The effect of recessions on the relationship between output variability and growth.
Olekalns, Nilss
Olan T. Henry (*)
Nilss Olekalns (+)
This paper investigates the relationship between output volatility
and growth using postwar real GDP data for the United States. We expand
on recent research by Beaudry and Koop (1993), documenting the
asymmetric effect of recessions on output growth. The results presented
in this paper suggest that output volatility is highest when the economy
is contracting. While we find that the economy expands most rapidly
following a recession, this expansion is offset by the negative impact
of output uncertainty.
1. Introduction
Traditional approaches to understanding the dynamics of economic
growth emphasized the role played by factor inputs. In contrast, the new
empirical growth literature makes use of a wide variety of auxiliary
explanatory factors. (1) In this paper, we focus on the role played by
one of these auxiliary factors, namely, the part that recessions play in
affecting the dynamics of real output growth. The paper reflects a
recent trend in macroeconomics of bringing together analyses of the
business cycle and of economic growth, areas that until comparatively
recently have been treated by macroeconomists as separate. (2)
Our paper extends the idea, first found in Beaudry and Koop (1993),
that the "current depth of recession" (hereafter CDR) produces
an asymmetry in output growth. This asymmetry is reflected in what is
sometimes known as a "bounce-back" effect, namely, that output
growth recovers strongly following a recent recession. The CDR approach
treats the historical maximum level of output as an attractor that
influences the dynamics of output growth when output falls below its
previous peak. Beaudry and Koop (1993) hypothesize that there is a
nonlinearity in this "peak reversion"; the further output
falls from its peak, the greater is the pressure that builds up for
output to return to its historical maximum. As a result, the speed at
which output recovers varies according to the severity of the recession.
The question of whether CDR asymmetries can be detected in the data
has been examined by Beaudry and Koop (1993), Bradley and Jansen (1997),
Bodman and Crosby (1998), and Jansen and Oh (1999). The empirical
evidence, in general, provides support for the inclusion of CDR
asymmetries in empirical models of economic growth dynamics. (3)
Our research differs from these previous analyses of CDR
asymmetries in that we use an empirical specification that also allows
for the possible existence of a relationship between output volatility
and growth. Whether such a relationship exists has been the subject of
debate at both the theoretical and the empirical level. Business cycle
models based on the natural rate hypothesis deny the existence of any
relation between output variability and growth. According to these
models, deviations of output around its long-run trend are the result of
signal extraction problems relating to workers' and firms'
difficulties in distinguishing relative from absolute price level
changes. Long-run output growth, being dependent on human and physical
capital accumulation, is independent from these information difficulties
(Friedman 1968). An alternate view emphasizes the increased riskiness
associated with investment when output is volatile. This acts to retard
real output growth (Woodford 1990). A third view argues that o utput
volatility will be positively associated with economic growth since
sufficient compensation to make risky investments worthwhile exists only
when growth rates are high (Black 1987).
Attempts to distinguish between these views have tended to find
support for a positive association between output volatility and average
growth rates. This is true for studies based on international
comparisons (Kormendi and Meguire 1985; Grier and Tullock 1989) as well
as for analyses using high-frequency time-series data and GARCH-in-mean
(GARCH-M) techniques (Caporale and McKiernan 1996, 1998). (4) A notable
exception is the cross-country study by Ramey and Ramey (1995), who
identify a negative volatility effect on growth.
Our paper brings these previously disparate strands of the
literature together. We consider a CDR-GARCH-M time-series
representation for U.S. output growth. This specification enables an
investigation of CDR asymmetries in the data while allowing for the
possibility of a volatility effect on output. Our specification also
allows for the possibility that output volatility itself may be subject
to an asymmetry as well.
The results in the paper strongly support the CDR-GARCH-M
specification. We find that the economy tends to expand fastest in the
period immediately after a recession. However, this expansion is offset
by a negative effect of output volatility on growth; we find that the
estimated conditional variance of output is highest in the periods
following a negative innovation to growth and that this acts to dampen
growth. (5)
The empirical model is subjected to a battery of diagnostic tests,
including tests designed to detect bias due to the size and the sign of
innovations and bias due to the omission of depth of recession effects.
