Detrending and the money-output link: international evidence.
Kutan, Ali M.
1. Introduction and Background
The question of whether there exists an empirical link between
nominal money and real output has been subjected to a variety of modern
econometric techniques, producing conflicting results. For example,
Stock and Watson (1989) use a vector autoregressive (VAR) model that
accounts for several important economic variables and find that money
exerts a statistically significant effect on real economic activity.
Friedman and Kuttner (1992, 1993), on the other hand, show that using
the same specification as Stock and Watson but extending their sample
through the 1980s obviates the money-income link. Friedman and
Kuttner's results indicate that interest rates are relatively more
useful in explaining movements in output. (1) Thoma (1994) also reports
that changes in money do not have a statistically significant impact on
output in the United States.
More recent studies, both theoretical and empirical, also have
shown money to have little or no direct effect on economic cycles.
Rudebusch and Svensson (1999, 2002), for example, conclude that the
behavior of money (real or nominal) has no marginally significant impact
on deviations of real output from potential (the output gap) once past
movements in the gap and real rates of interest are accounted for. Such
findings, on the basis of what Meyer (2001) refers to as the
"consensus macro model," have achieved an influential position
among macroeconomists and policymakers. (2)
Other studies challenge the argument that money does not affect
real output. An early study by Christiano and Ljungqvist (1988) using a
bivariate VAR model reports the existence of a statistically significant
money-to-output relation in U.S. data. Davis and Tanner (1997), using
monthly U.S. data extending back to the mid-1800s, find that even after
interest rate effects are allowed for, money remains statistically
significant in explaining short-run movements in real output. Using a
rolling regression approach, Swanson (1998) reports a statistically
significant relation between money--measured as simple sum aggregates
and as Divisia measures--and output, even after an interest rate spread
variable is added to the model. Hafer and Kutan (1997) considered
whether different stationarity properties of the data have influenced
reported outcomes. Since most prior studies assume difference
stationarity, Hafer and Kutan demonstrate that estimating VAR models
that include money and interest rate variables under the ex istence of
trend stationarity can dramatically affect the conclusion. Indeed, they
find that using a trend-stationarity assumption yields the finding that
money significantly affects real output movements in the United States.
A common characteristic of this literature is its focus on the
United States. There are a few exceptions. For example, Krol and Ohanian
(1990) apply the Stock-Watson specification to data for Canada, Germany,
Japan, and the UK. Although money (actual and detrended) significantly
affects output in the UK, Krol and Ohanian find no such affect in Japan,
Canada, and Germany. They conclude that although detrending the growth
rate of U.S. money affects conclusions about the role of money, little
is gained from this approach when applied to the other countries.
Another exception to the U.S. focus is a recent study by Hayo (1999).
Using data from 14 European Union (EU) countries plus Canada, Japan, and
the United States, Hayo shows that money-output test results are not
sensitive to the use of data in levels versus data in differences.
An obvious question to ask, then, is whether nominal money is
relatively more useful than interest rates in explaining movements in
real output across a wider variety of countries that includes industrial
and developing economies. Although the studies of Krol and Ohanian and
Hayo represent a broader analysis, they too focus on the money-output
relation in relatively industrialized, financially developed countries.
To address this question, we estimate an unconstrained, four-variable
(output, money, prices, and interest rates) VAR model for a sample of 20
industrialized and developing countries. (3) In addition to analyzing a
broader set of countries, we also determine whether the statistical
importance (or lack thereof) of money is a function of the definition of
money used. Thus our investigation compares the usefulness of both a
narrow (M1) and broad (M2) measure of money in addition to a short-term interest rate. (4) As in Hafer and Kutan (1997), we explore the
sensitivity of our results to the use of diff erent stationarity
assumptions. Unlike previous work in this area, we evaluate the
empirical results by considering the financial development of the
countries used. To this end the recent data set constructed by Beck,
Demirguc-Kunt, and Levine (1999) is used to explore a potential link
between financial development and our empirical results.
The format of the paper is to briefly discuss the econometric
issues involved with the use of trend and difference stationary data in
section 2. In section 3 the data are described along with the
specification of the estimated VARs. This section also presents the
estimation results. Measures of financial market development and
structure are then examined in section 4 to see if there is a
discernible pattern between the importance of money in explaining real
output and a country's financial development. Conclusions and
policy implications close the paper in section 5.
2. Econometric Issues
This study uses both stationary (with and without trend) and
difference stationary (DS) specifications of a VAR model given evidence
indicating that unit root tests may falsely indicate difference
stationarity. Several studies have questioned the use of difference
stationarity because of the low power of unit root tests. For example,
Dejong et al. (1992) show that the power of augmented Dickey-Fuller and
Phillips-Perron tests against the alternative null hypothesis of trend
stationarity is quite low. Dejong and Whiteman (1991) use Bayesian
analysis to test for the presence of a unity root in the data and report
mixed results: When a zero-trend prior is assigned to trend-stationary
alternatives, the data do not reject the presence of a unit root in the
data. Relaxing this prior, however, often leads to rejection of the
unit-root hypothesis. Rudebusch (1993) also reports that unit-root tests
cannot distinguish between data simulated by a trend-stationary model or
a difference-stationary model. In a more recent paper, Canova (1998)
studies the business cycle properties of a small set of real
macroeconomic time series for the period 1955-1986. He finds that using
different detrending techniques, including a linear time trend and
first-order differences, produces different--both quantitatively and
qualitatively--"stylized facts" of U.S. business cycles.
Concern about the stationarity properties of the data is important
because of the economic implications. If money and real output are
characterized by a difference-stationary model, then effects of monetary
shocks on real output diminish very slowly. In other words, a monetary
shock has a permanent impact on the level of output because the shock
affects the stochastic component of real output. If the money and output
series are represented by a stationary model, however, then money shocks
have only a transitory impact on output since they are mean reverting.
Our own work (1997) suggests that testing the money-output link for the
United States is sensitive to which model is used.
