damage in Hurricane Andrew. Year may be
capturing the effect of increasing wealth over time, with our Income
variable capturing the cross-sectional impact of wealth on losses. The
coefficient on PH, the probability of a major hurricane, is positive and
significant. After controlling for category, population density, and
income, regions with a higher probability of a hurricane still suffer
greater damages. (11) This is a surprising result because durable
loss-reduction measures such as strengthened building techniques and
hurricane shutters have higher expected benefits in more hurricane-prone
regions and thus should be more likely to be installed (or to have their
installation mandated). Our result is consistent with possible insurance
cross-subsidization or weak enforcement of building codes in
hurricane-prone regions.
Our measure of recent hurricane lethality provides evidence on
offsetting behavior. RFR has a positive and significant (at the 5%
level) direct effect on damages and a negative and significant (at the
1% level) effect when interacted with the probability of a major
hurricane. The interaction coefficient provides the strongest test of
the role of reducing the lethality of hurricanes or hurricane damages,
and we see that the reduction in the lethality of hurricanes does
increase damages in the following decade in more hurricane-prone
regions. (12) The marginal effect of a decrease in RFR becomes positive
when the annual probability of a major hurricane exceeds about 3.9%, a
threshold exceeded in most counties of south Florida and along the Texas
gulf coast. The magnitude of the impact of the declining fatality rate
on damages is quantitatively quite significant. The increase in expected
damages because of the observed decline in the fatality rate is $5.1
billion when the probability of a major hurricane is 7% and $10.9
billion when the probability of a major hurricane is at its maximum of
10.5%. (13,14)
We also estimated the damage model using the lower bounds and upper
bounds of the 95% confidence intervals for the estimates of the
coefficients of the decade dummy variables to determine if our results
were robust to plausible changes in the estimated lethality of
hurricanes. The second and third columns of Table 3 present the results.
Our results are not affected in any substantial way. The estimated
impact of the observed decrease in hurricane lethality with a 7%
probability of a major hurricane is $4.8 billion with the lower bounds
estimate and $5.5 billion with the upper bounds.
The potential for state policies, particularly regulation of the
insurance industry, to create subsidies for living on hurricane-exposed
coasts was noted in Section 2. To explore this possibility, we created
state effect variables. Because some hurricanes struck more than one
state, the state variables were defined to equal the fraction of the
population of the area struck by the hurricane living in that state,
based on the counties listed for each storm. The fourth column of Table
3 presents this estimation, which uses the point estimates of the decade
dummy variables for the RFR variable, with the state variables omitted
to conserve space. Inclusion of state effects does not affect the
estimates very much at all, and the state variables are both
individually and jointly insignificant. (15) The state effects model
does produce a slightly higher estimate of the impact of the observed
reduction in hurricane lethality on damages of $5.6 billion (with a 7%
probability of a hurricane), compared to $5.1 in the model in column 1.
5. Conclusion
Economists since Peltzman (1975) have identified a number of
offsetting behaviors, such that as technology or regulation reduce the
full cost of risky behavior, people will engage in more of the risky
behavior. We have considered an application of offsetting behavior to
natural hazards, and specifically hurricanes. Advances in meteorology,
engineering, and emergency management have combined to make hurricanes
less deadly over time. Yet if hurricanes are less likely to produce
fatalities and injuries, living along an exposed coast becomes more
inviting and coastal populations will increase. Therefore, hurricanes
will kill fewer people but will produce more property damage. We offer
evidence for this proposition through an analysis of land-falling
hurricanes in the United States between 1940 and 1999. Our results
suggest that the reduction in hurricane lethality has a statistically
significant and quantitatively large effect on damages on the portions
of the coast most prone to hurricanes.
Scientific or engineering approaches to natural hazards can
sometimes exacerbate hazards (Mileti 1999). Improved weather forecasts
and other measures that reduce hazard deaths provide obvious benefits to
society. But offsetting behavior will increase societal vulnerability,
leading perhaps to an increase in damages. We have examined only the
case of hurricanes here, but offsetting behavior should lead to a
lethality/damage tradeoff for other hazards.