We find that the CDR-GARCH-M specification is not rejected by the data.
In contrast, the more usual homoskedastic CDR model of output growth is
revealed as being misspecified.
The paper is organized as follows. In section 2, we describe the
CDR-GARCH-M methodology. The results are presented in section 3, and
section 4 concludes the paper.
2. Methodology
Our starting point is the standard ARMA representation of output
growth,
[THETA](L)[DELTA][y.sub.t] = [micro] + [PHI](L)[[member of].sub.t],
(1)
where [DELTA] is the first-difference operator, [y.sub.t] is a
measure of the natural logarithm of real output, [micro] is a term
capturing any drift in growth, [[member of].sub.t] is an i.i.d. error
term, and [THETA](L) and [PHI](L) are polynomials in the lag operator L.
Equation 1 can be used to forecast the effect of an innovation on output
out to some time horizon j according to
[[SIGMA].aup.j.sub.i=1][[psi].sub.i][[member of].sub.i], where
[psi](L) = [PHI](L)/[THETA](L) = [summation over ([infinity]/i=0)]
[[psi].sub.i][L.sup.i]. (2)
These forecasts will be conditional on there being a symmetric output response to positive and negative innovations. However, measures
of shock persistence derived from Equation 1 and forecasts derived from
Equation 2 will be biased if the data are not fully consistent with the
symmetry assumption.
One way of relaxing the symmetry constraint is to follow Beaudry
and Koop (1993) and augment Equation I with a measure of the CDR. This
is defined as the gap between the current level of output and its
historical maximum level, that is, [CDR.sub.t] =
max[{[y.sub.t-s]}.sup.t.sub.s=0] - [y.sub.t] CDR will take nonzero values either when output dips below its trend value because of a
negative shock or in the aftermath of a positive shock as output returns
to trend. The implication of adding the CDR term to Equation 1 is that
the conditional expectation of future output is influenced by whether
the current level of output is above, below, or at its historical
maximum.
With the introduction of the CDR term, Equation 1 is modified
according to
[THETA](L)[DELTA][y.sub.t] = [micro] + {[PSI](L) - 1}[CDR.sub.t] +
[PHI](L)[[member of].sub.t] (3)
where the lag polynomial [THETA](L) is of order p, [PHI](L) is of
order q, and [PSI](L) is of order r with (0) = 1. This parameterization
for [DELTA][y.sub.t] is very simple and nests the ARMA model (Eqn. 1)
while allowing for the possibility of asymmetries associated with
different stages of the business cycle.
Our concern in this paper is not just to identify an asymmetry in
output growth but to determine whether output volatility affects growth
once asymmetries are accounted for. Therefore, we model the conditional
variance of output and the conditional mean using a modified GARCH-M
specification. Conventional GARCH models allow for both "volatility
clustering" (i.e., the tendency for periods of high [low]
volatility to follow periods of high [low] volatility) and for the
conditional variance to affect the conditional mean (Engle 1982;
Bollerslev 1986; Engle, Lilien, and Robins 1987). However, unlike
conventional GARCH models, we generalize the conditional mean and
conditional variance to allow for the possibility that they are affected
by the state of the business cycle. This leads to the following
CDR-GARCH-M model:
[THETA](L)[DELTA][y.sub.t] = [micro] + {[PSI](L)- 1}[CDR.sub.t] +
[lambda][square root of ([h.sub.t])] + [PHI](L)[[member of].sub.1]
[[member of].sub.t] ~ N(0, [h.sub.t])
[h.sub.t] = [omega] + [alpha](L)[h.sub.t-1] + [beta](L)[[member
of].sup.2.sub.t-1] + [gamma](L)[I.sub.t-1][[member of].sup.2.sub.t-1]
(4)
where
[I.sub.t] = {1 if {max[{[y.sub.t-us]}.sup.t.sub.s=0] - [y.sub.t]}
> 0
0 otherwise,
where the persistence of shocks to the conditional mean and to the
conditional variance can vary according to the phase of the business
cycle. In essence, the model proposes a threshold in the variance.