3. Data and Estimation Results
Data
The data used are quarterly observations of money, measured as a
narrow (M1) and a broad (M2) aggregate; real output, measured as real
GDP ($1990); the price level, measured as the consumer price index (CPI)
(1990 = 100); and a short-term interest rate. Complete descriptions of
the data and sample periods used are provided in the data Appendix. We
use the CPI to increase the sample of countries: Using the GDP deflator results in a reduction in country coverage. All data are taken from the
IMF's International Financial Statistics CD-ROM release as of
December 1998. Country-specific sample periods are dictated by the
availability of data. In determining the country sample, we used the ad
hoc rule that countries with fewer than ten years of data are omitted.
This criterion and data availability results in a sample of 20
countries, a sample that extends the usual range of economic settings in
which the relative impacts of money and interest rates on real output is
tested.
To provide some background information on the diversity of the
sample, Table 1 reports summary statistics on real output growth,
inflation, and money growth for the countries included. As one can
quickly see, the sample covers a broad set of economic experiences. For
example, real output growth ranges from an average of 1.7% in
Switzerland to an average of 6.8% in Singapore. This range is dwarfed by
that for inflation. In our sample, average inflation runs from less than
2% to more than 50%. Interestingly, money growth, measured as M1 or M2,
exhibits a range similar to that of inflation. Indeed, if one believes
that long-run money growth and inflation move one-for-one, then such an
outcome is expected. Finding such a close relation between money growth
and inflation across countries over time would suggest that there is
little relation between money growth and the growth of real output in
the long run. And that is what the data in Table 1 suggest. (5) Even
though the data do not suggest a reliable long-run re lation between
average money growth and real output growth, that does not preclude the
existence of a short-run relation. To a large extent that is the
question addressed in the remainder of this paper.
Estimation Results
Three VAR models are estimated for each country. One is a levels
specification without a deterministic trend. Another VAR specification
includes a linear, deterministic time trend. This model is referred to
as the TS specification. This version assumes that the data are
stationary around a deterministic trend term. Both specifications use
the log level of the data (except for the interest rate) and allow us to
test whether the impact of money on output, if there is any, is
transitory. Furthermore, the TS version allows us to interpret the
results in terms of "detrended" variables (Krol and Ohanian
1990). The third specification uses log first-differences of the data,
except the interest rate, which is measured as a simple first
difference. In this DS model any impact of money on output is viewed as
long lasting, since the series are assumed to have stochastic trends
with fluctuations that are not mean reverting over time. VARs include a
constant term and quarterly seasonal dummies. (6)
Before turning to the results, a brief discussion of lag length
selection is in order. Swanson (1998) notes that many studies select the
structure of the VAR by simply assigning ad hoc lag lengths. It is well
known that inferences drawn from VARs are sensitive to the lag length
used. (7) In this paper the lag structure for each VAR is chosen using
the Akaike AIC and the Schwarz SC criterion. To keep the analysis
manageable, three alternative lag lengths are tested (eight, six, and
four) for each monetary aggregate and for each stationarity assumption.
In all but two cases, both lag-length selection criteria select four
lags. The exceptions are the TS model using M1 for Portugal, where eight
lags are chosen, and the TS and DS models with Turkish M2, where six
lags are selected. (8)
Variance decompositions derived from the VARs provide information
on the quantitative importance of money and interest rates in explaining
output. (9) We focus on the relative proportion of the total variation
in output explained by money and interest rates. Consequently, the full
set of variance decompositions (VDC) results are not reported. (10) Six
sets of variance decompositions are presented for each country. These
combinations reflect (i) the three VAR specifications and (ii) the fact
that two alternative orderings of the variables are used for each VAR.
One version, referred to as "Order 1" in subsequent
discussion, uses the ordering interest rate, money, prices, and real
output. As suggested by Sims (1980) and discussed in Todd (1990), an
ordering that places the short-term interest rate first assumes little
contemporaneous feedback from output to money. Because there are
different priors about the presence of contemporaneous feedback from
output to money or interest rates, an alternative ordering of output,
prices, interest rate, and money is estimated as a robustness test. This
is referred to as "Order 2." All reported variance
decompositions assume a 4-year horizon. (11)
The variance decompositions using M1 are found in Table 2. (12)
There are two aspects to interpreting the array of results in Table 2.
First, beneath each column heading is listed a ratio, the numerator of
which is the VDC for M1, the denominator being the VDC for the interest
rate. Second, this ratio is reported for the two orderings discussed
above. Last, because of the large number of combinations estimated, it
is useful to establish some criterion for evaluating the results. The
following setup is used: When the VDC of money exceeds 10% and exceeds
the VDC for the interest rate by 5% (not percentage points), the result
appears in bold. Although one may quibble over our benchmark, we believe
that this approach is reasonable and one that sets an acceptable minimum
for money to be thought of as providing useful information about the
behavior of real output.
The results in Table 2 provide an interesting comparison to
previous work which focused on the United States. First, the results
indicate that when the stationary specification without trend is used,
M1's VDC exceeds that of the interest rate for Germany, the
Netherlands, New Zealand, Portugal, Singapore, and Switzerland, although
this finding is sensitive to the ordering in New Zealand and Singapore.
This suggests that M1 plays only a minor role relative to interest rates
in explaining output in most other countries in our sample.
Turning to the results from the TS and DS specifications, the
evidence for the United States corroborates our earlier finding that the
VDC of M1 increases in absolute size and is larger than the interest
rate when the TS specification is used relative to the DS model. As seen
in Table 1, the TS specification delivers a VDC for M1 indicating that
about 25% of the variance in real output is explained by money, compared
with around 13-17% for the interest rate. When the DS specification is
used, however, the results are dramatically altered. Now the interest
rate dominates M1, the latter accounting for less than 3% of the
variance in output. (13) Finding that money's importance is
affected by the specification occurs not only for the United States, but
also for Australia, Israel, Portugal, Spain, and Sweden. In other words,
in these six countries one would have rejected the usefulness of money
on the basis of the TS or DS specification alone when this conclusion is
reversed using the alternative model. (14) Thus country-specific
analyses must recognize that model specification can significantly
affect the conclusions reached.
