Exclusive dealing through resellers in auctions with stochastic bidder participation.
Deltas, George
1. Introduction
This paper considers a private values auction in which some of an
item's potential consumers compete for its possession against
professional resellers (or intermediaries). If the resellers win, they
market the item to the general public, which includes the consumers who
participated in the auction. We show that prohibiting the participation
of these potential consumers in the auction can have direct
revenue-enhancing effects. In particular, we show that a risk-neutral
seller prefers to exclude final consumers from an auction and sell the
item exclusively to resellers when these resellers can gain access, at a
cost, to a sufficiently bigger market than the seller himself.
This result might at first appear counterintuitive, as increasing
the number of bidders increases expected revenue in private values
bidding models. Seemingly, a seller could not profit from excluding any
set of bidders. The intuition behind our result is that the resellers
recoup their expenses for buying the item by reselling it to the final
consumers. If some final consumers participate in the first auction and
are outbid by the resellers, this is an indication that their values for
the item are relatively low. Outbidding part of their customer base is
"bad news" for resellers, so their bids are depressed if final
consumers compete with them. Indeed, the resellers are less aggressive
when competing against a subset of the final consumers even if, by
observing the valuation of the participating consumers, they cannot make
any inference about the valuations of the nonparticipating consumers,
that is, even when consumer valuations are completely independent.
This paper also characterizes the social welfare implications of
restricting the participation of consumers. The socially optimal and
revenue-maximizing choices of auction format do not necessarily
coincide. Even though restricting the participation of consumers may be
both socially and privately (for the seller) optimal, it is also
possible that restricting participation is socially optimal but
privately suboptimal, and vice-versa.
Further, the results of this paper have implications for seller
strategy, implications that are particularly relevant in a world where
electronic trading is shrinking transactions costs. In Internet
auctions, for instance, bids for an item can now be submitted
electronically by potential consumers. Sellers who were hitherto unable
to sell directly to consumers can now do so through these electronic
auctions. However, it appears likely that Internet auctions fail to
attract the entire set of possible consumers, as up to 50% of the
auctions in some major sites do not result in a sale (see Lucking-Reiley
2000). The results of this paper suggest that if indeed only a small
fraction of the potential customers participate directly in the
electronic/Internet auction, the seller may find it optimal to exclude
them altogether and, instead, sell the item in a dealer auction.
Furthermore, such a direct exclusion of final consumers from an auction
may not be driven by the desire to reduce transaction costs. In real
estat e auctions, for example, it is frequently observed that properties
that could be sold separately are sold in large batches. Indeed, in some
cases the seller explicitly announces that only wholesalers are welcome
to participate. Although such exclusions and sales of items in large
batches might economize on transactions costs, they also result in more
aggressive bidding from wholesalers. In other words, the results of our
paper endogenize the distribution channel in auction markets, without an
appeal to transactions costs.
This paper is related to two different strands of the literature
that are discussed in the next section. The first strand considers
common or affiliated value bidding environments in which preventing the
participation of certain bidders can increase seller revenue. The second
strand studies auctions with the possibility of postauction resale, and
considers both private and common value environments. Our work
integrates these two strands by considering the impact that the
possibility of resale has on the incentives of the seller to forbid the
participation of certain bidders in the auction. Our paper shows that a
seller can profitably exclude some bidders from the auction even in a
private values environment when the set of bidders is partitioned to
those who purchase for their own consumption and those who purchase for
the explicit purpose of resale.
Section 2 of the paper summarizes the related literature, whereas
section 3 describes the modeling framework and a simple, tractable,
benchmark model. The following section solves the seller's problem
for the benchmark model, and section 5 analyzes the welfare implications
of his choice. Section 6 generalizes the benchmark model to markets of
arbitrary size and shows that the key results are robust to different
assumptions about bidder entry and seller reserve. Finally, the paper
ends with a few concluding remarks. All long proofs are contained in an
Appendix.
2. Related Literature
This paper is related to two different lines of research. The first
one studies auctions in which resale can arise in equilibrium. The other
studies the possibility that the exclusion of some bidders from the
auction can actually be revenue increasing. In this section we provide a
brief overview of this research and how it relates to our work.
