Market substitution and the Pareto dominance of ad valorem taxation.
Saving, Thomas R.
1. Introduction
Excise taxes take two basic forms: unit taxes based on quantity
sold and ad valorem taxes based on sales value. While these two versions
of excise taxes are equivalent in perfectly competitive markets, (1) in
noncompetitive markets ad valorem taxation has been shown to welfare
dominate unit taxation. (2) Ad valorem taxation also Pareto dominates
unit taxation in monopoly and, in some cases, oligopoly markets, in the
sense that, under an isorevenue constraint, replacing unit taxation with
ad valorem taxation increases both consumer welfare and producer profits
(Skeath and Trandel 1994). (3)
In this paper, we depart from the homogeneous product oligopoly
markets assumed in previous literature by adopting a model of
heterogeneous products developed by Dixit and Stiglitz (1977). First, we
study the Pareto dominance of ad valorem taxation in short-run equilibrium, where a fixed number of firms produce imperfectly substitutable goods and engage in Bertrand competition. We define market
demand as a weighted sum of firm quantities demanded and market price as
a similarly weighted average of firm prices. By assuming that market
demand is isoelastic with respect to market price, our framework allows
the elasticity of substitution among the goods in the taxed market and
the price elasticity of market demand to bear on the comparison of the
two forms of excise taxes.
We find that, in the short run, ad valorem taxation always
dominates unit taxation both in terms of consumer welfare and overall
welfare (the precise meaning of overall welfare is made clear later).
However, Pareto dominance of ad valorem taxation never exists if market
demand is inelastic because, in this case, firms always earn lower
profits under ad valorem taxation. Restricting our analysis to the case
where market demand is elastic, we find that ad valorem taxation Pareto
dominance is more likely the smaller the within-market elasticity of
substitution or the larger the market demand elasticity. We also
generalize a prior result for homogenous products: Increasing the number
of firms in a market decreases the likelihood of ad valorem taxation
Pareto dominance. Finally, we find that for a sufficiently large within-market elasticity of substitution, ad valorem taxation Pareto
dominance is more likely the smaller the tax level, contrary to an
existing result for the homogenous product case.
Given the results of previous literature that unit taxation tends
to be welfare dominated by equal-revenue ad valorem taxation in
noncompetitive environments, the existence of both types of taxes must
be explained by nonoptimal behavior on the part of government. (4) One
possible explanation for the coexistence of unit and ad valorem taxes,
despite the welfare dominance of ad valorem taxation, is that a
government only cares about the amount of revenue collected from each
market, and the choice between these two taxes in a specific market is
dictated by producers' interests, which are more concentrated than
consumers' interests in general. Given this hypothesis concerning
the political economy of choice between the two major forms of excise
taxes, the results of this paper make testable predictions with respect
to how the relative desirability of ad valorem taxation (from the
perspective of producers) changes with several important characteristics
of a market: the elasticity of substitution among goods in the market,
the market demand elasticity, the number of firms in the market, and the
level of taxation in the market.
Extending our analysis to long-run equilibrium, where entry and
exit provides an additional market equilibrating mechanism and where
firms always earn zero profits, we show that an equal-revenue switch
from unit to ad valorem taxation has welfare effects on consumers
through two channels. First, such a switch always lowers market price,
which has a positive welfare effect. Second, such a switch may reduce
the number of firms and, therefore, the range of consumer choice.
However, we are able to show that the combined effect of lower market
price and reduced range of choice always favors ad valorem taxation.
In spirit, our paper is similar to Anderson, de Palma, and Kreider
(2001a, b), Kay and Keen (1983), and Keen (1998), who have also studied
excise taxes in markets with horizontal product differentiation. (5)
However, the short-run and long-run results obtained in this paper are
complementary to these earlier studies in several important ways. First,
the short-run results in Anderson, de Palma, and Kreider (2001b) focus
on welfare comparisons of alternative forms of excise taxes and
generally confirm the comparative efficiency advantage of ad valorem
taxation previously found for markets with homogenous products. (6) We,
on the other hand, focus on firms' comparative profitability under
alternative tax regimes and use it to explain why unit taxation persists
in some markets despite the efficiency advantage of ad valorem taxation.
In particular, we link the comparative profitability under the two
excise taxes to market parameters such as the number of firms in the
taxed market and the market demand elasticity. For example, we find that
ad valorem taxation generates lower profits when market demand is
inelastic, perhaps explaining why unit taxation persists in markets
featuring inelastic demand, such as the cigarette and gasoline markets.
Second, the long-run analysis of this paper also goes beyond these
earlier studies, by combining both price and variety effects in
assessing the relative long-run efficiency of the two excise taxes.
Long-run welfare analyses of Kay and Keen (1983), Keen (1998), and
Anderson, de Palma, and Kreider (2001b) point to the negative variety
effect of ad valorem taxation in making a case for a long-run unit
taxation efficiency advantage. (7) In their locational models of product
differentiation, however, the price effect does not have any real
efficiency role to play because the quantity demanded is either one or
none for each consumer. In contrast, it is exactly the price effect that
generates ad valorem taxation's long-run welfare dominance in
studies featuring homogenous products. Using a different model of
product differentiation in this paper, we take both price and variety
effects into consideration and show that the price reduction benefits of
ad valorem taxation can always sufficiently compensate for its variety
disadvantage so that in the long run, ad valorem taxation welfare
dominates equal-revenue unit taxation.
2. The Model
Demand Functions
Let the taxed market consist of a set of m [greater than or equal
to] 2 goods {1,..., i,..., m} with each good produced by a single firm.
Further, assume that there are n identical individuals in the economy.
Following Dixit and Stiglitz (1977), let a representative
individual's utility function be
(1) u([z.sub.1],...[z.sub.m];x) [equivalent to]
[f[([z.sup.([theta]-1)/[theta].sub.1] + ... +
[z.sup.([theta]-1)/[theta].sub.m]).sup.[theta]/([theta]-1)],x]
[equivalent to] f(Z, x),
where [z.sub.i] is the individual's consumption of the ith
firm's product, 1 < [theta] < [infinity] is the common
elasticity of substitution among goods in the market, (8) and x is the
individual's consumption of a composite numeraire good. It is
easily shown that given total expenditure by all individuals on the m
goods in the market, E, the total demand from the ith firm is
(2) [q.sub.i] = n[z.sub.i] =
[m.sup.-1]E[p.sup.-[theta].sub.i][P.sup.[theta]-1],
where [p.sub.i] is the price of good i, and
(3) P = [([m.sup.-1][m.summation over
i=1][p.sup.1-[theta].sub.i]).sup.1/(1-[theta])]
is a measure of "average market price."
Define market price as Equation 3 and note that this market price
has the property that if [p.sub.i] = p, [for all]i, then P = p. Using
utility function 1, we define market quantity demanded, Q, as
(4) Q = [m.sup.-1/([theta]-1)] [([m.summation over i=1]
[q.sup.([theta]-1)/[theta].sub.i]).sup.[theta]/([theta]-1)],
where Q has the property that if [q.sub.i] = q, [for all]i, then Q
= mq. Substituting Equation 2 into Equation 4 and using Equation 3, we
have QP [equivalent to] E for arbitrary [p.sub.i] (i = 1, ..., m).
Therefore, the above definitions of P and Q result in their product
equaling total market expenditure.
In general, E is a function of P, with the exact functional form
depending on the functional form of f(Z, x) in utility function 1.