One of the most interesting outcomes in Table 2 is the robustness
of results for Germany, New Zealand, and Switzerland. For those
countries the VDC evidence indicates that money exceeds the variance in
real output accounted for by the interest rate regardless of
specification and ordering. Is there a common factor explaining this
outcome? One obvious possibility is that Germany and Switzerland are
recognized as countries in which the central bank follows a credible
low-inflation policy. Such policy actions also have occurred, though
more recently, in New Zealand. (15) In such a policy environment,
movements of money may be more exogenous to output than in policy
regimes where money growth is secondary to controlling interest rates as
a means to stabilize economic activity. Below we investigate other
potential explanations for this outcome, ones that focus on the
development and structure of the countries' financial markets.
Table 3 presents the battery of results with M2 replacing M1. The
U.S. results are qualitatively identical to Table 2: The VDC for M2
exceeds that for the interest rate only when the TS specification is
used. The switch to a broader measure of money affects the results for
several other countries. For instance, for the Netherlands and for
Singapore the VDC for M2 does not exceed that of the interest rate, even
though it did for M1. The results for Portugal indicate that M2 has a
greater explanatory power than the interest rate when the DS
specification is used. Using M1, we found exactly the opposite: M1
dominated the interest rate when the TS model is used. There also are
minor changes in the M1 versus M2 results for Canada, Japan, and Norway.
These results indicate that changes in the monetary aggregate can affect
outcome, but not always in a predictable fashion (e.g., moving to a
broader measure leads to increased importance of the interest rate).
The most noticeable change between Tables 2 and 3 is that the
results for Turkey indicate that M2 but not M1 plays a prominent role in
explaining the variance of output. This switch may be explained by the
significant trend of "dollarization" in Turkey. (16) Since
Turkey's M2 includes foreign currency deposits, the behavior of M2
and its potential impact on real output in Turkey may reflect nonpolicy
actions taken by the public in how they manage their portfolio of
financial assets. For the broader M2 measure the specification (TS vs.
DS) and ordering have no effect on the significance of money in
explaining output variance. The most striking result in Table 2 is that
M2 dominates the interest rate in Germany, New Zealand, and Switzerland.
This finding not only appears to be robust across specifications, but
also across definitions of money.
Overall, the results in Tables 2 and 3 suggest that the behavior of
money may be more important in explaining real output fluctuations than
some have concluded. (17) Although interpreting results such as these
can be likened to a beauty contest, a money-friendly view is that the
results do not reject the notion that in many countries money can serve
as a useful indicator of future real output behavior. Such a conclusion
is supported by the data in half of the countries tested. Viewing the
results slightly differently, the fact that interest rates dominate
money in only half of the countries is not overwhelming support for the
predominant view among economists and policy makers that interest rates
are the only variable worth considering in policy analysis and
deliberations.
Perhaps the most interesting finding is that money dominates the
interest rate in Germany, New Zealand, and Switzerland. (18) This
statement also is true for M2 in Turkey. What separates these countries
from the others? Is there something unique about them that generates
this outcome? In the next section, we investigate this question by
comparing the financial development and structure of these countries
with the others used.
4. The Role of Financial Size and Structure (19)
Are Germany, New Zealand, and Switzerland characterized by some
financial market development or structure that helps explain our
findings? To answer this we utilize the data set constructed by Beck,
Demirguc-Kunt, and Levine (1999). This data set is a comprehensive
collection of economic and social measures used primarily in research on
economic growth. We selected several measures to capture the relative
size of the central bank and the banking system, measured relative to
total financial assets and to GDP. We also gauge the "depth"
of the country's financial markets using statistics such as the
ratio of liquid liabilities to GDP and private credit extended by the
banking system relative to GDP. Measures of the structure and efficiency
of the countries' financial system also are used, including the
three-bank concentration ratio, overhead costs, and net interest margins
of commercial banks. Finally, we include measures of the relative size
of the stock and bond markets. A complete listing of the measures use d
and their mnemonics is provided in Table 4. Table 5 presents summary
statistics associated with each financial measure listed in Table 4
available, for each country. For the sake of comparison, Germany, New
Zealand, and Switzerland are separated from other countries.
Do the financial data reveal any discernible pattern that explains
our empirical results? In brief, the answer is no. For one thing, there
is a great deal of variation in each measure across countries. In
Germany and Switzerland, for example, central banks assets are less than
one percent of total assets (CBA/TA). In New Zealand, however, the
figure is over 6%. (For purpose of comparison, the figure for the United
States is less than 3%.) Glancing down this column reveals that Germany
and Switzerland have among the lowest measures in this category. Even
so, similarly low measures are reported for France and the Netherlands,
two countries for which money was not found to exert much influence on
output relative to interest rates. The measure "deposit bank assets
relative to total" (DBA/TA) indicates less dispersal among
countries, but no clear pattern emerges that would distinguish one
country from another. Size of the central bank and of the commercial
banking system relative to the whole financial system thus do not appear
as a likely explanations for our empirical results.
When measures of the financial system relative to GDP are
considered, the size of the financial markets relative to GDP in
Switzerland is larger than the average. Although "central bank
assets to GDP" seem extraordinary, the other three measures all
register the largest values of any country in the sample. Still, the
fact that such is not found for Germany and New Zealand suggests that
this characteristic isn't unique and is not an explanation for
finding that money explains the behavior of real output better than
interest rates.
Is there any evidence in measures of financial market structure and
efficiency that solve the puzzle? The statistics under this umbrella
heading presented in Table 5 suggest that the answer is no. Regardless
of the specific measure used, whether it is the three-bank concentration
ratio, measures of efficiency, or size of the stock and bond markets,
there is no apparent pattern that accounts for the findings in Tables 2
and 3.
5. Conclusions
This study examines the empirical relation between money, interest
rates, and output across a sample of diverse economies. Previous
analyses often rely on U.S. data or other financially developed
countries from a specific region, such as the EU. In contrast, the
evidence presented in this paper is based on a diverse sample of 20
countries, including industrial countries from different regions as well
as economically and financially less-developed countries.