Increasing populations along exposed coasts provide a potential new
hurricane hazard. As Dow and Cutter (2002) stress, the growth of coastal
populations threaten to exceed the capacity of the highway
infrastructure to allow timely evacuation. Indeed, the prospect of
massive traffic jams affected residents' evacuation decision in
advance of Hurricane Floyd in 1999. Traffic congestion, the impact of a
household's decision to live along the coast on others'
ability to evacuate, is a negative externality that households are
unlikely to take into account. Thus, even if residents bear the full
expected cost of hurricane damage, an evacuation externality might
result in greater than optimal coastal populations, and be exacerbated
as hurricanes become less deadly.
A reduction in the lethality of hurricanes may increase expected
hurricane damages but still raise social welfare. If the risk to life
and limb deterred some prospective residents from living along a
hurricane-exposed coast, this is also a social cost of hurricanes in
addition to property damage. But the risk to life and limb is one borne
by residents, whereas other costs of hurricanes can be externalized. If
the regulation of insurance or disaster relief subsidizes coastal
living, however, making hurricanes less deadly can lower social welfare.
As hurricanes become less deadly, the cost to society of socializing
property losses increases.
References
Camerer, Colin F., and Howard Kunreuther. 1989. Decision processes
for low probability events: Policy implications. Journal of Policy
Analysis and Management 8:565-92.
Changnon, Stanley A., and Geoffrey J. D. Hewings. 200l. Losses from
weather extremes in the United States. Natural Hazards Review 2: 113-23.
Dow, Kirstin, and Susan L. Cutter. 2002. Emerging hurricane
evacuation issues: Hurricane Floyd and South Carolina. Natural Hazards
Review 3:12-8.
Friday, Elbert W. Jr. 1994. The modernization and associated
restructuring of the National Weather Service: An overview. Bulletin of
the American Meteorological Society 75:43-52,
Fronstin, Paul, and Alphonse G. Holtman. 1994. The determinants of
residential property damage caused by Hurricane Andrew. Southern
Economic Journal 61:387-97.
Garrett, Thomas A., and Russell S. Sobel. 2003. The political
economy of FEMA disaster payments. Economic Inquiry 41: 496-509.
Greene, William H. 2000. Econometric analysis. 4th edition. Upper
Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall, pp. 880-6.
Katz, Richard W. 2002. Stochastic modeling of hurricane damage.
Journal of Applied Meteorology 41:754-62.
Kunkel, Kenneth E., Roger A. Pielke Jr., and Stanley A. Changnon.
1999. Temporal fluctuations in weather and climate extremes that cause
human health impacts: A review. Bulletin of the American Meteorological
Society 80:1077-98.
Kunreuther, Howard, R. Ginsberg, L. Miller, P. Sagi, P. Slovic, B.
Borkan, and N. Katz. 1978. Disaster insurance protection: Public policy
lessons. New York: Wiley & Sons.
Mileti, Dennis S. 1999. Disasters by design. Washington, DC: Joseph
Henry Press, pp. 17-40.
Pagan, Adrian. 1984. Econometric issues in the analysis of
regressions with generated regressors. International Economic Review
25:221-47.
Peltzman, Sam. 1975. The effects of automobile safety regulation.
Journal of Political Economy 83:677-725.
Pielke Jr., Roger A., and Christopher W. Landsea. 1998. Normalized
hurricane damages in the United States, 1925-1995. Weather and
Forecasting 13:621-31.
Platt, Rutherford H. 1999. Disasters and democracy: The politics of
extreme natural events. Washington, DC: Island Press, pp. 11-41.
Sheets, Bob, and Jack Williams. 2001. Hurricane watch: Forecasting
the deadliest storms on earth. New York: Vintage Books, pp. 292-4.
Simmons, Kevin M., Jamie B. Kruse, and Douglas A. Smith. 2002.