There has been a recent flurry of research on models of auctions
that incorporate the possibility of profitable resale. One strand of the
literature pursues explanations for resale on the basis of the existence
of further gains from trade available after the object is sold via an
auction. A potential source of these gains can arise from the
nonparticipation of a subset of the buyers in the first auction. The
winner in the first auction may then find it profitable to reauction the
item (see Haile 1996). Another potential source of gains from trade
arises from the existence of uncertainty about the private value of the
object, which is resolved after the first auction. A bidder who expects
to value the object most highly wins it in the first auction. When
uncertainty about private values is resolved, he may find it profitable
to sell the object to one of the other bidders (see Haile 2000, 2001,
2002). A third possibility of gains from trade occurs if bidder
asymmetry results in an inefficient allocation in the first-price
auction. The winner may find it profitable to resell the item to one of
the losing bidders (see Gupta and Lebrun 1997, 1999). The results in
Gupta and Lebrun (1997) are very interesting in the context of this work
because they show that it may be profitable for the seller to forbid
resale of the good. Limiting what the buyers can do with the item, which
seemingly reduces its value, can actually yield higher expected revenue.
In our work, forbidding consumption of the item, that is, limiting the
buyers to purchasing for resale, can actually increase expected revenue.
In all of the above models, all participants are potentially
"final consumers": They directly value the object that is put
up for sale. Another strand of the literature considers participants of
two types: The first type consists of participants in the first auction
who compete for the object with the intention of reselling it. The
second type consists of the final consumers who compete among themselves
to purchase the items from the resellers. Bikhchandani and Huang (1989),
for instance, analyze a common value auction in which an exogenous number of bidders competes in a multiple object auction to acquire items
that will then be resold to consumers. In that paper, the policy
question is which auction format to use to award the objects to the
resellers rather than to exclude or not to exclude the final consumers
from the auction.
This paper adopts the exogenous partition of the players into
resellers and final consumers. Unlike the model in Bikhchandani and
Huang (1989), ours is a private values model where some or all of the
final consumers can be present in the first auction. Furthermore, the
policy question we analyze is whether or not the initial seller should
allow the participation of the final consumers. Bose and Deltas (1999)
is the precursor to this work. In that paper, unlike this one, consumer
and reseller participation is deterministic with a single out of N final
consumers participating in a seller auction. That paper shows that the
seller is never better off by allowing the single consumer to compete
for the item. In contrast, in this paper the participation of both types
of buyers is stochastic. Under this framework, the optimal seller policy
depends on the probabilities of participation and the relative, to the
bidder valuations, size of the marketing costs. Furthermore, we are here
able to fully analyze the welfare im plications of the exclusion of the
final consumers from the seller's auction, derive the comparative
statics of the revenue (or welfare)-maximizing auction format, and
discuss the robustness of the results to the posting of reserve prices
and how stochastic consumer participation can arise endogenously by
analyzing the consumer participation decision.
There is a relatively small literature that considers the
profitability of exclusionary practices in auctions. Krishna and Morgan
(1997) demonstrate that, when consumer valuations are the average of all
bidders' signals, excluding one of the bidders at random can
potentially result in higher revenue. Bulow and Klemperer (1998) provide
a similar example when bidder valuations have a common and a private
component. Finally, an example in Haile (1996) shows that when competing
buyers know each other's type with probability that becomes
arbitrarily close to 1, and all competing buyers have some intrinsic
value for the auctioned object, the seller can profitably exclude one of
the buyers from the auction. Unlike our study, these three papers rely
on the fact that valuations have a common component. Our work shows
that, when the set of bidders is partitioned to those who purchase for
private consumption and those who purchase for resale, excluding bidders
from the auction can be revenue increasing even if consumer valuations
conform to the independent private values paradigm. (1)
3. Modeling Framework and the Benchmark Model
In this and the next two sections we describe and solve a benchmark
model. This model is parsimonious and simple enough that analytical solutions can be obtained. Nevertheless, the model is sufficiently rich
to allow for a range of comparative analyses. In section 6 we consider a
series of extensions that demonstrate that the main results of this
model are quite general.
