Aviation policy: past and present. (Association Lecture).
Bailey, Elizabeth E.
1. Introduction
Airline deregulation has been a symbol of the trend toward less
expansive government over the past quarter century. The move from
economic regulation to deregulation has delivered on its efficiency
promises. Although there are only a handful of large carriers remaining
after the consolidations of the 1980s and 1990s, there have been
enormous benefits to consumers in terms of lower prices and more
convenient schedules. However, airline competition remains imperfect,
particularly at hub airports. The nature of these imperfections is
explained better by models of oligopolistic behavior than by the
contestability theory.
Paradoxically for this industry, 19 men and four airplanes brought
the drive to shrink government to an abrupt end on September 11, 2001.
The resulting tragedy has dramatized the public-good aspects of
protection from terrorist attack and the need for information sharing by
law enforcement authorities. Emergency legislation sought to provide
financial stabilization for the airline industry in the short run.
Subsequent legislation addresses the need for stronger aviation security
in the long run.
This paper begins with a look at past policy. It describes the
nature of aviation regulation and the causes and beneficial consequences
of economic deregulation. It then evaluates the nature and extent of
competition in the deregulated marketplace. Finally, it examines
continued areas of governmental intervention in aviation, including new
security and bailout policies.
2. The Regulatory Era: 1938-1978
The Civil Aeronautics Board (CAB) was formed in 1938. Most
infrastructure industries (transportation, communications, energy,
financial services) had major regulatory initiatives during this period.
There was a downturn of faith in a laissez-faire economy emanating from
the Great Depression (Vietor 1990).
The Civil Aeronautics Act of 1938 created a five-member independent
regulatory agency and gave it authority to (i) control entry into the
industry (both interstate and foreign commerce) and control entry of
existing carriers into new or existing routes; (ii) control exit by
requiring approval before cessation of service to a point or on a route;
(iii) regulate fares on the basis of rate-making provisions adopted from
the Interstate Commerce Act (which regulated railroads); and (iv)
approve mergers, grant antitrust immunity to international rate-making
agreements, and engage in other antitrust functions. The original act
gave the CAB authority over safety issues as well. Congress separated
safety regulation from economic regulation in the Federal Aviation Act
of 1958 (Bailey, Graham, and Kaplan 1985).
The CAB designed route authority to ensure that an integrated
service network would develop. Route rights were granted to trunk
carriers on long-haul parallel routes and to local service carriers
within geographic regions. For example, United Airlines was granted the
east-west route through Chicago, and TWA was granted the east-west route
through St. Louis. Originally, planes flying coast-to-coast had to stop
at these interior cities because of the limitations of airplane
technology. Competition was not direct, but instead occurred over
parallel routes (New York to San Francisco via Chicago or St. Louis). In
this way, air travel was similar to rail transport. However, the
introduction of jet aircraft in the late 1950s and early 1960s enabled
overflights of cities (nonstop service). Competition then became direct.
The local service carriers were granted service in largely
nonoverlapping regions, for example, North Central around Minneapolis,
Allegheny around Pittsburgh, and Ozark around St. Louis. Because these
carriers were intended to serve as gatherers of traffic from small
communities, the CAB severely restricted their ability to compete
against the long-haul trunk carriers. Throughout the regulatory period,
the focus of the CAB was on strengthening existing carriers, not
authorizing new carriers. If a carrier was nearing bankruptcy, it would
be merged into a financially healthy carrier (Transportation Research
Board 1991).
Because of the monopoly, or near monopoly, conferred by CAB route
authority, it was necessary to regulate rates so that consumers were
protected from prices that were too high. Prior to World War II,
airfares were conventionally set at the prevailing first-class rail
fare. Gradually, a more formal review process set fares on an
industry-wide basis. Fare competition was not precluded by statute, but
the CAB's procedures and policies strongly discouraged it. Discount
fares were permitted for charter carriers, which were also called
"irregular," or unscheduled, carriers. There were no low-fare
scheduled carriers. Proposals to change fares substantially were the
subject of hearings. Thus, fares could not be changed quickly. There
were also provisions to subsidize jet service to small communities
(Meyer and Oster 1982).
This type of price and entry regulation contrasts sharply with
market competition, in which the status quo is regularly overthrown and
in which there is no legal recourse to entry and price changes as long
as no antitrust laws are violated. Regulation entailed delays of two to
four years for most route entry and industry-wide fare cases.