Specifically, given E, we have from Equation 2 that [z.sub.i] =
[(mn).sup.-1]E[p.sup.-[theta].sub.i][P.sup.[theta]-1]. Substituting this
into f (Z, x) and simplifying, we have f (Z, x) = f
([m.sup.1/([theta]-1)][P.sup.-1]E/n, x). E(P) is the solution to the
problem of choosing E and x to maximize f ([m.sup.1/([theta]-1)
[P.sup.-1]E/n, x), subject to (E/n) + x = Y, where E/n is total
individual expenditure on goods in the taxed market and Y is individual
income.
To facilitate tractable analytical treatment, we assume
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.].
so that E(P) has the form
E(P) = [bar.E][P.sup.-[eta]+1],
where K and [eta] are positive constants, and [bar.E] =
n[K.sup.[eta][m.sup.([eta]-1)/([theta]-1)] is a coefficient independent
of P or any individual [p.sub.i]. This assumption implies a
constant-elasticity market demand,
Q = [bar.E][P.sup.-n],
with [eta] being the absolute value of the price elasticity of
market demand. (9) The constant market demand elasticity assumption
allows us to write the demand for firm i's product Equation 2 as
(5) [q.sub.i] =
[bar.E][m.sup.-1][p.sup.-[theta].sub.i][P.sup.[theta]-[eta].
The two elasticities, [eta] and [theta], play important roles in
this paper. We have the following assumptions and properties concerning
their values.
ASSUMPTION 1. [theta] + [eta] > 2.
As we see further on, a positive market price in the oligopoly
equilibrium requires that ([theta] - 1)m - [theta] + [eta] > 0, which
is equivalent to [theta] + [eta] > 2, as indicated by the following
property.
PROPERTY 1. ([theta] - 1)m - [theta] + [eta] > 0 for all m
[greater than or equal to] 2 if and only if [theta] + [eta] >2.
PROOF: The equivalence between the two conditions is
straightforward using the facts that ([theta] - 1)m - [theta] + [eta] is
an increasing function of m for [theta] > 1 and that ([theta] - 1)m -
[theta] + [eta] > 0 for m = 2 if and only if [theta] + [eta] > 2.
QED.
ASSUMPTION 2. [theta] > [eta].
It seems reasonable to assume that any good in the taxed market is
a closer substitute to the goods in the market as a group than any good
outside the market. If this is true, then from the following property,
[theta] > [eta].
PROPERTY 2. If [q.sub.i] is a closer substitute to Q than x is to Q
for all i, then [theta] > [eta].
PROOF: From Equation 5, we have that the cross elasticity of demand for good i in the taxed market with respect to the market price P is
[differential][q.sub.i]/[differential]P P/[q.sub.i] = [theta] -
[eta],
implying that [theta] - [eta] is a measure of substitutability
between any [q.sub.i] and Q. Further, from the budget constraint P[Qn.sup.-1] + x = Y and Q = [bar.E][P.sup.-[eta]], the cross elasticity
of demand for the numeraire good (goods outside the market as a group) x
with respect to P is
[differential]x/[differential]P P/x = PQ/nx([eta] - 1).
One would normally expect that [q.sub.i] (a good in the market) is
a closer substitute to Q than x (the composite of goods outside the
market) is to Q. Therefore,
[theta] - [eta] > PQ/nx([eta] - 1).
It follows then that [theta] - [eta] > 0 because if [eta] <
1, [theta] - [eta] > 0 by virtue of the assumption that [theta] >
1, and if [eta] [greater than or equal to] 1, the right side of the
preceding relation is greater than or equal to 0; therefore [theta] -
[eta] > 0. QED.
As we show shortly, whether [eta] is larger or smaller than unity
often determines the direction of the relative desirability of the two
forms of excise taxation. The following property relates this condition
to the substitutability and complementarity between the taxed market and
the other market. As a result, we can say that while [theta] is a
measure of within-market substitutability, [eta] is a measure of
between-market substitutability.
PROPERTY 3. x and Q are gross substitutes if and only if [eta] >
1.
PROOF: From the budget constraint PQ[n.sup.-1] + x = Y and Q =
[bar.E][P.sup.-n], we have that
[differential]x/[differential]P = ([eta] - 1)Q/n.
So x and Q are gross substitutes if and only if [eta] > 1. QED.
Short-Run Market Equilibrium
Let all firms in the market have constant marginal cost equal to c.
Given the prices charged by other firms and a unit tax [tau], the first
order condition for firm i's profit-maximizing pricing behavior is
(6) [q.sub.i] + ([p.sub.i] - [tau] -c) [differential][q.sub.i] /
[differential][p.sub.i] = 0.
It follows from symmetry that all prices are equal in equilibrium.
Using Equation 5 in solving Equation 6, the (Nash) equilibrium price and
quantity under the unit tax [tau] are, respectively,
(7) [p.sup.[tau]] = [[theta]m - [theta] + [eta]/([theta] - 1)m -
[theta] + [eta]] (c + [tau])
and
(8) [q.sup.[tau]] = [Em.sup.-1][([p.sup.[tau]]).sup.-[eta]].
Under an ad valorem tax t, where t is the tax rate on producer
prices, a consumer price for firm i's product [p.sub.i] implies a
corresponding producer price of [p.sub.i]/(1 + t). Thus, the first order
condition for firm i's profit maximizing pricing problem, given
other firms' prices, is
(9) [q.sub.i]/1 + t + ([p.sub.i]/1 + t - c)
[differential][q.sub.i]/[differential][p.sub.i] = 0.
The (Nash) equilibrium price and quantity under the ad valorem tax
t are, respectively,
(10) [p.sup.t] = [[theta]m - [theta] + [eta]/([theta] - 1)m -
[theta] + [eta]] (c + ct)
and
(11) [q.sup.t] = [Em.sup.-1] [([p.sup.t]).sup.[eta]]
Note that according to Property 1, Assumption 1 ([theta] + [eta]
> 2) guarantees that ([theta] - 1)m - [theta] + [eta] > 0.
Therefore, from Equations 7 and 10, the equilibrium price under either
tax regime is positive. On the other hand, consistent with the short-run
analysis, we do not impose a condition here that guarantees positive
profits for the firms in the market. In section 4, we analyze long-run
equilibrium where entry and exit provide an additional equilibrating
mechanism.
3. Short-Run Results
Denoting fixed cost as [C.sub.F] and using Equations 7 and 8, the
equilibrium per-firm profit and government revenue under a unit tax
regime are, respectively,
(12) [[pi].sup.[tau]] = ([p.sup.[tau]] - [tau] - c) [q.sup.[tau]] -
[C.sub.F] = [E/[(c + [tau]).sup.[eta]-1]] {[[([theta] - 1)m - [theta] +
[eta]].sup.[eta]-1]/ [[[theta]m - [theta] + [eta]].sup.[eta]]} -
[C.sub.F]
and
(13) [R.sup.[tau]] = m[tau][q.sup.[tau]] = [E[tau]/[(c +
[tau]).sup.[eta]]] [[([theta] - 1)m - [theta] + [eta]]/[theta]m -
[theta] + [eta]].sup.[eta]].
In the same fashion, using Equations 10 and 11, the equilibrium
per-firm profit and government revenue under the ad valorem tax are,
respectively,
(14) [[pi].sup.t] = ([p.sup.t]/1 + t - c)[q.sup.t] - [C.sub.F] =
[Ec/[(c + ct).sup.[eta]]] {[[([theta] - 1)m - [theta] +
[eta]].sup.[eta]-1]/[[[theta]m - [theta] + [eta]].sup.[eta]] - [C.sub.F]
and
(15) [R.sup.t] = m([p.sup.t]t/1 + t)[q.sup.t] = [Ect/[(c +
ct).sup.[eta]]] [[([theta] - 1)m - [theta] + [eta]/[theta]m - [theta] +
[eta]].sup.[eta]-1].