Our results indicate that rejecting money as an informative tool in
setting monetary policy is unwarranted. First, the results suggest that
money often plays a significant role in explaining the fluctuations of
real output. Across the different specifications used and countries
examined, money accounts for more of the variance in real output than
nominal interest rates in about half of the countries. Second, the
results indicate that concern over the stationarity assumption, found to
be important for the United States, can alter conclusions about the
relative importance of money and interest rates in other countries. In
summary, the results do not support an out-and-out rejection of money as
an informative economic variable when it comes to setting or evaluating
monetary policy.
The most intriguing result is that in Germany, New Zealand, and
Switzerland money, Ml or M2, always explains a greater percentage of the
variation in real output than do interest rates. Other than the
well-known bias toward low-inflation policies by these central banks, a
review of data measuring the size, structure, and efficiency of their
financial systems provides no obvious pattern to explain the results.
Appendix
All quarterly data are taken from IMF's International
Financial Statistics CD-ROM tape. The following further describes the
data and indicates the sample periods for each country:
Prices: CPI, 1990 = 100, line 64
Money: Narrow money (Ml) line 34 and M2 = Ml + quasi money (line 5)
Output: Real GDP (1990 prices), line 90
Interest rate: Money market rate (line 60B) for all countries,
except Mexico and Israel (T-bill rate, line 60C), and Finland (central
bank rate, line 60)
Table 1
Summary Statistics
Mean and Standard Deviation (in Parentheses)
Country [DELTA]RGDP [DELTA]M1 [DELTA]M2 [DELTA]CPI
United States 288 (0.92) 5.48 (1.77) 7.24 (1.17) 4.28 (0.80)
Australia 3.21 (1.25) 10.72 (2.65) 11.44 (1.99) 7.16 (1.61)
Canada 2.80 (0.86) 8.72 (2.66) 9.24 (1.81) 5.04 (1.15)
Finland 2.52 (6.02) 15.72 (10.16) 10.96 (2.21) 6.96 (1.56)
France 2.48 (0.71) 7.96 (5.13) 13.08 (6.53) 6.04 (1.38)
Germany 3.12 (1.53) 7.88 (1.80) 8.28 (1.96) 3.20 (0.91)
Israel 4.56 (2.26) 21.68 (5.02) 19.44 (2.11) 12.96 (1.50)
Italy 2.40 (0.86) 11.28 (14.34) 10.76 (9.37) 9.28 (2.09)
Japan 5.04 (1.61) 10.80 (2.51) 11.20 (2.83) 4.32 (1.61)
Korea 5.48 (21.37) 13.84 (6.88) 18.48 (2.32) 7.92 (1.90)
Mexico 2.64 (5.34) 35.84 (8.98) 34.48 (15.56) 28.64 (7.32)
Netherlands 2.24 (0.92) 6.40 (1.80) 6.04 (1.27) 2.88 (0.78)
New Zealand 2.24 (2.90) 13.80 (10.81) 15.60 (10.13) 5.28 (1.59)
Norway 3.44 (4.00) 11.96 (3.67) 9.04 (2.20) 6.04 (1.28)
Portugal 2.68 (1.75) 14.48 (11.47) 14.96 (4.11) 11.20 (2.20)
Singapore 6.84 (3.44) 8.44 (2.81) 11.84 (1.78) 1.68 (0.63)
Spain 2.32 (0.48) 11.68 (2.04) 11.28 (2.63) 9.44 (1.94)
Sweden 2.64 (11.96) 3.72 (53.64) 11.96 (8.06) 7.92 (1.60)
Switzerland 1.68 (1.25) 4.24 (3.95) 6.48 (2.19) 2.88 (0.84)
Turkey 5.56 (27.47) 52.28 (12.31) 60.56 (5.20) 56.28 (5.04)
Mean and
Standard
Deviation (in
Parentheses)
Country R Sample Period
United States 6.41 (3.32) 1957:4-1998:3
Australia 9.37 (3.76) 1970:1-1996:3
Canada 8.91 (3.67) 1975:2-1998:2
Finland 8.12 (1.38) 1970:2-1996:2
France 8.82 (3.14) 1970:2-1998:2
Germany 5.52 (2.50) 1960:2-1998:3
Israel 14.60 (3.60) 1986:2-1998:2
Italy 12.37 (4.24) 1970:2-1997:2
Japan 6.41 (3.12) 1957:4-1998:2
Korea 14.25 (3.94) 1977:1-1998:2
Mexico 39.75 (31.11) 1987:1-1997:3
Netherlands 6.52 (2.46) 1997:2-1997:4
New Zealand 12.71 (5.70) 1983:2-1998:2
Norway 9.87 (3.50) 1973:2-1998:2
Portugal 13.33 (4.49) 1981:2-1997:4
Singapore 4.27 (1.51) 1984:4-1998:1
Spain 12.39 (4.95) 1974:2-1998:2
Sweden 9.42 (3.17) 1969:2-1989:4
Switzerland 3.36 (2.33) 1976:1-1998:2
Turkey 68.35 (32.30) 1987:2-1998:1
RGDP is real GDP (1990$), M1 is the narrow definition of money, M2 is
the broad definition of money, CPI is the consumer price index, and R is
a short-term interest rate. [DELTA] is the difference operator. All
variables except the interest rate are expressed in logarithms. A more
complete description of the data and the sample periods is found in the
data Appendix.