Periods where the CDR term is nonzero will lead to higher variance of
output compared with periods where the CDR term is zero, if the
coefficient [gamma] is statistically significant. This model is an
extension of the Threshold GARCH of Glosten, Jagannathan, and Runkle
(1993).
3. Results
The data used are U.S. real GNP measured in billions of chained
(1992) dollars, originally sourced from the Bureau of Economic Analysis
and reformatted by Economic Information Systems. The data are quarterly
and span the period 1947:1 to 1998:4. The upper panel of Figure 1 plots
the quarterly growth rate in the data while the lower panel plots the
CDR variable.
Table 1 reports maximum likelihood estimates of Equation 3 using
the scheme proposed by Campbell and Mankiw (1987) to determine the order
of the lag polynomials, p, q, and r. This involves setting the maximum
values of p, q, and r to 3 and p + q + r = 6. The optimal model for each
number of parameters was chosen using the Akaike (1974) and Schwarz
(1978) information criteria.
The results in Table 1 are broadly consistent with those reported
by Beaudry and Koop (1993), namely, that growth is higher in periods
following recessions. Moreover, it is not possible to exclude the CDR
term from Equation 3 on statistical grounds.
Given that the aim of this study is to examine the volatility of
output over the business cycle, we move to the CDR-GARCH-M model
discussed previously. Table 2 reports the maximum likelihood estimates
of the model obtained using the quasi-maximum-likelihood approach of
Bollerslev and Wooldridge (1992). The lag order in the conditional mean
equation was determined initially by assuming that p = q = r = 3 and
testing down. The preferred model was an ARMA(2, 2) p = q = 2, with one
lag of the CDR term, r = 1, and a GARCH in mean coefficient [lambda].
The results of a Ljung-Box test on the standardized residuals,
Q(4), suggest that the preferred model is free from serial correlation in the mean equation. Furthermore, the choice of a Threshold GARCH(1, 1)
parameterization for the conditional variance equation appears
appropriate. We also evaluate the adequacy of the GARCH specification by
using Pagan and Sabau's (1992) moment-based test. This test has its
basis in the implication derived from a GARCH model that E([[member
of].sup.2.sub.t] = [h.sub.t]. The test is based on the satisfaction of
the restriction [H.sub.0]:[[delta].sub.0] = 0, [delta] = 1, in the
auxiliary regression [[member of].sup.2.sub.t] = [[delta].sub.0] +
[[delta].sub.1][h.sub.t] + [[upsilon].sub.t], where [[upsilon].sub.t]
represents a white-noise innovation. As reported in Table 2, the
estimated CDR-GARCH model satisfies the moment condition at all usual
levels of significance. Moreover, on the basis of a Ljung-Box test for
serial correlation in the squared, standardized residuals, [Q.sup.2]
(4), we are unable to detect evidence of misspecification in the
conditional variance.
The CDR-GARCH-M model collapses to a CDR model under the
restrictions [lambda] = [alpha] = [beta] = [gamma] = 0. However, these
restrictions are overwhelmingly rejected using a Wald test. The test
statistic is 43.1249, which under a [chi square](4) distribution
indicates that the marginal significance of the test is 0.0000. The
CDR-GARCH-M model appears to offer a superior conditional data
characterization to the standard CDR model of Beaudry and Koop (1993).
The positive and significant coefficient associated with
[CDR.sub.t-1] in the conditional mean equation indicates the asymmetry
in economic growth, that is, growth is fastest in the recovery phase of
a recession. The model also displays evidence of an asymmetric
volatility response to innovations in the growth rate. That is, periods
where the CDR term is nonzero lead to higher levels of output volatility
than periods where the CDR term is zero. This suggests that periods
where output has fallen below its historical maximum are inherently more
volatile than booms.