For market demand elasticities greater than unity, the requirement
that government always sets tax rates in the increasing portion of the
total tax revenue function implies, from Equations 13 and 15, certain
relations between [tau] and [eta] and between t and [eta], which are
stated as the following assumption.
ASSUMPTION 3. For [eta] > 1,
[tau]/c < 1/[eta] - 1 and t < 1/[eta] - 1.
Note that if market demand is inelastic ([eta] [less than or equal
to] 1), feasible tax rates are unrestricted. We adopt Assumption 3
throughout this paper. (10) Now consider the welfare implications of
switching from a unit tax with a tax rate [tau] to an ad valorem tax
that maintains the same level of revenue. The minimum ad valorem tax
rate that generates at least the unit tax revenue, which we denote as
[t.sup.[tau]], is the solution to
(16) [t.sup.[tau]] / [(1 + [t.sup.[tau]]).sup.[eta]] = [tau]/c /
[(1 + [tau]/c).sup.[eta]] [([theta] - 1)m - [theta] + [eta] / [theta]m -
[theta] + [eta]].
Because the bracketed term on the right side of Equation 16 is less
than 1 for any finite 0, we have [t.sup.[tau]] < [tau]/c as long as
total tax revenue is increasing in the tax rate at the original unit tax
rate. (11) Thus, it follows from Equations 7 and 10 that [p.sup.t] <
[p.sup.[tau]], and we have the following proposition.
PROPOSITION 1. Whenever market goods are heterogeneous (finite
[theta]), for any unit tax, there exists an ad valorem tax that raises
the same amount of revenue and generates higher welfare for consumers of
the taxed goods.
That consumer surplus is increased when a unit tax is replaced with
an equal-revenue ad valorem tax does not automatically imply that such a
tax switch is Pareto improving or even overall welfare improving
(however the overall welfare is defined), because firm owners may
experience reduced income (as is clear from Proposition 2). Following
the Pareto comparison approach as represented in Skeath and Trandel
(1994), we assume in this paper that firm owners, who only consume the
numeraire commodity so that their welfare is monotonic in profits, are a
different group of people than the consumers of the taxed goods.
Therefore, only if an equal-revenue replacement of a unit tax with an ad
valorem tax raises both consumer surplus and firm profits, is such a
change regarded as Pareto improving. In the rest of this section, the
focus is on firms' comparative profitability under alternative
forms of excise taxes. Nonetheless, in the Appendix, we show that ad
valorem taxation always welfare dominates unit taxation in the short run
in our model if consumers of the taxed goods are also the owners of the
firms that produce these goods. (12)
Using Equations 12 and 14, we have that the difference in profits
when a unit tax is replaced with an equal-revenue ad valorem tax is
(17) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
so that
(17) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.].
For any given values of [theta], [eta], m and [tau]/c, the
equal-revenue generating ad valorem tax rate [t.sup.[tau]] can be
calculated from Equation 16. Then Equation 17 can be checked to see
whether profits are higher under ad valorem taxation.
Begin by considering the special case where goods in the market
taken as a group and all other goods (represented by the numeraire good
x) are not gross substitutes (that is, [eta] [less than or equal to] 1
according to Property 1). Note first that price-setting firms have a
stronger incentive to reduce their price under an ad valorem tax regime
than under a unit tax regime because the tax paid on each unit of their
product is proportional to the price charged. The effects on firms'
profits of a lower price under ad valorem taxation are twofold. Lower
prices reduce per unit profit but increase quantity demanded. Whether
profits will be enhanced by switching to the ad valorem regime depends
on the relative magnitude of these two effects. The smaller the market
demand elasticity, the less likely the quantity effect will dominate the
price effect. In particular, when [eta] [less than or equal to] 1, with
a lower price, output rises, but total sales revenue falls, leaving
firms with lower profits. Thus, we have the following proposition.
PROPOSITION 2. If [eta] < 1, then firms earn lower profits under
ad valorem taxation than under unit taxation that generates the same tax
revenue.
PROOF: We must show that, when [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.] and finite [theta]. Because [t.sup.[tau]] <
[tau]/c, [eta] [less than or equal to] 1 implies from Equation 17 that
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]. QED.
Proposition 2 says that, in the case in which the taxed market
features an inelastic market demand, ad valorem Pareto dominance fails
although consumers are always better off under ad valorem taxation than
under equal-revenue unit taxation according to Proposition 1.
Proposition 2 provides us with a basis for the existence of both forms
of taxation that is not based on market or government imperfections.
Specifically, for markets with inelastic demand, firm profits are
greater with unit taxation. However, we do not expect many such markets
to exist because such markets must be gross complements to all other
goods. (13)
We know that ad valorem taxation Pareto dominance does not hold
when the taxed market is a gross complement to all other goods ([eta]
[less than or equal to] 1), but is there a combination of finite [theta]
and [eta] > 1 that assures ad valorem taxation Pareto dominance? If
so, is Pareto dominance more likely with smaller [theta] or larger
[eta]? (14) The answer to both questions is yes and is reflected in the
following fact and proposition.
FACT (Existence). Pareto dominance of ad valorem taxation holds for
some [theta] < [infinity] and [eta] > 1.
Consider a hypothetical economy with [theta] = 3, [eta] = 2, m = 2,
[tau]/c = 0.5. (15) From Equation 16, [t.sup.[tau] = 0.188 and from
Equation 17, the ratio determining the relative advantage from the
firms' perspective of ad valorem taxation is 1.063 > 1.
Therefore, [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]. So, for
this case, an equal-revenue replacement of a unit tax with an ad valorem
tax will be Pareto improving. Given the existence of ad valorem Pareto
dominance, we have the following proposition.
PROPOSITION 3.
(a) Other things being equal, ad valorem taxation is more likely to
Pareto dominate equal-revenue unit taxation the larger the degree of
product differentiation in the taxed market.
(b) Other things being equal, ad valorem taxation is more likely to
Pareto dominate equal-revenue unit taxation the more elastic the market
demand.
PROOF: (a) We want to prove that for fixed values of [eta] > 1,
m, [tau]/c, if [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.] for
[theta] = [[theta].sub.1], then [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.] for any [[theta].sub.2] < [[theta].sub.1].
First, the right side of Equation 16 is increasing in [theta]. Second,
the left side of Equation 16 is increasing in [t.sup.[tau]] under
Assumption 2 that the revenue effect of an increase in tax rates is
positive. Thus, [dt.sup.[tau]]/d[theta] > 0. Then, the left side
ratio of Equation 17, [(1 + [tau]/c).sup.[eta]-1]/[(1 +
[t.sup.[tau]).sup.[eta]], is decreasing in [theta]. Hence, if
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.] when [theta] =
[[theta].sub.1], then [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII.] when [theta] = [[theta].sub.2] < [[theta].sub.1].
(b) We want to prove that for given values of [theta], m, [tau]/c,
if [t.sup.[tau]] from Equation 16 decreases in [eta] and [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.], for [eta] = [[eta].sub.1] then
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.] for any
[[eta].sub.2] > [[eta].sub.1]. Note that
(18) d { 1n [[(1+[tau]/c).sup.[eta]-1]/
[(1+[t.sup.[tau]).sup.[eta]]] / d[eta]} = 1n (1 + [tau]/c / 1 +
[t.sup.[tau]]) - ([eta] / 1 + [t.sup.[tau]]) [dt.sup.[tau]] / d[eta],
which is positive if ([dt.sup.[tau]/d[eta]) < 0. Then, from
Equation 17, if [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.] for
[eta] = [[eta].sub.1], then [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII.] for any [[eta].sub.2] > [[eta].sub.1]. QED.