3. The Deregulatory Era: 1978-Present
By the early 1970s, evidence had begun to accumulate from a number
of infrastructure industries that regulation was having unintended
consequences, such as harm to efficiency and innovation. Government was
viewed as being captured by the industries they were supposed to control
and was believed to have become heavy-handed, doing more harm than good.
In aviation, three carriers (Eastern, TWA, and Pan American) were near
bankruptcy in the early 1970s. Political forces began to marshal, and
these forces reached full flower in the aviation hearings held by
Senator Edward Kennedy in 1975. Steven Breyer, now a Supreme Court
Justice, provided Kennedy staff support for these hearings (Breyer
1982).
There was a lot of drama generated by the way the hearings were
staged: Each day produced a dramatic point; for example, on one day,
East Coast Boston fares were shown to be twice as high as West Coast San
Francisco fares for routes of similar distances and densities. On
another day, it was made clear that no new carrier entry had been
permitted into the industry in 40 years. The hearings were fact-based.
Evidence was brought to bear to address the fears aroused by reform and
to convince others of the benefits of reform. One fear was that lower
fares would lead to carrier bankruptcy. California and Texas provided
the basis for a natural experiment, since their state regulators chose
to deregulate fares for flights within their states. Southwest Airlines in Texas and Pacific Southwest Airlines in California offered much lower
fares than CAB-regulated airlines and prospered financially (Levine
1965). Their fares were half as high as the CAB fares, due mostly to
higher load factors and planes configured with mor e seats. Importantly,
trunk carriers were not crippled financially by the coexistence of the
low-fare scheduled carriers.
Another influential leading activity concerned Federal Express,
which had requested deregulation of airfreight so that it could
introduce an innovative new service in the mail area. Overnight package
delivery would be offered at prices significantly higher than those for
slower postal service delivery. Since no one opposed the idea, cargo
deregulation was granted, and the new business proved to be a huge
success.
With these early successes and the momentum of the Kennedy
hearings, the stage was set for airline passenger deregulation.
President Jimmy Carter was behind the reform movement and appointed two
deregulators--Alfred Kahn and Elizabeth Bailey--to the Civil Aeronautics
Board. A new economic theory called the contestability theory helped to
provide a practical template for reform (Baumol, Panzar, and Willig
1982). The idea was to segment an industry into markets and to evaluate
the extent of contests for the market that could take place under
conditions of free entry and exit. Airlines were viewed as a potentially
contestable industry. While most markets were limited by demand to only
one or two carriers (an average of 1.5 in 1978), airplanes were viewed
as "marginal costs with wings" that could readily be moved
from one market to another if pricing became too high (Bailey and Baumol
1984; Kahn 1990). Indeed, deregulation improved route pair competition
somewhat, to around 1.9 to 2.0 per route in recent years.
Deregulators at the CAB provided immediate opportunities for
downward pricing flexibility by asking carriers to "show
cause" why up to 35% of all fares should not be discount fares (to
fill empty seats during off-peak periods). If an airport was underserved
(e.g., San Jose or Newark at the time), carriers should "show
cause" why the CAB should not permit any carrier to enter any route
at that airport. In another initiative, it was announced that diversion
was no longer to be considered a material fact when considering route
entry. By such stratagems, entry was opened into airports, routes, and
the industry within a year after passage of the Airline Deregulation Act of 1978. In contrast, upward pricing flexibility was delayed until 1980,
after entry had been fully opened (Bailey 1981).
In terms of the entry of low-fare scheduled carriers, Southwest is
the archetypal carrier. An important source of the airline's cost
savings and efficiency is its avoidance of congested primary airports in
large cities. With its low-fare, point-to-point strategy, Southwest has
successfully generated high traffic volumes in many secondary
airport-pair markets (e.g., Ontario, California, to Oakland, California)
and has pressured other airlines to lower their fares not only in the
same markets, but also in related airport-pair markets (e.g., Los
Angeles to San Francisco). In 160 short-haul (<750 miles) airport
pairs that Southwest entered between 1990 and 1998, air passenger
traffic increased by more than 174%, and average yields adjusted for
inflation fell by 54%. Southwest alone accounts for about 75% of
passenger traffic on low-fare airlines (Transportation Research Board
1999). Thus, the existence of this single carrier has had an enormous
influence on the price benefits to consumers from airline deregulatio n.