This asymmetry in volatility is clearly depicted in Figures 2 and
3. These figures show the news impact curves, depicting the relationship
between innovations to growth and the volatility of output, holding
information constant at time t - 1 and before. (6) The equation for the
GARCH(1, 1) news impact curve is [h.sub.t] = A + [beta][[member
of].sup.2.sub.t-1], where A = [omega] + [alpha][h.sub.t-1]. In our
model, the news impact curve during nonrecessionary periods, that is,
when [CDR.sub.t] = 0 is [h.sub.t] = A + [beta][[member
of].sup.2.sub.t-1]. In recessionary periods, that is, when [CDR.sub.t]
> 0, the news impact curve is [h.sub.t] = A + ([beta] +
[gamma])[[member of].sup.2.sub.t-1]. (7)
The simulated news impact curve in Figure 2 is consistent with the
absence of a relationship between news about growth and the volatility
of output during nonrecessionary periods. Conversely, in recessionary
periods, the significance of the [gamma] parameter results in large
innovations in growth being associated with large values of [h.sub.t].
The significant and negative coefficient on the GARCH in mean term
points toward a negative volatility feedback on growth. The news impact
curve confirms that this feedback will be strongest after a period of
recession. In effect, recessions result in increased output uncertainty,
which in turn serves to retard recovery following unfavorable news about
output.
All these conclusions are dependent on the model we have selected
being an adequate representation of the data-generating process. The
Ljung-Box and Pagan-Sabau tests reported previously suggest that our
model specification is appropriate. However, there is the potential for
bias due to asymmetric response to the sign or magnitude of the
innovation, [[member of].sub.t], or to bias associated with periods
where the CDR term is nonzero.
To identify potential misspecification of the conditional variance
due to asymmetric response to innovations in growth, [[member
of].sub.t], we calculated Engle and Ng's (1993) test for size and
sign bias in conditionally heteroskedastic models. Define
[S.sup.-.sub.t-1] as an indicator dummy that takes the value of 1 if
[[member of].sub.t-1] < 0 and the value zero otherwise. The test for
sign bias is based on the significance of [[phi].sub.1] in
[[member of].sup.2.sub.1] - [[phi].sub.0] +
[[phi].sub.1][S.sup.-.sub.t-1] + [v.sub.t], (5)
where [v.sub.t] is a white-noise error term. If positive and
negative innovations in [[member of].sub.t] impact on the conditional
variance of growth differently to the prediction of the model, then
[[phi].sub.1] will be statistically significant. It may also be the case
that the source of the bias is caused not only by the sign but also by
the magnitude of the shock. The negative size bias test is based on the
significance of the slope coefficient [[phi].sub.1] in
[[member of].sup.2.sub.t] = 0
[[phi].sub.1][S.sup.-.sub.t-1][[member of].sub.t-1] + [v.sub.t]. (6)
Likewise, defining [[S.sup.+.sub.t-1]] = 1 - [S.sup.-.sub.t-1],
then the Engle and Ng (1993) joint test for asymmetry in variance is
based on the regression
[[member of].sup.2.sub.t] = 0 + [[phi].sub.1][S.sup.-.sub.t-1] +
[[phi].sub.2] [S.sup.-.sub.t-1] [[member of].sub.t-1] +
[[phi].sub.3][S.sup.+.sub.t-1][[member of].sub.t-1] + [v.sub.t], (7)
where [v.sub.t] is a white-noise disturbance term. Significance of
the parameter [[phi].sub.1] indicates the presence of sign bias. That
is, positive and negative realizations of [[member of].sub.t] affect
future volatility differently to the prediction of the model. Similarly,
significance of [[phi].sub.2] or [[phi].sub.3] would suggest size bias,
where not only the sign but also the magnitude of innovation in growth
is important. A joint test for sign and size bias, based on the Lagrange
multiplier principle, may be performed as T.[R.sup.2] from the
estimation of Equation 7. The results in Table 2 suggest that the model
is free from size and sign bias.