Skeath and Trandel (1994) established that a monopoly can earn a
larger profit under an
ad valorem tax that generates the same level of tax revenue as a
unit tax. So part (a) of Proposition 3 can be easily explained because
each firm in the oligopoly market operates more like a monopoly as the
elasticity of substitution among their products gets smaller. The
intuition for part (b) of Proposition 3 is the same as that for
Proposition 2.
For an oligopoly market with homogenous products and linear demand,
Skeath and Trandel (1994) found that Pareto dominance of ad valorem
taxation never holds when the number of firms in a market is
sufficiently large, but always holds when the tax level exceeds a
critical value. With product heterogeneity where firms engage in
Bertrand competition, however, the first of these propositions continues
to hold while the second does not.
PROPOSITION 4. (a) Other things being equal, ad valorem taxation is
less likely to Pareto dominate equal-revenue unit taxation the larger
the number of firms in the taxed market. (b) Other things being equal,
ad valorem taxation is more likely to Pareto dominate equal-revenue unit
taxation the lower the tax level.
PROOF: (a) We want to prove that for given values of [theta],
[eta], and [tau]/c, if [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII.] for m = [m.sub.1], then [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.] for any [m.sub.2] > [m.sub.1]. First, by
signing its derivative with respect to m, the second term on the right
side of Equation 16 can be shown to be increasing in m. Second, the left
side of Equation 16 is increasing in [t.sup.[tau]] so long as revenues
increase with tax rates. Thus, ([dt.sup.[tau]]/dm) > 0. Then from
Equation 17, results in part (a) follow.
(b) We want to prove that for given values of [eta], m, c and
sufficiently large [theta], if [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE
IN ASCII.] for [tau] = [[tau].sub.1], then [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.] for any [[tau].sub.2] < [[tau].sub.1]. First,
from Equation 16,
[dt.sub.[tau] / d([tau]/c) = 1/[tau]/c - [eta]/1+[tau]/c /
1/[t.sup.[tau]] - [eta]/1+[t.sup.[tau]].
Also from Equation 16, [t.sup.[tau]] [right arrow] [tau]/c when
[theta] [right arrow] [infinity]. Hence,
(19) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
Second,
d 1n [[(1+[tau]/c).sup.[eta]-1] / [(1+[t.sup.[tau]]).sup.[eta]]] /
d([tau]/c) = [eta] - 1 / 1 + [tau]/c - [eta] / 1 + [t.sup.[tau]]
[dt.sup.[tau]] / d([tau]/c)
which, from Equation 19 and that [t.sup.[tau]] < [tau]/c, is
negative when [theta] is sufficiently large. So,
[(1 + [tau]/c).sup.[eta]-1] / [(1 + [t.sup.[tau]]).sup.[eta]]
decreases in [tau] for given c. Then, from Equation 17, results in
part (b) follow. QED.
The first part of Proposition 4 confirms prior results regarding
the effect of the number of firms in an oligopoly market on ad valorem
taxation Pareto dominance. We can offer some intuition for why [theta]
> [eta] guarantees that a larger number of firms in the market makes
an equal-revenue switch from unit to ad valorem tax regimes less likely
to increase firm profits. First, note that a major difference between
unit and ad valorem taxation is that price-setting firms have a stronger
incentive to lower their prices under an ad valorem tax regime because
taxes are proportional to price. A larger number of firms in the market
serves to strengthen this price incentive. Whether all firms in the
market can benefit from individual firms' incentive to lower prices
depends on whether the sales increase for individual firms comes from
expanding market demand or from "stealing" other firms'
sales, which in turn depends on the relative magnitudes of [eta] and
[theta].
The second part of Proposition 4 says that the smaller the original
unit tax rate, the more likely an equal-revenue switch from unit to ad
valorem taxation will increase firm profits. Thus, when the goods in the
market are sufficiently close substitutes, the lower the original level
of a unit tax the more likely an equal-revenue ad valorem tax will
Pareto dominate, exactly the opposite of previous homogeneous product
linear demand results. Alternative but equally plausible assumptions are
responsible for the differential results. Specifically, we assume
Bertrand competition and a demand with constant price elasticity, while
Skeath and Trandel (1994) use Coumot competition and linear demand. Our
results here serve to show that the ad valorem Pareto dominance, with
respect to the level of taxation, is sensitive to model specifications.
4. Long-Run Equilibrium: The Case of Endogenous Variety
The short-run results for a heterogeneous product market are more
restrictive than for homogeneous markets because holding the number of
firms constant, holds product variety constant. Because firms'
profits are always zero in the long ran, the focus here is on consumer
welfare. (16) When variety is endogenous, excise tax comparisons must
account for both price and variety effects. Given utility function 1,
for any given elasticity of substitution among goods in the market,
consumers' welfare is determined by market price as well as market
variety. Thus, an assessment of the welfare implications of the two
excise taxes must take into account their impact on both market price
and variety.
In this section we examine whether ad valorem taxation welfare
dominance exists in the long run. (17) Our main long-run results are the
following: (i) While a switch to ad valorem taxation reduces market
price, consumer choice may also be reduced; (ii) ad valorem taxation
welfare dominance always holds.
The approach taken in this section is a little different from that
taken in previous sections. Rather than making a direct comparison
between all unit taxation and all ad valorem taxation, we begin with a
mix of both taxes and analyze the effects of substituting ad valorem for
unit taxation at the margin. (18) When both a unit tax [tau] and an ad
valorem tax t are imposed, the ith firm's problem is to choose
[p.sub.i] to maximize its profits
[q.sub.i] = ([p.sub.i] - [tau]/1 + t - c) - [C.sub.F],
where [q.sub.i] is related to [p.sub.i] through Equation 5. The
first order condition yields the equilibrium price
(20) p = (c + [tau] + tc)[[theta]m - [theta] + [eta]]/([theta] -
1)m - [theta] + [eta]
for all the goods in the market. (19)
The zero profit condition that determines the equilibrium number of
firms is
[Em.sup.-1][p.sup.-[eta]](p - [tau]/1 + t - c) - [C.sub.F] = 0,
or, substituting E = n[K.sup.[eta]][m.sup.([eta]-1)/([theta]-1)]
from the discussion before Equation 5,
(21) n[K.sup.[eta]][m([eta]-[theta])/([theta]-1)][[p.sup.-[eta]](p
- [tau] - c - tc) - (1 + t)[C.sub.F] = 0
From Equations 20 and 21, the following comparative statics results, with respect to the effects of a change in either z or t on the
equilibrium m and p, are obtained (See Appendix for a derivation):
[differential]m/[differential][tau] = ([theta] - 1)m[([theta] - 1)m
- [theta] + [eta]][[theta]m - [theta] + [eta]]/[OMEGA](c + [tau] +
tc)([theta] - [eta]) ([eta] - 1),
[differential]p/[differential][tau] = - p/[OMEGA](c + [tau] + tc)
([theta]m + [eta] - 1)[([theta] - 1)m - [theta] + [eta]],
[differential]m/[differential]t = ([theta] - 1)m[([theta] - 1)m -
[theta] + [eta]][[theta]m - [theta] + [eta]]/[OMEGA](c + [tau] +
tc)([theta] - [eta]) [[tau] + [eta]c(1 + t)]/(1 + t),
[differential]p/[differential]t = - p/[OMEGA](c + [tau] + tc)
([theta] - 1)m[[tau] + [eta]c(1 + t)] - c(1 + t)[OMEGA]/(1 + t),
where
[OMEGA] = -([theta] - 1)([theta] - [eta])(m - 1) - ([theta]m -
[theta] + [eta])[([theta] - 1)m - [theta] + [eta]] < 0.