Valuing mitigation: Real estate market response to hurricane loss
measures. Southern Economic Journal 68:660-71.
Simpson, R. H. 1998. Stepping stones in the evolution of a national
hurricane policy. Weather and Forecasting 13:617-20.
Sobel, Russell S., and Todd M. Nesbit. 2002. Automobile safety and
the incentive to drive recklessly: Evidence from NASCAR. Unpublished
paper, West Virginia University.
(1) The National Hurricane Center maintains a continuous watch for
tropical cyclones throughout hurricane season, May 15 through November
30. The Center issues watches and warnings for hurricanes threatening
landfall, and orders evacuations based on the warnings. Throughout the
remainder of the year, the Center provides training for emergency
managers from the United States and other countries affected by tropical
storms and conducts research on hurricanes and forecasts.
(2) See also our Table 1 reporting land-falling hurricanes in the
U.S. by decade.
(3) Garrett and Sobel (2003) document political influence on
presidential disaster declarations and the dollar value of disaster
assistance provided under the Stafford Act.
(4) Imagine an island exposed to frequent hurricanes. Absent any
type of hurricane forecast, residents of the island could be surprised
any time during the hurricane season. Under such circumstances, the
island may remain uninhabited, but it may well become inhabited once
residents can be warned in time to evacuate from an approaching
hurricane.
(5) In this simple formulation, we consider all casualties
equivalent. Gradations of casualties could be introduced but would not
affect the testable hypotheses derived here.
(6) Fronstin and Holtman (1994) argue that an ability to evacuate
from an approaching hurricane encourages residents to substitute lower
quality construction, which would provide an additional method by which
improved forecasts can increase damages. Note that the effect of a
decrease in the probability of hurricane casualties for a household on
the overall number of casualties is theoretically ambiguous because of
the Peltzman (1975) offsetting behavior effect.
(7) The hurricane archive was accessed at
http://www.nhc.noaa.gov/pastall.shtml.
(8) For details on the Saffir-Simpson scale, see
www.nhc.noaa.gov/aboutsshs.shtml.
(9) On market incentives for the installation of loss-reduction
measures like hurricane shutters, see Simmons, Kruse, and Smith (2002).
(10) A Breusch-Pagan heteroscedasticity test failed to reject the
null hypothesis of homoscedasticity at even the 10% significance level.
The test statistic was 44.44, with a p-value of 0.1085.
(11) Note that, because of the interaction term, the partial effect
of hurricane probability on damages becomes negative if RFR is greater
than 1.21, which it is with the 1950s value. We also estimated the
damages model using an estimate of the probability of any hurricane also
reported in Sheets and Williams (2001), because we do not know a priori what measure of hurricane risk people might use in estimating B. The
signs of the estimated coefficients were the same as reported in Table
3, but the model overall did not perform as well, with an adjusted
[R.sup.2] of only 0.199. Consequently, we conclude that the probability
of a major hurricane seems to approximate the public's subjective
measure of hurricane risk.
(12) We also estimated the fatalities model using a linear time
trend and constructed an RFR variable in this fashion. The time trend
variable had a negative and significant sign in the fatalities equation,
and the interaction term in the damages regression was again negative
and significant.
(13) The observed reduction in the hurricane fatality rate is
assumed to equal the difference between the mean of the point estimates
of D40 and D50 and the point estimate of D80 and the omitted decade, the
1990s, so [DELTA]RFR = -1.38.
(14) Our use of an estimated parameter from the first stage as our
RFR variable creates the potential for a generated regressor bias as
noted by Pagan (1984), which could bias the estimate of the standard
errors downward. Unfortunately, there is no widely accepted correction
for this type of bias in our type of model. To examine the robustness of
our results, we estimated our models using Newey-West and White's
standard error. The interaction term remained significant in both cases,
at the 10% level using Newey-West standard errors and at the 10% level
in a one-tailed test with White's standard errors.