Finally, we test for bias in the conditional variance arising from
the failure to adequately capture the effects of recessions. Again, this
test may be performed using a Lagrange multiplier approach based on the
auxiliary regression
[[member of].sup.2.sub.t] = [[phi].sub.0] +
[[phi].sub.1][I.sub.t-1] + [[phi].sub.2][CDR.sub.t-1] + [v.sub.1], (8)
where [I.sub.t] = 1 if {max[{[y.sub.t-s]}.sup.t.sub.s=0] -
[y.sub.t]} > 0 and is zero otherwise. In other words, [I.sub.t]
captures periods when the economy is "in recession." The CDR
term is used to capture biases due to the depth of the recession. The
test is based on the restrictions [[phi].sub.1] = 0, [[phi].sub.2] = 0,
and is distributed as a [chi square](2). The test statistic of 1.9836
indicates a marginal significance level of 0.3709. There is no evidence
of bias due to recessions in the model.
4. Conclusion
In common with the results of Beaudry and Koop (1993), Bradley and
Jansen (1997), and Jansen and Oh (1999), the evidence in this paper
suggests that U.S. economic growth differs according to whether the
economy's level of output has fallen relative to its historical
maximum. However, we demonstrate that the CDR-GARCH-M model provides a
superior conditional characterization for U.S. postwar GNP to the
standard CDR model. This indicates that the volatility of U.S. economic
growth is also affected by the level of output relative to the
historical maximum; contractionary periods tend to be more volatile than
expansions of similar magnitude. The CDR-GARCH-M model passes a battery
of standard specification tests as well as a series of LM tests designed
to detect bias due to size and sign of innovation and bias due to
recessions.
Our results provide further support for the view that there exists
a significant asymmetry in the U.S. growth rate, with growth
accelerating as the economy recovers from recessions. However, we also
document an increase in output volatility that accompanies recessions
and that acts to dampen subsequent growth. A theoretical explanation for
why an increase in output volatility might accompany a recession is a
topic worthy of future research.
(*.) Department of Economics, University of Melbourne, Victoria,
3010, Australia; E-mail oth@unimelb.edu.au.
(+.) Department of Economics, University of Melbourne, Victoria,
3010, Australia; E-mail nilss@unimelb.edu.au; corresponding author.
The authors thank Michelle Barnes, participants at the Fifth Annual
Australian Macroeconomics Workshop, and an anonymous referee for their
comments on earlier drafts on this paper. Any errors in the paper are
our responsibility.
Received June 2000; accepted November 2000.
(1.) This point is made by Durlauf and Quah (1999) in a recent
survey article.
(2.) For a discussion of this trend and a list of seminal papers,
see Ramey and Ramey (1995).
(3.) Beaudry and Koop (1993) fit their model to U.S. real GNP data
over the period 1947:1 to 1989:4 and find that it performs better than a
linear autoregressive model. Further, they construct impulse response functions and conclude that innovations to GNP are more persistent in
expansions than in recessions. Bradley and Jansen (1997) fit the CDR
model to the other G7 countries and find that the model is supported by
the data, and Jansen and Oh (1999) also find that the CDR model
outperforms a smooth transition regression model when fitted to a
measure of U.S. industrial production. Bodman and Crosby (1998) find no
evidence of CDR asymmetries for Australia.
(4.) The robustness of Caporale and McKiernan's (1996) results
has been questioned by Speight (1999).
(5.) We are not aware of any previous study that has documented the
effect of recessions on output volatility.
(6.) Because the GARCH(1, 1)I formulated in the squares [[member
of].sub.t] of positive and negative shocks are treated in the same way.
The relationship between [[member of].sup.2.sub.t] and [h.sub.t] is
known as the news impact curve.