Hence, from Equation 22, [differential]p/[differential][tau] >
0, [differential]p/[differential]t > 0,
[differential]m/[differential]t < 0, and
[differential]m/[differential][tau] [greater than or equal to] 0 if and
only if [eta] [less than or equal to] 1.
The effect of taxation on the equilibrium number of firms is a
combination of two factors: an industry scale effect and a firm scale
effect. A pure increase in ad valorem taxation reduces equilibrium
market quantity. Although equilibrium firm size may go up or down, the
market downsizing effect always dominates. As a result, an uncompensated increase in ad valorem taxation reduces the number of firms. On the
other hand, a pure increase in the level of a unit tax decreases both
equilibrium market quantity and equilibrium firm size. If the resulting
market quantity decrease is small enough, it will be more than offset by
the decrease in equilibrium firm scale, and the number of firms may
actually rise. As it turns out, a market demand elasticity less than one
is sufficient to ensure that the reduction in firm scale dominates the
market scale reduction, so the number of firms rises in response to a
pure increase in unit taxation.
Kay and Keen (1983) and Anderson, de Palma, and Kreider (2001 a)
found, as we did here, that the long-run equilibrium consumer price
increases in both tax rates. Using a locational model of product
differentiation, Kay and Keen (1983) also found that an increase in ad
valorem taxation reduces variety. As they explain, ad valorem taxation
is akin to a grossing up of the fixed cost associated with each variety.
While we confirm the negative effect of ad valorem taxation on variety,
we find that unit taxation also has a variety effect and relate the
variety effect of unit taxation to the elasticity of market demand.
For our purposes, we want to consider the revenue-neutral
substitution of ad valorem taxation for unit taxation. In equilibrium,
the market price p and the number of firms m are functions of tax rates
[tau] and t, as implicitly determined by Equations 20 and 21. Therefore,
the total tax revenue from the market can also be expressed as a
function of these tax rates, which is
R([tau], t) = mq(p - p - [tau]/1 + t),
where q = [Em.sup.-1][p.sup.-[eta]]. Substituting E =
n[K.sup.[eta]][m.sup.([eta]-1)/([theta]-1)] and the zero-profit
condition
q(p - [tau]/1 + t - c) = [C.sub.F],
we arrive at
(23) R([tau], t) =
n[K.sup.[eta]][m.sup.([eta]-1)/([theta]-1)][p.sup.-[eta]](p - c) -
m[C.sub.F].
Note that in the tax revenue expression 23, tax rates [tau] and t
do not directly appear, and R([tau], t) is a function of [tau] and t
through p and m. Such an expression of the tax revenue function is
significant in simplifying some of the following derivations.
The effects of an increase in [tau] or t on the tax revenue are
given by
(24) [differential]R/[differential][tau] =
n[K.sup.[eta]][m.sup.([eta] - 1)/([theta] - 1)][p.sup.-[eta]][1 -
[eta]([p-c)/p] [differential]p/[differential][tau] +
n[K.sup.[eta]][m.sup.([eta]-1)/([theta]-1)-1][p.sup.-[eta]][(p - c)
[eta]- 1/ [theta]-1 - p-c-[tau]-tc/1+t]
[differential]m/[differential][tau]
[differential]R/[differential]t =
n[K.sup.[eta]][m.sup.([eta]-1)/([theta]-1)][p.sup.-[eta]][1 -
[eta]([p-c)/p] [differential]p/[differential]t +
n[K.sup.[eta]][m.sup.([eta]-1)/([theta]-1)-1][p.sup.-[eta]][(p - c)
[eta]-1/[theta]-1 - p-c-[tau]-tc/1+t] [differential]m/[differential]t
both of which are assumed to be positive. (20) Substituting ad
valorem taxation for unit taxation at the margin while keeping tax
revenue unchanged requires that
(25) d[tau]/dt = -
[differential]R/[differential]t/[differential]R/[differential][tau].
PROPOSITION 5. A revenue-constant substitution of ad valorem
taxation for unit taxation always reduces market price, but reduces the
number of firms as well if [eta] [less than or equal to] 1, that is, if
the taxed market is not a gross substitute to the numeraire.
PROOF: The impact on the consumer price of a constant-revenue
increase in ad valorem taxation (with an offsetting decrease in unit
taxation) is given by
(26) dp/dt = [differential]p/[differential]t +
[differential]p/[differential]t d[tau]/dt =
[([differential]R/[differential][tau]).sup.-1]
([differential]R/[differential][tau] [differential]p/[differential]t -
[differential]R/[differential]t [differential]p/[differential][tau]) =
[([differential]R/[differential][tau]).sup.-1]
n[K.sup.[eta]][m.sup.([eta]-1)/([theta]-1)-1][p.sup.-[eta]][(p-c)[eta] -
1/[theta] - 1 - p - c - [tau] - tc/1 +
t]{[differential]m/[differential][tau] [differential]p/[differential]t -
[differential]m/[differential]t [differential]p/[differential][tau]}.
In the Appendix, it is shown that
(27) (p - c) [eta] - 1/[theta] - 1 - p - c - [tau] - tc/1 + t <
0
and
(28) [differential]m/[differential][tau]
[differential]p/[differential]t - [differential]m/[differential]t
[differential]p/[differential][tau] = - p([theta] - 1)m[([theta] - 1)m -
[theta] + [eta]][[theta]m - [theta] + [eta]]/(1 + t)[OMEGA][(c + [tau] +
tc).sup.2]([theta] - n) [[tau] + c(1 + t)] > 0.
Therefore, dp/dt < 0. That is, market price falls as unit
taxation is replaced with ad valorem taxation. On the other hand, the
impact on the number of firms of a revenue-constant move toward ad
valorem taxation is determined by
dm/dt = [differential]m/[differential]t +
[differential]m/[differential][tau] d[tau]/dt.
Because [differential]m/[differential]t, d[tau]/dt < 0,
[differential]m/[differential][tau] [greater than or equal to] 0 is
sufficient (but not necessary) for ensuring that dm/dt < 0, which is
the case if [eta] [less than or equal to] 1. QED.
When variety matters in the long-run equilibrium of a heterogenous product market, a lower consumer price under ad valorem taxation by
itself cannot guarantee its welfare dominance, and the variety dimension
must also be considered in determining its relative efficiency. Then,
exactly how is the relative long-run efficiency of the two tax regimes
determined based on their effects on the equilibrium price and variety?
When there are m firms in the taxed market and each firm charges a price
of p, individual welfare, as we established in section 2, is given by
(29) f([m.sup.1/([theta]-1)][p.sup.-1] E/n, Y - E/n),
where E/n is individual expenditure on goods in the taxed market
and Y is individual income. From Equation 29 it follows that a consumer
welfare index that combines both price and variety effects is
[m.sup.1/([theta]-1)][p.sup.-1]. Thus, for an equal-revenue switch from
unit to ad valorem taxation to increase consumer welfare in the long
ran, the price (reduction) effect must be sufficiently large to overcome
any possible negative variety effect. The following proposition says
that this is always the case in our model.
PROPOSITION 6. Ad valorem taxation always welfare dominates unit
taxation in the long run.