Description of Players and Auction Formats
A seller is willing to sell an item to a market that consists of
two consumers. The value, [v.sub.i], that consumer i attaches to the
item is an independent draw from a nondegenerate, differentiable,
distribution F(v) with density function f(v) and is private knowledge.
We assume that the probability that each one of these two consumers
attends an auction organized by the seller is equal to p. This reflects
the possibility that a consumer may not be aware that the auction is
taking place. There also exist two intermediaries who specialize in the
resale of items of the type being sold. Either one of these
intermediaries, upon incurring a marketing cost c > 0, can ensure
that both potential customers will be aware that the item is for sale.
The intermediaries derive no direct benefit from ownership of the item.
Their willingness to pay for it equals the expected revenue they will
receive from the resale minus the marketing cost. Each intermediary will
participate in the auction organized by the seller with prob ability q.
(2) All agents in this model are risk neutral. We assume that the item
is perishable in the sense that if it does not sell there are no further
opportunities for the seller to receive any revenue from its sale. (3)
We further assume that the bidders in any auction can identify whether
the competitors are consumers or intermediaries. (4) We also assume that
there is no possibility of resale from one consumer to the other, that
is, the "marketing cost" for the consumers is too high and, if
only one of them attends the auction and wins, it will not pay to locate
the other consumer and bargain with him. (5) Finally, all the
information given above is common knowledge.
We consider two possible sales mechanisms at the disposal of the
seller: A restricted oral (English) auction in which only the
intermediaries are allowed to participate and an unrestricted oral
auction in which anyone is allowed to participate. The seller must
commit to the auction format before he observes the number and type of
participants. This reflects the institutional constraint that the rules
of an auction must be preannounced. We assume that if the intermediaries
win the item they, too, will sell it to the two consumers via an oral
auction. (6) Both auctions are assumed to be without reserve. (7)
Therefore, the seller and the intermediaries are treated symmetrically with respect to the selling mechanisms they use. (8)
Limiting the model to two consumers allows us to characterize the
choice of auction format using only the three parameters defined above
and the expected values of the highest and lowest consumer valuations.
As we show below, the functional form and any additional properties of
f(v) need not be considered. The probability of consumer participation p
can be thought of as indicating the size of the market the seller can
access without the use of a professional reseller. The marketing cost c
indicates the efficiency of these services in gaining access to the
remainder of the market. The probability q of reseller participation in
the auction indicates the availability of reseller services and the
degree of competition between resellers for the provision of these
services. A high value of q would result in a higher proportion of the
value of these services being appropriated by the seller, as resellers
are more likely to compete with each other. Conversely, a low value of q
would result in most of the rents accrui ng to the intermediaries.
Therefore, this framework is parsimonious but sufficiently rich for us
to analyze the factors that drive the seller's choice of auction
format and the factors that lead to a conflict between revenue and
welfare maximization.
Restricted Auction Revenue
In the restricted auction no consumers are allowed to participate
in the seller's auction. Observe that the expected revenue that an
intermediary will receive from selling the item to the two consumers,
[R.sup.I.sub.r], is equal to
[R.sup.I.sub.r] = E{min([v.sub.i])}.
The reservation value of an intermediary in the restricted auction
is equal to [R.sup.I.sub.r] - c. If neither intermediary shows up at the
seller auction, the realized price would equal zero. If only one
intermediary shows up at the seller auction, the realized price would
also equal zero, since there is no reserve. If both intermediaries show
up at the seller auction, they will bid up the price until it reaches
their reservation value. Therefore, the expected revenue the seller will
receive in a restricted auction, [R.sup.S.sub.r], equals:
[R.sup.S.sub.r] = [q.sup.2][[R.sup.I.sub.r] - c] =
[q.sup.2][E{min([v.sub.i])} - c].
Note that the intermediaries make positive expected profits, since,
if a single intermediary shows up, he will secure the item at a price of
zero.
Unrestricted Auction Revenue
If consumers are allowed to participate but none actually appears
at the sale the seller's revenue will be the same as in the
restricted auction. If both appear, then the intermediaries will not
bid, and the item will go to the highest valuation consumer at a price
equal to the second highest consumer valuation. To complete the
evaluation of the seller's revenue, we must determine the bidding
behavior of the intermediaries and the consumer in the case in which a
single consumer, say consumer 1 with valuation [v.sub.1], shows up at
the seller's auction.