Table 2
Variance Decompositions
Money/Rate
Trend Difference
Money: M1 Stationary Stationary Stationary
Country Order Without Trend (TS) (DS)
United States 1 28.17/26.82 25.45/12.78 2.81/21.94
2 25.40/30.37 24.51/16.58 2.25/13.02
Standard 0.03565 0.2488 0.00860
Error (SE)
Australia 1 13.10/20.56 12.98/7.19 7.88/8.47
2 10.52/22.05 13.20/5.17 7.51/8.58
SE 0.03117 0.01936 0.01215
Canada 1 16.08/51.44 21.00/44.12 1.97/10.5
2 16.10/47.95 21.12/43.85 13.56/11.94
SE 0.02655 0.02446 0.00848
Finland 1 2.50/45.13 3.18/7.85 1.70/21.54
2 0.68/46.24 0.48/9.18 1.76/23.98
SE 0.03901 0.02284 0.2577
France 1 8.66/42.45 4.23/36.15 11.45/17.15
2 9.09/53.40 5.06/48.46 10.37/16.23
SE 0.02393 0.02026 0.00692
Germany 1 52.32/9.74 27.53/4.30 16.01/2.92
2 43.43/8.54 22.94/4.90 25.58/2.26
SE 0.04511 0.03134 0.01514
Israel 1 10.59/8.36 10.25/9.14 29.6/8.53
2 4.78/1.83 5.51/2.40 12.36/5.88
SE 0.03028 0.02393 0.01980
Italy 1 12.34/44.17 13.61/45.58 11.46/15.59
2 7.31/43.00 7.38/46.35 2.44/16.67
SE 0.02314 0.02190 0.00857
Japan 1 0.67/0.28 0.93/0.21 6.94/4.77
2 2.53/0.15 3.07/0.16 2.68/4.59
SE 0.06386 0.06473 0.01617
Korea 1 8.60/35.70 6.73/35.47 3.76/6.13
2 5.42/7.98 4.39/9.29 2.94/3.23
SE 0.06953 0.06101 0.04988
Mexico 1 6.29/35.44 13.35/18.02 17.36/18.00
2 4.07/9.52 8.86/16.54 14.46/15.70
SE 0.03081 0.02407 0.01986
Netherlands 1 31.00/23.68 14.81/21.85 10.69/9.01
2 34.17/22.90 16.74/12.62 7.90/3.58
SE 0.01726 0.01482 0.00926
New Zealand 1 20.56/24.26 21.78/13.53 25.48/4.34
2 34.10/6.45 11.04/6.54 16.27/2.84
SE 0.05654 0.02457 0.02799
Norway 1 7.32/30.51 14.06/30.33 8.32/19.34
2 6.67/13.34 14.22/21.49 8.06/16.82
SE 0.04337 0.03087 0.02393
Portugal 1 37.23/24.02 52.50/17.41 11.65/16.46
2 17.63/7.10 49.74/24.19 7.71/11.98
SE 0.01640 0.01326 0.01424
Singapore 1 57.23/33.65 36.20/28.88 19.44/6.85
2 29.09/30.73 23.15/29.54 21.31/5.84
SE 0.08495 0.02432 0.01567
Spain 1 5.41/14.03 6.85/1.76 22.35/7.69
2 6.91/14.11 4.33/3.16 20.16/11.45
SE 0.03454 0.02458 0.00440
Sweden 1 16.79/19.45 10.95/11.12 13.72/4.53
2 8.71/16.91 6.37/8.07 15.64/1.94
SE 0.02496 0.02328 0.02423
Switzerland 1 59.61/16.27 42.95/17.54 26.16/11.01
2 53.33/13.94 39.19/12.42 21.61/8.46
SE 0.03620 0.03060 0.01094
Turkey 1 12.09/35.02 17.96/32.06 20.08/18.59
2 14.59/34.75 23.78/30.95 19.19/21.38
SE 0.04056 0.04044 0.04805
Order 1: R, M, CPI, RGDP. Order 2: RDGP, CPI, R, M. Variable definitions
and sources are documented in Table 1 and the data Appendix. Results in
bold indicate that the VDC of money exceeds 10% and exceeds the VDC for
the interest rate by 5% (not percentage points).
Table 3
Variance Decompositions
Money/Rate
Trend Difference
Money: M2 Stationary Stationery Stationary
Country Order Without Trend (TS) (DS)
United States 1 9.74/36.72 26.76/16.54 4.70/25.10
2 5.25/36.66 19.58/15.62 3.46/11.76
Standard 0.03714 0.02721 0.00861
Error (SE)
Australia 1 13.10/20.56 12.98/7.19 9.47/5.97
2 10.53/22.05 13.20/5.17 7.18/6.19
SE 0.03121 0.01879 0.01216
Canada 1 5.46/69.95 14.71/48.23 4.84/7.84
2 4.23/64.84 13.68/51.65 3.75/10.02
SE 0.02959 0.02404 0.00845
Finland 1 22.51/40.14 18.31/9.78 4.07/21.48
2 10.82/40.39 3.98/11.05 1.54/24.13
SE 0.03521 0.02447 0.02579
France 1 5.96/47.33 7.93/34.29 10.75/15.50
2 3.68/59.15 3.79/45.82 7.06/14.68
SE 0.02285 0.01975 0.00694
Germany 1 36.27/13.11 37.66/4.58 14.92/2.78
2 27.68/10.57 33.37/2.41 15.24/2.08
SE 0.04369 0.02923 0.01509
Israel 1 10.08/13.59 8.94/14.00 12.17/9.41
2 4.31/3.90 5.60/4.22 11.21/6.70
SE 0.02524 0.02382 0.01976
Italy 1 13.13/33.49 10.36/50.40 8.67/15.68
2 6.70/26.66 6.54/40.32 3.87/15.60
SE 0.02011 0.02129 0.00858
Japan 1 7.99/1.07 7.46/3.87 12.88/4.32
2 4.45/0.12 4.68/1.15 9.90/3.91
SE 0.05681 0.05723 0.01585
Korea 1 4.31/42.80 4.92/41.90 2.07/5.68
2 4.03/15.41 4.57/19.44 1.79/5.71
SE 0.07344 0.06480 0.05050
Mexico 1 7.66/36.15 14.56/44.40 19.79/21.81
2 5.64/6.45 3.98/12.33 9.28/20.07
SE 0.02943 0.02592 0.01965
Netherlands 1 17.22/43.95 20.23/21.99 4.94/7.94
2 10.11/40.90 11.19/14.05 2.90/2.51
SE 0.01758 0.01485 0.00923
New Zealand 1 12.37/22.13 34.84/12.72 26.43/9.74
2 22.67/3.48 13.06/3.54 13.35/2.39
SE 0.04008 0.02751 0.02729
Norway 1 1.01/46.67 7.54/8.71 6.12/15.02
2 2.57/31.38 10.77/4.84 4.17/13.32
SE 0.04776 0.03200 0.02390
Portugal 1 3.71/70.88 4.68/69.07 20.54/12.83
2 1.86/62.92 2.11/64.98 20.18/9.27
SE 0.02156 0.02144 0.01528
Singapore 1 26.38/29.15 14.81/25.17 7.39/10.08
2 32.80/31.87 14.36/25.78 6.41/9.46
SE 0.03932 0.02610 0.00439
Spain 1 1.00/31.89 5.34/2.19 7.39/8.01
2 0.34/29.36 2.89/2.69 10.44/10.87
SE 0.03598 0.02610 0.00439
Sweden 1 3.06/30.44 3.60/19.13 1.18/5.34
2 3.15/22.12 3.97/11.86 1.36/2.84
SE 0.02451 0.02258 0.02285
Switzerland 1 47.00/17.45 45.73/17.23 15.35/7.53
2 46.00/16.60 46.39/15.78 15.02/5.62
SE 0.02717 0.02697 0.01080
Turkey 1 25.65/19.21 35.99/27.47 41.72/18.27
2 10.89/5.55 35.37/7.45 40.39/13.49
SE 0.04690 0.03845 0.05139
Notes: See Table 2.