PROOF: Because [m.sup.1/([theta]-1)][p.sup.-1] is the welfare index
that combines both price and variety considerations, the welfare impact
of an equal-revenue switch from unit to ad valorem taxation can be
assessed by
(30) d([m.sup.1/([theta]-1)][p.sup.-1])/dt =
[m.sup.1/([theta]-1)-1]/([theta] - 1)p dm/dt -
[m.sup.1/([theta]-1)]/[p.sup.2] dp/dt,
where dp/dt is given by Equation 26 and
dm/dt = [differential]m/[differential]t +
[differential]m/[differential][tau] d[tau]/dt =
[([differential]R/[differential][tau]).sup.-1]
([differential]R/[differential][tau] [differential]m/[differential]t -
[differential]R/[differential]t [differential]m/[differential][tau]) = -
[([differential]R/[differential][tau]).sup.-1]
n[K.sup.[eta]][m.sup.[eta]-1/[theta]-1][p.sup.-[eta]][1 - [eta](p -
c)/p] {[differential]m/[differential][tau]
[differential]p/[differential]t - [differential]m/[differential]t
[differential]p/[differential][tau]}.
Substituting dp/dt and dm/dt, Equation 30 becomes
d([m.sup.1/([theta]-1)][p.sup.-1])/dt =
[([differential]R/[differential][tau]).sup.-1]
n[K.sup.[eta]][m.sup.([eta] - [theta]+1)/ ([theta]-1)][p.sup.-[eta]-2]{-
p/[theta] - 1 [1 - [eta](p-c)/p] - [(p - c) [eta] - 1/[theta] - 1 - p -
c - [tau] - tc/1 + t]} {[differential]m/[differential][tau]
[differential]p/[differential]t - [differential]m/[differential]t
[differential]p/[differential][tau]}
=[([differential]R/[differential][tau]).sup.-1]
n[K.sup.[eta]][m.sup.([eta]-[theta]+1)/([theta]-1)][p.sup.-[eta]-2][-c/[theta] - 1 + p - c - [tau] - tc/1 + t]
{[differential]m/[differential][tau] [differential]p/[differential]t -
[differential]m/[differential]t [differential]p/[differential][tau]}.
From Equation 28,
[differential]m/[differential][tau] [differential]p/[differential]t
- [differential]m/[differential]t [differential]p/ [differential][tau]
> 0.
Further,
-c/[theta]-1 + p - c - [tau] - tc/1 + t = - c/[theta] - 1 + (c +
[tau] + tc)m/[([theta] - 1)m - [theta] + [eta]](1 + t) = -c(1 +
t)[([theta] - 1)m - [theta] + [eta]] + ([theta] - 1)(c + [tau] +
tc)m/([theta] - 1)[([theta] - 1)m - [theta] + [eta]](1 + t) = c(1 +
t)([theta] - [eta]) + ([theta] - 1)[tau]m/([theta] - 1)[([theta] - 1)m -
[theta] + [eta]](1 + t) > 0.
So, d([m.sup.1/([theta]-1)][p.sup.-1])/dt > 0. That is, an
equal-revenue substitution of ad valorem taxation for unit taxation
always increases consumer welfare in the long run. QED.
Proposition 6 is complementary to Kay and Keen (1983) and Anderson,
de Palma, and Kreider (2001b), both of whom used versions of a
locational model of product differentiation to study the relative
efficiency of ad valorem and unit taxes. In Kay and Keen (1983), variety
is excessive in the absence of taxation. So they showed that, initially,
the ad valorem tax, which is variety reducing in locational models,
should be used to bring about the optimal level of product variety, but
any additional revenue should be raised using the unit tax, which is
variety neutral in locational models. For similar reasons, Anderson, de
Palma, and Kreider (2001b) found that ad valorem taxation is welfare
dominated by unit taxation in a locational model in which the
equilibrium variety is optimal in the absence of taxation. However, the
locational models used in these studies, while allowing variety to play
a role in long-run welfare analysis, do not allow a quantity and/or price effect to play any role in the analysis. On the other hand, the
established long-run welfare dominance of ad valorem taxation for
homogenous product markets is entirely based on the quantity and/or
price advantage of ad valorem taxation. While Anderson, de Palma, and
Kreider (2001b) suggested that allowing the quantity and/or price effect
may reverse the results they obtained and give back the ad valorem tax
its efficiency advantage, they did not provide any formal analysis to
substantiate this valuable point. This paper confirms that point and
generalizes their findings.
5. Concluding Remarks
There is a recent trend to study surplus incidence (in contrast to
more traditional price incidence) of excise taxation. (21) Related to
this topic is the investigation of Pareto superiority of ad valorem
taxation in noncompetitive markets. In these Pareto comparisons, the
effect of (equal-revenue) switching between tax regimes on both consumer
and producer surpluses are examined, providing a more complete picture
of who loses or gains from a change in tax structure, enhancing our
understanding of why unit taxes are imposed in some markets and ad
valorem taxes in others. Using the elasticity of substitution parameters
in the utility function, we define market demand and price when a market
consists of heterogeneous products. We can then bring the within-market
and between-market substitutability to bear on the comparison of unit
and ad valorem taxation. As a result, we show conditions under which
consumers and firms would prefer one type of excise taxation to another.
Our results address several interesting aspects of excise taxation.
In the short run, when the number of firms, and by construction product
variety, is fixed, the conditions for Pareto dominance of ad valorem
taxation, while similar to those derived assuming homogeneous product
oligopoly markets, are different in certain critical aspects. First,
when the market consists of heterogeneous products and there exists a
unit tax rate such that an equal-revenue ad valorem tax is Pareto
dominant, any smaller unit tax rate has a corresponding equal-revenue
Pareto dominant ad valorem tax. More importantly, our work emphasizes
the critical importance of between-market substitutability. In
particular, when goods in the taxed market have a complementary relation
to all other goods, implying that market demand is inelastic, ad valorem
taxation Pareto dominance fails in the sense that firms earn lower
profits. The nature of this ad valorem Pareto dominance failure is
important because it rests on the effect on profits of a switch from
unit to ad valorem taxation. While such a change makes consumers better
off in that it results in lower price, firm owners are worse off because
profits are lower. Thus, firms in markets with inelastic demand will
prefer unit taxation, perhaps explaining the persistence of unit
taxation in such markets as gasoline and cigarettes.
While our short-run results are interesting, the real advantage of
our approach is that we allow for long-run adjustment in the number of
firms and, therefore, in product variety. In the long run, the effect of
taxation on general welfare depends not just on the final consumer
price, but on the equilibrium number of firms as well. Again, the
between-market substitutability (the price elasticity of the market
demand for the taxed goods) plays an important role here. An
equal-revenue substitution of ad valorem for unit taxation reduces
variety as long as the goods in the taxed market have a complementary
relation to the other goods (i.e., market demand is inelastic).
Nonetheless, we have been able to show that ad valorem taxation always
welfare dominates unit taxation in the long run.
Appendix
Short-Run Welfare Dominance (in Total Welfare) of Ad Valorem
Taxation
Note that one cannot argue for the short-run ad valorem total
welfare dominance by simply looking at the sum of consumers' and
producers' surpluses and be satisfied with the fact that price is
lower and output is higher, and, therefore, consumer surplus plus
profits is higher under ad valorem taxation than under equal-revenue
unit taxation. First, if consumers and firm owners are two different
sets of people, as these previous studies have implicitly assumed, the
sum of consumer and producer surpluses is not an unambiguous welfare
indicator. In this case, one must separately consider the welfare of
consumers and producers (firm owners), as we did in the present paper.
Second, if consumers are also firm owners, then a comparison of their
welfare under two forms of excise taxes can be unambiguously made. In
this case, however, profits must be explicitly added to consumers'
income in determining final consumer utility under each tax. With regard
to the second scenario, we have the following proposition which upholds
the ad valorem taxation welfare dominance (in total welfare).