(15) Both Wald and F-tests failed to reject the null hypothesis of
joint insignificance of the state variables at even the 10% level. The
test statistic for the Wald test was 14.82 with 13 degrees of freedom
and a p-value of 0.3185, and the test statistic for the F-test was 1.140
with a p-value of 0.3488.
Nicole Cornell Sadowski * and Daniel Sutter ([dagger])
* Department of Economics, University of Oklahoma, Norman, OK
73019-2103, USA; E-mail nicole.L.cornell-1@ou.edu; Present address:
Department of Business Administration, York College, York, PA 17405,
USA.
([dagger]) Department of Economics, University of Oklahoma, Norman,
OK 73019-2103, USA; E-mail dsutter@ou.edu; corresponding author.
We would like to thank Robin Grier, Cindy Rogers, Aaron Smallwood,
two referees, and session participants at the 2003 SEA meetings for
useful comments on an earlier draft.
Received February 2004; accepted February 2005.
Table 1. Land-Falling U.S. Hurricanes using Saffir-Simpson Scale,
by Decade
Number of Storms, by Category
Decade 1 2 3 4 5 Total
1940s 5 8 7 1 0 21
1950s 4 1 8 2 0 15
1960s 4 5 3 2 1 15
1970s 6 2 4 0 0 12
1980s 8 2 4 1 0 15
1990s 5 6 4 1 0 16
Total 32 24 30 7 1 94
Table 2. Poisson Regression of Hurricane Fatalities
Standard 95%
Independent Variable Estimate Error Confidence Interval
Category of hurricane 1.081 ** 0.0255 1.031 1.131
Population density 0.0007180 ** 0.0000 0.0006 0.0008
1940s dummy (D40) 0.9937 ** 0.0912 0.8149 1.173
1950s dummy (D50) 1.354 ** 0.0884 1.181 1.528
1960s dummy (D60) 0.4865 ** 0.0965 0.2974 0.6757
1970s dummy (D70) 0.2145 * 0.1270 -0.0344 0.4634
1980s dummy (D80) -0.4082 ** 0.1286 -0.6602 -0.1562
Intercept -0.6580 ** 0.1130 -0.8794 -0.4366
Number of observations = 94. Dependent variable is the natural
logarithm of expected fatalities.
* Significant at the 10% level.
** Significant at the 1% level.
Table 3. Analysis of Hurricane Damages
Independent Variable RFR Point Estimates RFR Lower Bounds
Category of hurricane 1427 ** (3.98) 1430 ** (3.99)
Population density 1.322 * (2.09) 1.312 (2.07)
Income -0.3177 * (2.15) -0.3189 * (2.16)
Year 141.4 * (1.95) 143.4 * (1.95)
Recent fatality rate (RFR) 4675 * (2.28) 4474 * (2.27)
Probability of major
hurricane (PH) 1454 ** (3.90) 1181 ** (3.78)
RFR*PH -1199 ** (3.39) -1138 ** (3.38)
Intercept -6038 * (2.30) -5032 * (2.13)
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.3141 0.3134
Independent Variable RFR Upper Bounds State Fixed Effects
Category of hurricane 1422 ** (3.97) 1386 ** (3.64)
Population density 1.333 * (2.10) 6.639 ** (2.89)
Income -0.3161 * (2.15) -0.3737 * (2.05)
Year 139.0 (1.96) 160.2 (1.66)
Recent fatality rate (RFR) 4883 * (2.30) 5610 * (2.15)
Probability of major
hurricane (PH) 1755 ** (3.93) 1767 ** (4.15)
RFR*PH -1266 ** (3.40) -1385 ** (3.62)
Intercept -7125 * (2.42) -1234 (0.06)
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.3149 0.3421
The first column presents estimates using the point estimates of the
Recent Fatality Rate variable from Table 2, and the second and third
columns use the lower and upper bounds of the 95% confidence interval
of the estimates from Table 2. The fourth column includes state fixed
effects, which are not presented here to conserve space. Number of
observations = 73. t-statistics are in parentheses. Source: Author
estimation using U.S. Census Data.
* Significant at the 10% level.
** Significant at the 1% level.