Economists have been surprised by how much of the gains from
deregulation have been in the service dimension rather than in the price
dimension (Bailey and Liu 1995). Most cities now offer convenient
business travel whereby people can travel to their destination in the
morning and return that evening. Of the $8.5 billion gain from such
improved scheduling, $1.0 billion needs to be netted out to reflect the
negative of the extra stop at a hub airport (Morrison and Winston 1986;
Winston 1993). In terms of price performance, about half of the $6.5
billion gains are negated by booking restrictions, particularly in terms
of mandatory Saturday night stays and advance-purchase requirements.
Leisure travelers' benefits from deregulation have been mainly in
lower fares, while business benefits have been mainly in frequency
improvement. Basically, carriers set frequencies for business needs and
then try to induce leisure travelers to fill empty seats.
Innovations following deregulation include the development of
complex yield management systems that have evolved to price discriminate
among travelers, for example, offering cheap tickets to early bookers
and requiring last-minute travelers to pay a lot more. Large airlines,
such as American and United, also innovated by developing computer
reservation systems for travel agents. The host airlines' flights
appear on early screens and give these large carriers a benefit for the
high investments they made in these systems. Government eventually
weighed in to remove some of the bias toward the monopolistic host
airlines (Levine 1987). At the present time, use of the Internet for
sales is beginning to bloom. The Web offers airlines significant savings
on their marketing and distribution costs.
Overall, airlines have been reasonably profitable over time, but
profits are still vulnerable to the business cycle. The industry loses
money during recessionary periods, such as the early 1990s, and recoups
these losses when the economy improves, as in the late 1990s. The
average consumer is paying 27% less than what the regulated prices would
have been, and 80% of passengers are paying less than they would have
under government-set prices (Morrison and Winston 1989; Winston 1998).
Demand for air services has more than doubled from 254 million domestic
passengers in 1978 to 582 million in 1999.
In an analysis of the nature of competition following deregulation,
the extent of contest-ability has been questioned. There was a natural
pricing experiment in the late 1970s, during which local service
carriers were permitted to charge higher prices than trunk carriers.
During the period of the experiment, prices set by local service
carriers were below those allowed in long-haul markets, in which
carriers faced actual or potential trunk competition. These long-haul
markets looked contestable. However, local service carrier prices were
near allowed levels in short-haul markets, in which there was less fear
of trunk competition because of trunk fleet composition. Thus, the
short-haul markets did not appear to be contestable (Bailey and Panzar
1981).
Other evidence supports an oligopolistic interpretation of
postderegulation pricing conduct at hub airports. Concentrated hubs are
defined as airports where one carrier accounts for more than 50% of all
local traffic or where the sum of two hubbing carriers accounts for more
than 75%. Comparisons of average fares in city-pair markets involving 10
concentrated and 5 unconcentrated hubs consistently found higher fares
in the concentrated hubs (by about 14-18%), especially in short-haul
markets. At such airports, high fares do not seem to induce entry.
Instead, the hub networks can be viewed as bringing about oligopolistic
rather than contestable behavior (Morrison and Winston 1987; Borenstein
1991; Borenstein and Rose 1994; Hendricks, Piccione, and Tan 1997).
Further evidence comes from industry attempts to gain systemwide
price increases. In March 2000, Continental proposed $20 and $40 price
increases based on distance. Most carriers engaged in parallel pricing
and immediately matched. The fare hike was rescinded when Northwest
failed to match. Some time later, Northwest proposed a similar level of
systemwide fare hikes, but based on a leisure-versus-business
distinction; the action was immediately matched by all of the trunk
carriers (Baker 2001).
4. Antitrust Oversight following Deregulation
When there is a reduction in economic regulation, it is important
that there be a continuation of antitrust oversight. The Department of
Justice (DOJ) has been vigilant in the conduct area. Robert Crandall,
CEO of American Airlines, was caught on tape trying to price fix with
Howard Putnam, then CEO of Braniff, shortly after deregulation. More
recently, the DOJ brought charges of predatory pricing against American
Airlines. The government accused American of incurring large short-term
losses in the late 1990s to drive three low-cost competitors (Vanguard
Airlines, Sun Jet International, and Western Pacific) from the
Dallas-Fort Worth Airport, where American is the dominant carrier. All
of these competitors except Vanguard have gone out of business. The
issue was whether American was simply responding to market forces by
lowering prices and increasing flights or whether flooding a market with
capacity while matching price constitutes predation (Baker 2001). In
April 2001, the court made it even harder to prove monopolization through predatory scheduling by finding against the DOJ. Further, U.S.
antitrust law is not designed to prevent bankruptcy or purchase, and
thereafter disappearance, of small low-fare carriers.