Table 4
Description of Financial Development Variables
Variable Definition
CBA/TA Central bank assets to total
financial assets
DBA/TA Deposit money bank assets to
total financial assets
CBA/GDP Central bank assets to GDP
DBA/GDP Deposit money banks assets
to GDP
LL/GDP Liquid liabilities to GDP
PC/GDP Private credit by deposit
money banks to GDP
CONC Three-bank concentration
ratio
OVER/TA Overhead costs to total
assets
NIM/TA Net interest margin to
total assets
CAP/GDP Stock market capitalization
to GDP
DEBT/GDP Long-term private debt issues
to GDP
Variable Description/Page Reference to Beck,
Demirgue-Kunt, and Levine (1999)
CBA/TA Central bank defined as
institutions that perform duties
of central banks. Total financial
assets equal sum of central bank,
deposit money bank, and other
financial institutions assets.
End-of-period. pages 5-6
DBA/TA Deposit money banks are all
financial institutions whose
liabilities are in the form of
deposits transferable by check
or otherwise used in making
payments. End-of-period. Page 6
CBA/GDP Central bank assets defined above,
GDP as measured in IMF. Page 6
DBA/GDP Deposit money banks and GDP as
defined above. Page 6
LL/GDP Sum of currency, demand deposits
and interest-bearing liabilities
of banks and other financial
intermediaries relative to GDP.
Pages 6-7
PC/GDP Claims on private sector by
deposit money banks relative to
GDP. Page 7
CONC Ratio of three largest banks'
assets to total banking sector
assets. Page 11
OVER/TA Accounting value of bank's overhead
costs relative to its total
assets. End-of-period. Page 10
NIM/TA Accounting value of value of bank's
net interst revenue relative to
total assets. End-of-period. Page
10
CAP/GDP Value of listed shares on country's
stock market relative to GDP.
Values are end-of-year. Page 17
DEBT/GDP Enquity issues, both long-term and
debt issues, relative to GDP.
Nominal measure. Page 18
Source: Beck, Demirguc- Kunt, and Levine (1999).
Table 5
Measures of Financial Size, Structure and Efficiency
Size
Country CBA/T DBA/T CBA/GDP DMBA/GP LL/GDP
Germany 0.95 93.43 1.14 110.12 64.10
New Zealand 6.12 66.62 3.91 48.84 55.43
Switzerland 0.77 81.27 1.45 154.31 138.18
Australia 2.86 55.05 2.88 56.11 56.42
Canada 4.68 60.87 4.20 53.68 68.53
Finland na na 1.55 68.14 51.09
France 0.74 72.24 1.06 93.87 68.02
Israel na na 11.17 97.01 62.94
Italy na na 11.98 69.39 69.70
Japan 1.80 50.12 4.19 119.16 168.31
Korea, Rep. of 3.11 57.03 2.49 48.35 46.15
Mexico 17.60 48.78 7.69 19.18 23.37
Netherlands 0.46 51.42 0.84 93.66 81.76
Norway 2.38 54.76 2.88 93.13 53.83
Portugal na na 14.07 79.80 73.19
Singapore na na na 89.63 102.71
Spain 7.14 85.99 7.30 87.45 72.85
Sweden 5.50 41.23 7.25 54.12 49.82
Turkey 34.38 59.61 9.26 18.64 21.82
United States 2.91 47.15 4.66 75.13 62.61
Size Structure and Efficiency
Country PC/GDP CONC OVER/A NIM/TA CAP/GDP
Germany 92.26 44.16 2.77 2.46 18.64
New Zealand 54.17 76.94 2.75 2.51 40.47
Switzerland 177.64 73.92 4.94 1.55 70.59
Australia 81.23 67.44 2.61 1.92 43.10
Canada 76.63 58.01 2.44 1.75 45.54
Finland 66.99 86.46 1.65 1.60 18.44
France 90.89 40.66 4.41 3.51 19.77
Israel 50.54 86.39 3.82 3.30 28.89
Italy 50.50 35.81 3.56 3.60 11.87
Japan 169.26 20.99 1.39 1.75 73.01
Korea, Rep. of 80.90 33.40 2.48 2.29 24.55
Mexico 17.61 59.06 5.03 5.35 14.55
Netherlands 127.97 73.34 1.00 1.46 40.92
Norway 88.51 84.54 2.48 3.13 15.19
Portugal 63.21 45.27 2.56 3.46 7.75
Singapore 94.80 72.91 1.43 2.09 123.06
Spain 72.02 46.44 3.49 3.76 18.08
Sweden 108.94 88.57 3.07 2.66 38.09
Turkey 13.82 44.77 6.36 9.37 6.14
United States 130.74 18.21 3.65 3.88 58.18
Structure
and
Efficiency
Country DEBT/GDP
Germany 37.43
New Zealand 0.00
Switzerland 62.09
Australia 13.76
Canada 8.62
Finland 39.09
France 41.24
Israel 0.00
Italy 28.10
Japan 29.99
Korea, Rep. of 32.19
Mexico 0.97
Netherlands 16.56
Norway 19.17
Portugal 10.59
Singapore 3.65
Spain 9.28
Sweden 57.56
Turkey 0.69
United States 52.58
Notes: All measures are in percentages.