(7.) Our use of the terms "recession" and
"nonrecession" differs from their normal usage. For
exposition, we will restrict the use of the term "recession"
to mean a period in which [CDR.sub.t] > 0.
References
Akaike, Hirotugu. 1974. A new look at statistical model
identification. IEEE Transactions and Automatic Control AC-19:716-23.
Beaudry, Paul, and Gary Koop. 1993. Do recessions permanently
change output? Journal of Monetary Economics 31:149-63.
Black, Fisher. 1987. Business cycles and equilibrium. New York:
Blackwell.
Bodman, Phillip M., and Mark Crosby. 1998. The Australian business
cycle: Joe Palooka or Dead Cat Bounce. University of Melbourne,
Department of Economics Working Paper No. 586.
Bollerslev, Tim. 1986. Generalised autoregressive
heteroscedasticity. Journal of Econometrics 31:307-27.
Bollerslev, Tim, and Jeffrey M. Wooldridge. 1992. Quasi-maximum
likelihood estimation and inference in models with time varying
covariances. Econometric Reviews 11:143-72.
Bradley, Michael D., and Dennis W. Jansen. 1997. Nonlinear business
cycle dynamics: Cross-country evidence on the persistence of aggregate
shocks. Economic Inquiry 35:495-509.
Campbell, John Y., and N. Gregory Mankiw. 1987. Are output
fluctuations transitory? Quarterly Journal of Economics 102:857-80.
Caporale, Tony, and Barbara McKiernan. 1996. The relationship
between output volatility and growth: Evidence from post war UK data.
Scottish Journal of Political Economy 43(2):229-36.
Caporale, Tony, and Barbara McKiernan. 1998. The Fisher Black
hypothesis: Some time series evidence. Southern Economic Journal
64:765-71.
Durlauf, Steven N., and Danny T. Quah. 1999. The new empiries of
economic growth. In Handbook of macroeconomics IA, edited by J. B.
Taylor and M. Woodford. Amsterdam: North-Holland, pp. 235-308.
Engle, Robert F. 1982. Autoregressive conditional
heteroscedasticity with estimates of the variance of United Kingdom
inflation. Econometrica 50:987-1007.
Engle, Robert F., David M. Lilien, and Russell P. Robins. 1987.
Estimating time varying risk premia in the term structure: The Areh-M
model. Econometrica 55(2):391-407.
Engle, R. F., and Victor Ng. 1993 Measuring and testing the impact
of news on volatility. Journal of Finance 48:1749-78.
Friedman, Milton. 1968. The role of monetary policy. American
Economic Review 58:1-17.
Glosten, Lawrence, Ravi Jagannathan, and David Runkle. 1993. On the
relation between the expected value and the volatility of the nominal
excess return on stocks. Journal of Finance 48:1779-1801.
Grier, Kevin, and Gordon Tullock. 1989. An empirical analysis of
cross-national economic growth, 1951-1980. Journal of Monetary Economics
24:259-76.
Jansen, Dennis W., and Wankeun Oh. 1999. Modelling nonlinearity of
business cycles: Choosing between the CDR and STAR models. Review of
Economics and Statistics 81(2):344-9.
Kormendi, Roger, and Philip Meguire. 1985. Macroeconomic determinants of growth: Cross-country evidence. Journal of Monetary
Economics 16:141-63.
Pagan, Adrian, and Hernan Sabau. 1992. Consistency tests for
heteroscedasticity and risk models. Estudios Economicos 7:3-30.
Ramey, Garey, and Valerie Ramey. 1995. Cross-country evidence an
the link between volatility and growth. American Economic Review 85(5):
1138-51.
Speight, Alan E. H. 1999. UK output variability and growth: Some
further evidence. Scottish Journal of Political Economy 46(2):175-84.
Schwarz, Gideon. 1978. Estimating the dimension of a model. Annals of Statistics 6:461-4.
Woodford, Michael 1990. Learning to believe in sunspots.