Deregulation caused a major change in carrier strategy toward route
networks. Local service airlines immediately entered longer-haul and
denser markets. Their feed into these markets gave them a stable pattern
and level of earnings (Bailey and Williams 1988). Trunk carriers moved
from the linear system of routes designed by regulators to hub-and-spoke
systems under which traffic flowed more efficiently. Since consumers
dislike changing carriers, all airlines attempted to provide one-carrier
service (Levine 1987). Within a decade following deregulation, trunk
carriers strengthened themselves by merging. Some mergers were with
local service carriers at their hubs (TWA and Ozark, Northwest and
Republic). Other trunk or local carriers merged with each other to
achieve their national service goals (Delta and Western, US Airways and
Piedmont). Antitrust authorities by and large accepted most of these
mergers. Unfortunately, studies of these mergers found that fares paid
by hub-originating and hub-terminating passen gers became higher and
were only partially offset by the efficiency gains arising from the
creation of a larger network (Borenstein 1990; Brueckner, Dyer, and
Spiller 1992; Kim and Singal 1993).
For this reason, the DOJ opposed the $4.3 billion bid made by
United Airlines in May 2000 to buy US Airways. There was concern that
the same carrier would control too many contiguous hub airports in the
east, furthering the negative competitive consequences that had been
found to arise from hub dominance. The DOJ did, however, approve the
takeover of the failing TWA by American in 2001.
In terms of international aviation policy, there has been massive
privatization of government-owned airlines abroad, which was driven by
the need to match the efficiency of U.S. carriers. There has also been a
growing desire to form alliances among international carriers. Antitrust
immunity is needed for such alliances. At the most basic level, an
airline alliance may be simply a joint marketing deal known as code
sharing, in which both airlines put their identification codes on a
flight and they both sell it, even though only one operates it. The next
step from simple code sharing is block booking on each other's
flights, then joint marketing of the two airlines' network routes
and sharing of frequent-flyer codes. In the closest alliance, that of
KLM and Northwest, the carriers have completely integrated their
business.
Some alliances have not received the approval they wished for.
Twice, American Airlines and British Airways have sought approval for an
alliance. Governmental authorities want British Airways to cede Heathrow
airport slots as a condition of approval. The governmental view is that
entry needs to be open at Heathrow (open skies) before this alliance is
permitted to go forward. The carriers have not been willing to cede
sufficient slots at Heathrow to enable the alliance to be approved.
5. Government Ownership of Aviation Facilities
Two types of aviation facilities continue to be owned and operated
by the government: airports and air-traffic control facilities. When it
became necessary to modernize and expand gates and other passenger
facilities over the past two decades, many large airport authorities
turned to their major airline tenants for financing help. In return,
airports offered long-term leases that often gave air carriers control
over a large share of gates and the authority to approve future
expansions. Thus, instead of using regulation to open competition,
airport policy has locked in monopoly elements.
There has also been a lack of efficient pricing policies at
airports. Airport landing fees rarely do more than cover the wear and
tear on runways. Fees are not equated with the costs imposed by users
(on others) taking up valuable runway space during peak periods. Both
airport and airway capacity are allocated to users on a first come,
first served basis, a simple queuing approach that provides little
incentive for low-value users, such as small private aircraft, to shift
some of their activity to less congested airports and off-peak travel
times. Not only has this approach been accompanied by air traffic
congestion and delays, but it has also prompted a series of often
arbitrary administrative and physical controls on airline and airport
operations that have had anticompetitive side effects such as perimeter
rules and slot control (Transportation Research Board 1999). Finally,
there is provocative research suggesting that carriers also have
incentives to overschedule planes at hub airports, leading to furthe r
delays (Mayer and Sinai 2002).