Source: Beck, Demirgue-Kunt, and Levine (1999).
Definitions of the measures used are provided in the data appendix to
this paper.
Received May 2000; accepted December 2001.
(1.) The importance of interest races has been questioned in
several studies. Bernanke (1990) reports that the empirical significance
of the interest rate variable declines throughout the 1980s. Hafer and
Kutan (1997) demonstrate that the impact of interest rates on output and
the apparent decline in money's importance through the 1980s is
largely a function of the stationarity assumption used.
(2.) This consensus model can be written as a three-equation
dynamic system, including an aggregate demand equation, a Phillips
curve, and a monetary policy rule. In this model, aggregate demand
movements are driven by past deviations of output from potential and
changes in the real rate of interest. As such, monetary policy works
only indirectly through the interest rate channel. For another
discussion of this model, see MeCallum (2001). Nelson (2000) provides
empirical estimates that refute the findings of Rudebusch and Svensson,
at least for the United Kingdom and the United States. Where Rudebusch
and Svensson find that M2 has no predictive power over output in the
United States, Nelson finds that movements in the St. Louis adjusted
monetary base do. See also Hafer (2001).
(3.) Hayo (1999) uses a similar VAR model.
(4.) Nelson's (2000) work demonstrates that conclusions about
money are subject to this concern.
(5.) Running a regression of real output growth on money growth
across countries results in an estimated coefficient on money growth of
0.04 for M1 and M2, statistically insignificant at the 5% level.
Conversely, a regression of inflation on money growth yields estimated
coefficients of 1.02 for M1 and 0.97 for M2, both significant at the 1%
level of significance. These results support the belief that increasing
money growth does not permanently increase real output growth, but is
more likely to lead to higher inflation. For a similar analysis and a
review of the relevant literature, see Dwyer and Hater (1999) and Hater
(2001).
(6.) We searched for apparent structural breaks in data.
Time-series plots of the data indicated a significant break for M1 for
Finland during the second quarter of 1991. Therefore, for Finland, the
estimated VAR models with M1 include a dummy variable that takes a value
of 1 starting from 1991:II to the end and zero otherwise.
(7.) See, among others, Hafer and Sheehan (1991) and the articles
cited therein.
(8.) A complete listing of the lag-length test results is available
on request.
(9.) In an earlier version of this paper we also reported Wald
tests. Such tests can be viewed as "within-sample" tests,
because they do not provide an indication of the dynamic characteristics
of variables in the system and their usefulness is limited to the sample
period used. As a result, we rely on variance decompositions, which are
considered as out-of-sample tests, to gauge the relative strength of
money and interest rates on output. For further discussion of these
issues, see Masih and Masih (2001).
(10.) The complete set of results is available upon request.
(11.) Increasing the horizon does not affect the qualitative
outcomes reported.
(12.) For ease of presentation, only the VDC results for money and
interest rates are presented. A full set of results is available upon
request. One could also consider the impact of exchange rates on output
within the VAR model. We believe that the domestic interest rate
captures this impact through interest parity relation, which states that
[i.sub.d] - [i.sub.f] = e, where [i.sub.d] and [i.sub.f] are domestic
and foreign interest rates, respectively, and e is the expected change
in the exchange rate. Assuming that this parity relation holds, which is
a reasonable assumption because of the increasing level of world capital
mobility, domestic interest rates may capture foreign influences, such
as changes in foreign interest rates and exchange rates, In case of a
fixed exchange rate regime, using exchange rates is not relevant.
Therefore, our VAR models do not include exchange rates.
(13.) It is unresolved in the literature whether the interest rate
should be included in its level of first-differenced form. Bernanke and
Blinder (1992) argue that including a first-differenced interest rate in
a VAR model is questionable. Because there is no agreed-upon procedure,
the DS specification was estimated with the interest rate in its level
form. These results led to the same conclusions as the DS specification,
except for Mexico, where the results are markedly different from those
reported in Table 2. In that case the DS specification with the levels
of the interest rate produced an M1 VDC that was larger than that for
the interest rate, and exceeded 10%. Complete results using this
specification are available upon request.
(14.) One could draw a similar conclusion for Canada and the
Netherlands. However, in those cases a change in the VAR ordering
changes the outcome, suggesting that the sensitivity of money's
role is explained by more than the use of the TS or DS specifications
alone.
(15.) For a discussion of central bank policies in Germany, see von
Hagen (1999); for Switzerland, see Bernanke et al. (1999, chapter 4);
and for New Zealand, see Evans et al. (1996) and Bernanke et al. (1999,
chapter 5). For a general discussion of the role of central banks, see
Bernanke et al. (1999) and Mishkin (1999).
(16.) The dollarization ratio based on the IMF data, as measured by
the ratio of foreign currency deposits to GDP, was about 5% in 1990.
This ratio jumped to around 15% in 1995 and then to 20% in 2000.
(17.) The results of Nelson (2000) and Hafer (2001) agree with this
assessment.
(18.) This outcome is robust to changing the sample period. At the
suggestion of the referee, the VAR models were reestimated using a
common sample. Attempting to maximize the sample length and the number
of countries produced a limited subset of the original countries sample.