PROPOSITION 1'. For the purpose of making a short-run welfare
comparison, assume consumers of the taxed goods own the firms that
produce these goods. Whenever market goods are heterogeneous (finite 0),
for any unit tax, there exists an ad valorem tax that raises the same
amount of revenue and generates higher welfare for individuals as both
consumers and firm owners.
PROOF: The proof consists of two steps. The first step is to show
that adding profits to consumers' income does not alter the finding
that equilibrium price is lower, and equilibrium quantity higher, under
ad valorem taxation than under equal-revenue unit taxation. Within the
assumptions of this model, the equilibrium price and quantity of each
firm under two alternative tax regimes are given by Equations 7 to 8,
and 10 to 11, regardless of whether consumers' income includes
profits. Therefore, the relation between the unit tax rate and the
equal-revenue ad valorem tax rate--Equation 16--still holds. As a
result, price is lower and quantity is higher under ad valorem taxation
than under equal-revenue unit taxation.
The second step is to show that consumer (as both consumers and
firm owners) welfare is improved as the tax regime switches from unit
taxation to equal-revenue ad valorem taxation, given that the price is
lower (and quantity higher) under the latter tax regime. To show this,
it is sufficient to demonstrate that consumers have more money left
after buying the original quantity with the new, lower price, taking
into account the difference in profits under the two tax regimes. Denote
(p, Q) as the price-(aggregate) quantity pair under the original unit
tax regime, and (p', Q') as the price-quantity pair under the
equal-revenue ad valorem tax regime. We have shown in the first step
that p' < p and Q' > Q. Under unit taxation, the money
left (for all consumers) after buying the equilibrium quantity of each
firm's product is
nY + (pQ - R - cQ - m[C.sub.F]) - pQ,
where R is tax revenue paid. Under equal-revenue ad valorem
taxation, on the other hand, the money left after buying the old
quantity (the equilibrium quantity under the unit taxation) of each
firm's product is
nY + (p'Q' - R - cQ' - m[C.sub.F]) - p'Q,
which is larger than the earlier expression by (p' -
c)(Q' - Q) > 0. QED.
Derivation of Comparative Statics Results in Equation 22
Using logarithmic terms, equilibrium conditions 20 and 21 can be
expressed as
n p = ln(c + [tau] + tc) + ln([theta]m - [theta] + [eta]) -
ln[([theta] - 1)m - [theta] + [eta]]
ln(n[K.sup.[eta]]) + [eta] - [theta]/[theta] - 1 ln m - [eta] ln p
+ ln(p - c - [tau] - tc) = ln(1 + [tau]) + ln (C.sub.F).
Taking derivatives with respect to [tau] in the above two
equations, we have
1/p [differential]p/[differential][tau] = 1/c + [tau] + tc +
[[theta]/[theta]m - [theta] + [eta] - [theta] - 1/([theta] - 1)m -
[theta] + [eta]] [differential]m/[differential][tau]
[eta] - [theta]/[theta] - 1 1/m [differential]m/[differential][tau]
+ 1/p - c - [tau] - tc ([differential]p/[differential][tau] - 1) = 0.
Solving for [differential]p/[differential][tau] and
[differential]m/[differential][tau], we have
[differential]m/[differential][tau] = ([theta] - 1)m[([theta] - 1)m
- [theta] + [eta]][[theta]m - [theta] + [eta]]/[OMEGA](c + [tau] +
tc)([theta] - [eta]) x ([eta] - 1)
[differential]p/[differential][tau] = - p/[OMEGA](c + [tau] + tc) x
([theta]m + [eta] - 1)[([theta] - 1)m - [theta] + [eta]].
Similarly, taking derivatives with respect to t in the two
equations in (A1), we have
1/p [differential]p/[differential]t = c/c + [tau] tc +
[[theta]/[theta]m - [theta] + [eta] - [theta] - 1/([theta] - 1)m -
[theta] + [eta]] [differential]m/[differential]t
[eta] - [theta]/[theta] - 1 1/m [differential]m/[differential]t -
n/p [differential]p/[differential]t + 1 /p - c [tau] - tc
([differential]p/[differential]t - c) = 1/ 1 + t.
Solving for [differential]p/[differential]t and
[differential]m/[differential]t, we have
[differential]m/[differential]t = ([theta] - 1)m[([theta] - 1)m -
[theta] + [eta]][[theta]m - [theta] + [eta]]/[OMEGA](c + [tau] +
tc)([theta] - [eta]) x [[tau] + [eta]c(1 + t)/(1 + t)
[differential]p/[differential]t = - p/[OMEGA](c + [tau] + tc) x
([theta] - 1)m[[tau] + [eta]c(1 + t)] - c(1 + t) [OMEGA]/(1 + t)
PROOF OF EQUATION 27. From Equation 24,
(A2) [differential]R/[differential]t =
n[K.sup.[eta]][m.sup.([eta]-1)/([theta]-1)][p.sup.-[eta]][1 - [eta](p -
c)/p] [differential]p/[differential]t +
n[K.sup.[eta]][m.sup.([eta]-1)/([theta]-1)][p.sup.-[eta]][(p - c) [eta]
- 1/ [theta] - 1 - p - c - [tau] - tc/1 + t]
[differential]m/[differential]t.
To prove
(p - c) [eta] - 1/[theta] - 1 - p - c - [tau] - tc/1 + t < 0,
consider the following two situations, while keeping in mind that,
from Equation 22, [differential]p/[differential]t > 0 and
[differential]m/[differential]t < 0.
(a) 1 - [eta](p - c)/p < 0.
In this case, the assumption [differential]R/[differential]t > 0
implies
(p - c) [eta] - 1/[theta] - 1 - p - c - [tau] - tc/1 + t < 0.
(b) 1 - [eta](p - c)/p [greater than or equal to] 0.
In this case, [eta] [less than or equal to] p/(p - c). Then
(p - c) [eta] - 1/[theta] - 1 - p - c - [tau] - tc/1 + t [less than
or equal to] (p - c) p/p - c - 1/[theta] - 1 - p - c - [tau] - tc/1 + t
= c/[theta] - 1 - p - c - [tau] - tc/1 + t = c/[theta] - 1 - (c + [tau]
+ tc)m/(1 + t)[([theta] - 1)m - [theta] + [eta]] = - c(1 + t)([theta] -
[eta]) + ([theta] - 1) [tau]m/([theta] - 1)(1 + t)[([theta] - 1)m -
[theta] + [eta]] < 0.
DERIVATION OF EQUATION 28. From Equation 22,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.].
References
Anderson, Simon P., Andre de Palma, and Brent Kreider. 2001a. Tax
incidence in differentiated product oligopoly. Journal of Public
Economics 81 : 173-92.
Anderson, Simon P., Andre de Palma, and Brent Kreider. 2001b. The
efficiency of indirect taxes under imperfect competition. Journal of
Public Economics 81:231-51.
Barzel, Yoram. 1976. An alternative approach to the analysis of
taxation. Journal of Political Economy 84:1177-97.
Bohanon, Cecil E., and T. Norman Van Cott. 1991. Product quality
and taxation: A reconciliation. Public Finance Quarterly 19:233-7.
Cremer, Helmutyh, and Jacques-Francois Thisse. 1994. Taxation in a
differentiated oligopoly. International Economic Review 35:613-33.
Delipalla, Sofia, and Michael Keen. 1992. The comparison between ad
valorem and specific taxation under imperfect competition. Journal of
Public Economics 49:351-67.