The U.S. government runs air traffic control. There have been a
number of criticisms of current aviation policy in this area. In the
1980s, air traffic controllers went on strike. The system responded by
temporarily limiting airway capacity, basically by stretching out the
periods between takeoffs and landings, creating delays. Such delays have
continued. In 2000, U.S. air traffic delays were occurring for about one
flight in four during peak summer season. Flights are controlled by a
ground-based system that obliges pilots to stick rigidly to prescribed
routes--often not the shortest ones--dictated by the need to stay close
to radio beacons or radar stations. Conventional air traffic control,
which relies on radar and wireless communications, has severe limits in
today's crowded skies. Radar is accurate to only a few miles and
involves exchanging much routine information between the pilot and the
controller over the airwaves. There are plans to replace today's
radar-based system with one built around satelli tes. Such a system
could rely largely on Global Positioning System data, rather than radar,
for navigation. If the new technology passes testing over the next
several years, it would enable flight plans to follow a variety of more
efficient and economical flight paths. However, having the new
technology work for large, busy airports and for zero-visibility
landings could take another decade or more.
6. Security Interventions
The issues discussed above were the major aviation policy issues
facing the industry prior to the tragic event of September 11, 2001. The
simultaneous hijacking of four planes and the use of airliners to
destroy the Twin Towers of the World Trade Center and to attack the
Pentagon has emphasized how vulnerable the industry is to terrorism. The
government has been turned to for both immediate financial help and
long-term structural change in aviation security.
On September 11, as the terrorists crashed planes into the Twin
Towers and the Pentagon, United and American began to ground their
airplanes. Within a short time, the Federal Aviation Administration ordered a nationwide shutdown. For three days, the entire U.S. aviation
system was shut down for the first time in history. For four days, no
international flights were permitted into the United States. Even after
flights began again, the negative externalities persisted. Traffic was
down 35-40% for the month of September (vs. the previous year) and was
still down 20-25% for the month of October. This drop in traffic is much
steeper than any that had occurred before. For example, the drop in air
traffic during the Gulf War in spring 1991 was 10-11%.
Within weeks after September 11, an airline financial stabilization
package was rushed through Congress. There was concern that the
unprecedented drop in airline revenues, along with high potential
liability, would preclude the industry from obtaining private financing.
Emergency airline bailout legislation provided the industry with an
immediate $5 billion cash infusion, most of which was used up in the
fall of 2001. The legislation also created an Air Transportation
Stabilization Board empowered to grant up to $10 billion in loan
guarantees for up to nine months (applications through June 2002). Two
of the three members of this board are strong market advocates, namely,
Alan Greenspan (Chairman of the Federal Reserve) and Paul O'Neill
(Secretary of the Treasury). The government also took on an insurance
role, setting up a special master at the DOJ to pay the extraordinary
costs of liability after insurance coverage. Thus, a strong degree of
financial security was offered to keep the industry solvent and abl e to
borrow.
Clearly, the traveling public views protection from terrorism as a
public good. There is a growing view that federal control of security
can help internalize the externality. The European system of government
supervision of screeners, as well as the extent of professionalism of
the European workforce, is viewed as superior to the U.S. system. In the
past, the screeners of baggage and passengers have been paid by airlines
and local airports in the United States. There has not been information
sharing among various law enforcement officers or between law
enforcement officers and screeners. The Anti-Terrorism Bill of October
26, 2001, addresses this need for information sharing among the
Immigration and Naturalization Service, the Federal Bureau of
Investigation, and those handling airport security.
The Aviation Security Bill of November 19, 2001, federalizes
screeners of passengers and baggage, imposes a surcharge on airline
tickets, and tightens law enforcement aspects of security. Some
flexibility for local airport authority experimentation will be
permitted. Efforts to minimize the transaction costs associated with
improved security were not addressed.
7. Conclusions
It is ironic that at the beginning of the twenty-first century,
there is a new regulatory wave in aviation policy. The role of
government is being increased, much as it was in the early decades of
the twentieth century. However, there has not been a return to detailed
intervention in airline economic decisions. Rather, the new wave
reflects a new focus of American society on financial stabilization and
on improving its ability to provide security.
References
Bailey, Elizabeth E. 1981. Contestability and the design of
regulatory and antitrust policy. American Economic Review Papers and
Proceedings 71:178-83.