Even so, over a common sample period of 1977/I-1996/II, M1 and M2 still
generate VDCs that are large relative to the interest rate for Germany
and Switzerland. The only other notable result from this estimate is
that money, regardless of the specification, plays a secondary role to
the interest rate in explaining output in the United States. Complete
common-sample estimates are available upon request.
(19.) We thank the referee for suggesting this line of inquiry.
References
Beck, Thorsten, Asli Demirguc-Kunt, and Ross Levine. 1999. A new
database on financial development and structure. Unpublished paper,
University of Minnesota.
Bernanke, Ben S. 1990. On the predictive power of interest rates
and interest rate spreads. New England Economic Review 51-68.
Bernanke, Ben, and Alan S. Blinder. 1992. The Federal funds rate and the channels of monetary transmission. American Economic Review
82:901-21.
Bernanke, Ben. S., Thomas Laubach, Frederic S. Mishkin, and Adam S.
Posen. 1999. Inflation targeting: Lessons from the international
experience. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Christiano, Lawrence J., and Lars Ljungqvist. 1998. Money does
Granger-cause output in the bivariate money-output relation. Journal of
Monetary Economics 22:217-36.
Canova, Fabio. 1998. Detrending and business cycle facts. Journal
of Monetary Economics 41:475-512.
Davis, Mark S., and J. Ernest Tanner. 1997. Money and economic
activity revisited. Journal of International Money and Finance
16:955-68.
Dejong, David N., John C. Nankervis, N. E. Savin, and Charles H.
Whiteman. 1992. The power problems of unit root tests in time series
with autoregressive errors. Journal of Econometrics 53:323-43.
Dejong, David N., and Charles H. Whiteman. 1991. Reconsidering
trends and random walks in macroeconomic time series. Journal of
Monetary Economics 28:221-54.
Dwyer, Gerald P., Jr., and R. W. Hafer. 1999. Are money growth and
inflation still related? Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic Review
84:32-43.
Evans, Lewis, Arthur Grimes, Bryce Wilkinson, and David Teece.
1996. Economic reform in New Zealand 1984-95: The pursuit of efficiency.
Journal of Economic Literature 34:1856-902.
Friedman, Benjamin M., and Kenneth N. Kuttner. 1992. Money, income,
prices and interest rates. American Economic Review 82:472-92.
Friedman, Benjamin M., and Kenneth N. Kuttner. 1993. Another look
at the evidence on money-income causality. Journal of Econometrics
57:189-203.
Hafer, R. W. 2001. What remains of Monetarism? Federal Reserve Bank
of Atlanta Economic Review Fourth Quarter: 13-33.
Hafer, R. W., and A. M. Kutan. 1997. More evidence on the
money-output relationship. Economic Inquiry 35:48-58.
Hafer, R. W., and Richard G. Sheehan. 1991. Policy inference using
VAR models: The effects of alternative lag structures. Economic Inquiry
29:44-52.
Hayo, Bernd. 1999. Money-output and Granger causality revisited: An
empirical analysis of EU countries. Applied Economics 31:1489-501.
Krol, Robert, and Lee E. Ohanian. 1990. The impact of stochastic
and deterministic trends on money-output causality: A multi-country
investigation. Journal of Econometrics 45:291-308.
Masih, Rumi, and Sbul M. M. Masih. 2001. Long and short term
dynamic casual transmission amongst international stock markets. Journal
of International Money and Finance 20:563-87.
McCallum, Bennett T. 2001. Monetary policy analysis in models
without money. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Review
83:145-63.
Meyer, Laurence H. 2001. Does money matter? Federal Reserve Bank of
St. Louis Economic Review 84:1-15.
Mishkin, Frederic S. 1999. International experiences with different
monetary policy regimes. Journal of Monetary Economics 43:579-605.
Nelson, Edward. 2000. Direct effects of base money on aggregate
demand: Theory and evidence. Unpublished paper, Bank of England.
Rudebusch, Glenn D. 1993. The uncertain unit of root in real GNP.
American Economic Review 83:264-72.
Rudebusch, Glenn D., and Lars E.O. Svensson. 1999. Policy rules for
inflation targeting. In Monetary policy rules, edited by John B. Taylor.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 203-62.
Rudebutch, Glenn D., and Lars E.O. Svensson. 2002. Eurosystem
monetary targeting: Lessons from U.S. data. European Economic Review
46:417-42.
Sims, Christopher A. 1980. Comparison of interwar and postwar business cycles: Monetarism reconsidered. American Economic Review
70:250-7.
Stock, James H., and Mark W. Watson. 1989. Interpreting the
evidence on money-income causality. Journal of Econometrics 40:161-81.
Swanson, Norman R. 1998. Money and output viewed through a rolling
window. Journal of Monetary Economics 41:455-73.
Thoma, M. A. 1994. Subsample instability and asymmetrics in
money-income causality. Journal of Econometrics 64:279-306.
Todd, Richard M. 1990. Vector autoregression evidence on
monetarism: Another look at the robustness debate. Federal Reserve Bank
of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 14:19-37.
Von Hagen, Jurgen. 1999. Money growth targeting by the Bundesbank.
Journal of Monetary Economics 43:681-701.
R. W. Hafer * and Ali M. Kutan +
* Department of Economics and Finance, Southern Illinois University
Edwardsville, Edwardsville, IL 62026, USA; E-mail rhafer@siue.edu;
corresponding author.
+ Department of Economics and Finance, Southcm Illinois University
Edwardsville, Edwardsville, IL 62026, USA, and Center for European
Integration Studies (ZEI), Bonn, Germany. E-mail akutan@siue.edu.
This paper began while Hafer was a Research Fellow, Institute for
Urban Research, and a Visiting Scholar, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta;
and Kutan was a Visiting Scholar with the Federal Reserve Bank of St.
Louis. We thank Garett Jones, colleagues at the Banks, and an anonymous
referee for comments and suggestions that improved an earlier version of
this paper. Tansu Aksoy provided excellent research assistance. The
views and conclusions expressed may not be those of the Federal Reserve
Banks of Atlanta and St. Louis, or of the Federal Reserve System.