Econometrica 58:277-307.
[Figure 1 omitted]
[Figure 2 Omitted]
[Figure 3 omitted]
Table 1
Parameter Estimates--CDR Models
[THETA](L)[DELTA][y.sub.t] = [micro] + {[PSI](L) - 1} [CDR.sub.t] +
[lambda] [square root of ([h.sub.t])] + [PHI](L)[[member of].sub.t]
Model
(1, 0, 0) (0, 2, 0) (2, 0, 1) (2, 0, 2)
[micro] 0.0052 0.0081 0.0018 0.0021
(0.0007) (0.0010) (0.0007) (0.0007)
-[[THETA].sub.1] 0.3500 -- 0.4337 0.3486
(0.0527) -- (0.0526) (0.0529)
-[[THETA].sub.2] -- -- 0.1818 0.2207
-- -- (0.0532) (0.0530)
[[PHI].sub.1] -- 0.3045 -- --
-- (0.0518) -- --
[[PHI].sub.2] -- 0.1855 -- --
-- (0.0527) -- --
[[PHI].sub.3] -- -- -- --
-- -- -- --
[[PSI].sub.1] -- -- 0.3339 0.1452
-- -- (0.0694) (0.0685)
[[PSI].sub.2] -- -- -- 0.2111
-- -- -- (0.0788)
[[PSI].sub.3] -- -- -- --
-- -- -- --
Model
(2, 0, 3) (2, 3, 1)
[micro] 2.4940 (a) 0.0014
(6.7567) (b) (0.0027)
-[[THETA].sub.1] 0.3683 1.2536
(0.0529) (0.2927)
-[[THETA].sub.2] 0.1454 -0.4951
(0.0538) (0.3862)
[[PHI].sub.1] -- -0.9227
-- (0.3097)
[[PHI].sub.2] -- 0.3876
-- (0.3639)
[[PHI].sub.3] -- -0.0005
-- (0.1557)
[[PSI].sub.1] 0.2030 0.1548
(0.0660) (0.1281)
[[PSI].sub.2] -0.0384 --
(0.0742) --
[[PSI].sub.3] 0.2119 --
(0.0705) --
Standard errors are in parentheses.
(a)X 10[e.sup.-3].
(b)X 10[e.sup.-4].
Table 2
Estimates of the CDR-GARCH(1, 1)-M Model
[THETA](L)[DLETA][y.sub.t] = [micro] + {[PSI][L] - 1} [CDR.sub.t] +
[lambda] [square root of ([h.sub.t])] + [PHI](L)[[member of].sub.t]
[[member of].sub.t] ~ N(0, [h.sub.t]); [h.sub.t] = [omega] +
[alpha](L)[h.sub.t-1] + [beta](L) [[member of].sup.2.sub.t-1] +
[gamma](L)[I.sub.t-1] [[member of].sup.2.sub.t-1]
where
[I.sub.t] = {1 if {max[{[y.sub.t-s]}.sup.t.sub.s=0] - [y.sub.t]} > 0, {0
otherwise.
[micro] -[[THETA].sub.1] -[[THETA].sub.2] [[PSI].sb.1] [lambda]
0.0048 0.5898 -0.0243 0.2032 -0.2430
(0.0010) (0.0943) (0.0943) (0.0646) (0.1078)
[micro] [[PSI].sub.1] [[PSI].sub.2]
0.0048 -0.1094 0.1157
(0.0010) (0.1068) (0.0756)
[omega] [alpha] [beta] [gamma] L
0.00003 0.5030 0.0086 0.4958 853.0649
(0.00001) (0.1102) (0.0664) (0.1978)
Q(4) [Q.sup.2](4) P - S N-sign N-size Joint
0.7800 5.6853 2.6835 -0.3228 0.5906 0.8082
[0.9411] [0.2239] [0.2674] [0.7472] [0.5555] [0.8475]
Standard errors are in parentheses. Marginal significance levels are in
brackets.