Bailey, Elizabeth E., and William J. Baumol. 1984. Deregulation and
the theory of contestable markets. Yale Journal on Regulation 1:111-37.
Bailey, Elizabeth E., David R. Graham, and Daniel P. Kaplan. 1985.
Deregulating the airlines. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Bailey, Elizabeth E., and Dong Liu. 1995. Airline consolidation and
consumer welfare. Eastern Economic Journal 21: 463-76.
Bailey, Elizabeth E., and John C. Panzar. 1981. The Contestability
of airline markets during the transition to deregulation. Law and
Contemporary Problems 44:125-45.
Bailey, Elizabeth E., and Jeffrey R. Williams. 1988. Sources of
economic rent in the deregulated airline industry. Journal of Law and
Economics 31:173-202.
Baker, Jonathan B. 2001. Mavericks, mergers and exclusion: Proving
coordinated competitive effects under the antitrust laws. Unpublished
paper, Washington College of Law, American University.
Baumol, William J., John C. Panzar, and Robert D. Willig. 1982.
Contestable markets and the theory of industry structure. New York:
Harcourt, Brace, Jovanovich.
Borenstein, Severin. 1990. Airline mergers, airport dominance and
market power. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 80:400-4.
Borenstein, Severin. 1991. The dominant-firm advantage in
multi-product industries: Evidence from the U.S. airlines. Quarterly
Journal of Economics 106:1237-66.
Borenstein, Severin, and Nancy Rose. 1994. Competition and price
dispersion in the U.S. airline industry. Journal of Political Economy
103:653-83.
Breyer, Steven. 1982. Regulation and its reform. Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press.
Brueckner, Jan K., Nicola J. Dyer, and Pablo T. Spiller. 1992. Fare
determination in airline hub-and-spoke networks. RAND Journal of
Economics 23:309-33.
Hendricks, Ken, Michelle Piccione, and Guofu Tan. 1997. Entry and
exit into hub-spoke networks. RAND Journal of Economics 28:291-303.
Kahn, Alfred E. 1990 Deregulation: Looking backward and looking
forward. Yale Journal on Regulation 7:325-54.
Kim, E. Han, and Vijay Singal. 1993. Mergers and market power:
Evidence from the airline industry. American Economic Review 83:549-69.
Levine, Michael E. 1965. Is regulation necessary? California air
transportation and national regulatory policy. Yale Law Journal
74:1416-47.
Levine, Michael E. 1987. Airline competition in deregulated
markets: Theory, firm strategy, and public policy. Yale Journal on
Regulation 4:393-494.
Mayer, Christopher, and Todd Sinai. 2002. Network effects,
congestion externalities, and air traffic delays, or why all delays are
not evil. NEER Working Paper No. 8701.
Meyer, John R., and Clinton V. Oster, Jr. 1982. Deregulation and
the future of intercity passenger travel. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Morrison, Steven A., and Clifford Winston. 1986. The economic
effects of airline deregulation. Washington, DC: The Brookings
Institution.
Morrison, Steven A., and Clifford Winston. 1987. Empirical
implications and tests of the contestability hypothesis. Journal of Law
and Economics 30:53-66.
Morrison, Steven A., and Clifford Winston. 1989. Enhancing the
performance of the deregulated air transportation system. In Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics, pp. 61-123.
Transportation Research Board. 1991. Winds of change: Air transport
since deregulation. Washington, DC: National Academy Press.
Transportation Research Board. 1999. Competition in the U.S.
airline industry. Washington, DC: National Academy Press.
Victor, Richard H. K. 1990. Contrived competition: Airline
regulation and deregulation, 1925-1988. Business History Review
64:61-108.
Winston, Clifford. 1993. Economic deregulation: Days of reckoning
for microeconomists. Journal of Economic Literature 31:1263-89.
Winston, Clifford. 1998. U.S. industry adjustment to economic
deregulation. Journal of Economic Perspectives 12:89-110.
Elizabeth E. Bailey *
* John C. Hower Professor of Business and Public Policy, Wharton
School, University of Pennsylvania, 3100 Steinberg Hall-Dietrich Hall,
Philadelphia, PA 19104-6372, USA; E-mail baileye@wharton.upenn.edu.
This paper was presented as an invited lecture on "Airline
Deregulation: Past and Present" at the Southern Economic
Association meetings on November 18, 2001, in Tampa, Florida.