Dixit, Avinash K., and Joseph E. Stiglitz. 1977. Monopolistic
competition and optimum product diversity. American Economic Review
67:297-308.
Hines, James R., Jr., John C. Hlinko, and Theodore J. F. Lubke.
1995. From each according to his surplus: equi-proportionate sharing of
commodity tax burdens. Journal of Public Economics 58:417-28.
Kay, John, and Michael Keen. 1983. How should commodities be taxed?
European Economic Review 23:339-58.
Kay, John, and Michael Keen. 1991. Product quality under specific
and ad valorem taxation. Public Finance Quarterly 19: 238-47.
Keen, Michael. 1998. The balance between ad valorem and specific
taxation. Fiscal Studies 19:1-37.
Liu, Liqun. 2003. Relative efficiency of ad valorem and unit taxes:
the case of endogenous quality. Public Finance Review 31:291-301.
Saving, Thomas R. 1982. Market organization and product quality.
Southern Economic Journal 48:855-67.
Skeath, Susan E., and Gregory A. Trandel. 1994. A pareto comparison
of ad valorem and unit taxes in noncompetitive environments. Journal of
Public Economics 53:53-71.
Suits, David B. and Richard A. Musgrave. 1953. Ad valorem and unit
taxes compared. Quarterly Journal of Economics 67: 598-604.
Trandel, Gregory A. 1999. Producers lose: The relative percentage
reductions in surplus due to an ad valorem commodity tax. Public Finance
Review 27:96-104.
(1) However, the two versions of excise taxes are not equivalent in
a perfectly competitive market when product quality is endogenous. For
examples of incorporating quality into comparative commodity tax
analysis, see Barzel (1976), Bohanon and Van Cott (1991), Kay and Keen
(1991), Cremer and Thisse (1994), and Liu (2003). See also Saving (1982)
for a general discussion of the product quality and market structure.
Throughout the discussion of this paper, however, we assume that the
quality of each firm's product is exogenously determined.
(2) Suits and Musgrave (1953) showed for the monopoly case that
when the same revenue is raised, equilibrium output and thus welfare is
greater under an ad valorem tax than under a unit tax. Similar welfare
comparison results for the oligopoly market were established by
Delipalla and Keen (1992).
(3) The Pareto dominance of ad valorem taxation in a monopoly
market was first found by Skeath and Trandel (1994). Assuming a
homogeneous product and linear demand in an oligopoly market, Skeath and
Trandel (1994) also demonstrated that the Pareto dominance of ad valorem
taxation holds when the tax level exceeds a critical value but never
holds when the number of firms in a market is sufficiently large.
(4) For example, federal telephone and air transportation taxes and
state and local public utility taxes are ad valorem, while national
gasoline taxes and state liquor and cigarette taxes are unit.
(5) Also see Cremer and Thisse (1994) for an analysis of excise
taxes in a market with vertical product differentiation.
(6) The focus of Kay and Keen (1983) and Keen (1998) is on the long
run in which firms always earn zero profits. On the other hand, although
the incidence analysis of both forms of excise taxes in Anderson, de
Palma, and Kreider (2001a) includes their effects on profits, it is not
a differential incidence analysis in which one form of excise tax is
substituted for another with the total tax revenue unchanged. As a
result, it does not address firm comparative profitability under the
alternative tax regimes.
(7) Anderson, de Palma, and Kreider (2001a) considered the long-ran
price effects but not the variety effects of the two forms of excise
taxes.
(8) The constraint [theta] > 1, first introduced by Dixit and
Stiglitz (1977) to motivate a desire for variety, is imposed here to
ensure an equilibrium for firms' profit maximization problem. The
welfare role of [theta] emphasized by Dixit and Stiglitz is discussed in
section 4 where entry and exit is endogenous.
(9) From this assumption the price elasticity of total expenditures
on goods produced in the oligopoly market is constant at [eta] - 1 and
total expenditures decrease (increase) in P if [eta] - 1 is positive
(negative).
(10) Note that a revenue (or welfare) maximizing government would
not raise tax rates to a point where revenue is decreasing in the tax
rates.
(11) If [theta] = [infinity] (i,e., all goods in the oligopoly
markets are identical), Equation 16 implies [t.sub.[tau]] = [tau]/c.
Therefore, from Equations 7, 8, 10, and 11, the equilibriums for equal
revenue ad valorem and unit taxes are identical. This equivalence result
stands in marked contrast to previous nonequivalence results for
homogenous oligopoly markets [Suits and Musgrave (1953), Delipalla and
Keen (1992), and Skeath and Trandel (1994)] and results from the
fundamental difference between Bertrand competition and Coumot
competition in modeling oligopoly behavior. Bertrand price competition
by oligopoly firms producing identical products leads to the perfect
competition outcome (marginal cost pricing) regardless of tax regime.
(12) It has been unanimously found that ad valorem taxation has an
efficiency advantage in the short run. See, for example, Delipalla and
Keen (1992) for the case of product homogeneity and Anderson, de Palma,
and Kreider (2001b) for the case of product heterogeneity.
(13) We regard gross complementarity as a rare case because, while
possible in a two good world, it is unrealistic in a world where the
other good consists of the composite of all goods not in the single
heterogeneous market, because the income effect of a change in P is
proportional to the ratio of expenditures on Q and all other goods.
Viewing the consumer's utility maximization problem as a choice
between Q/n and x subject to P[Qn.sup.-1] + x = Y, the Slutsky equation gives us [[epsilon].sub.xP] = [[epsilon].sub.xP]|[sub.u] -
([differential]x/[dif (QP/nx)--where [[epsilon].sub.xP],
[[epsilon].sub.xP]|[sub.u] are, respectively, uncompensated and
compensated elasticities of x with respect to P--which is positive for
sufficiently small QP/nx.
(14) Note that the experiment with changes in [eta] must be
conducted within the range where at the original [tau], tax revenue is
increasing in the tax rate so that [tau]/c < 1/([eta] - 1).
(15) Note these parameter values satisfy Assumptions 1 to 3.
(16) If existing firms earn positive (negative) short-run profits
following the regime switch, they will earn positive (negative) profits
during the entire transition. Thus, the short-run results concerning
firms' profitability presented in Propositions 2, 3, and 4, can be
directly generalized to account for transitional profits.
(17) Delipalla and Keen (1992) demonstrate that ad valorem taxation
welfare dominates unit taxation in the long run in homogenous product
oligopoly markets.
(18) The reason for doing so is that with an additional endogenous
variable m and a nonlinear relation among variables, it is impossible to
explicitly solve for p and m under either tax regime. On the other hand,
the marginal approach here does not rely on an explicit solution to the
initial equilibrium.
(19) Note Equation 20 is the general form of Equation 7 or 10.
(20) This assumption is similar to Assumption 3 in spirit. However,
with endogeneity of both p and m, it cannot be easily boiled down to a
simple up-bound on the tax rates.
(21) For examples, see Hines, Hlinko, and Lubke (1995), Trandel
(1999), and Anderson, de Palma, and Kreider (2001a).
Liqun Liu * and Thomas R. Saving ([dagger])
* Private Enterprise Research Center, Texas A&M University,
College Station, TX 77843-4231, USA; E-mail: lliu@tamu.edu.
([dagger]) Private Enterprise Research Center, Texas A&M
University, College Station, TX 77843-4231, USA; E-mail:
t-saving@tamu.edu; corresponding author.
We want to thank Andy Rettenmaier, Laura Razzolini, and several
anonymous referees for very helpful comments and suggestions.
Received November 3, 2003; accepted February 3, 2005.