First, let us consider the participating consumer's optimal
bidding strategy. If he loses in the seller's auction, he knows
that he will be able to compete with the other consumer for the item in
the auction organized by the intermediary who won the item. Denote the
valuation of the other consumer by [v.sub.2]. Then, in that second
auction, the participating consumer's expected rent is
[FORMULA NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Therefore, if a single consumer with valuation [v.sub.1]
participates in the seller's auction, his reservation value,
r([v.sub.1]) will be equal to
r([v.sub.1]) = [v.sub.1] - U([v.sub.1]).
Let us now turn to the bidding strategy of the intermediaries when
a single consumer participates in the seller's auction. If an
intermediary wins the auction, beating a consumer with valuation
[v.sub.1], the expected revenue he will reap when he resells the item,
[R.sup.I.sub.u]([v.sub.1]), is equal to
[FORMULA NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
The first term is equal to the expected revenue he will receive if
the participating consumer has the highest valuation for the item, and
the second term is equal to the expected revenue if the other consumer
has the highest valuation. We can write the above expression as:
[FORMULA NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
The expected revenue of the intermediaries, if they win the
auction, is equal to the reservation value of the bidder they are
competing against. Therefore, for any positive marketing cost c the
intermediaries will find it unprofitable to outbid the consumer. This
implies that if a single consumer shows up in the seller's auction
the intermediaries will not bid and the seller's revenue will be
zero. Therefore, the expected seller revenue in the unrestricted
auction, [R.sup.S.sub.u], is equal to
[R.sup.S.sub.u] = [p.sup.2]E{min([v.sub.i])} + [(1 -
p).sup.2][q.sup.2]{min([v.sub.i])} - c].
In the next section we consider the seller's optimal choice of
auction format.
4. Seller's Choice of Auction Format
The seller will choose the restricted auction if
[R.sup.S.sub.r] > [R.sup.S.sub.u].
It turns out, as Proposition 1 states below, that the
revenue-maximizing auction format is a function of the probability of
consumer participation, p, the probability of reseller participation, q,
and the ratio of the marketing cost, c, to the revenue obtained in a
reseller's auction. We, therefore, find convenient to introduce a
definition of the normalized marketing cost:
DEFINITION. The normalized marketing cost, c, is the ratio of the
marketing cost, c, to the revenue obtained in a reseller's auction.
c = c/E{min([v.sub.i])}
Suppose that the normalized marketing cost, c, is low enough that
the restricted auction yields positive revenue. Then, if the probability
of consumer participation, p, is sufficiently low, the seller would
prefer to exclude the consumers from the auction. This is formally
stated in Proposition 1 below, the proof of which (and of all other
results) is to be found in the Appendix.
PROPOSITION 1. For any value of marketing costs c [member of] (0,
1) and probability of intermediary participation q [member of] (0, 1)
there exists some critical probability of consumer participation
[p.sup.*] [member of] (0, 1) such that for p < [p.sup.*] the seller
would prefer to exclude the consumers from the auction. Furthermore,
this probability is given by
[p.sup.*] = 2[q.sup.2] 1 - c/1 + [q.sup.2](1 - c).
It follows that [p.sup.*] is an increasing function of the
probability of the reseller participation, q, and a decreasing function
of the normalized marketing cost, c.
Observe from the expressions for [R.sup.S.sub.r] and
[R.sup.2.sub.u] that if the probability of consumer participation is 0,
then the seller is indifferent between the two auction formats. If, on
the other hand, the probability of consumer participation is 1, then the
seller would choose the unrestricted auction. One might presume, on the
basis of the above observations, that for any positive probability of
consumer participation the seller would prefer the unrestricted auction.
Proposition 1 shows that this conjecture is false. The intuition for
this is as follows: Since when neither consumer participates, both
auction formats yield the same revenue, and the seller weighs the
probability that both consumers participate (in which case the
unrestricted auction yields the most revenue) with the probability that
a single consumer participates (in which case the restricted auction
yields the most revenue). For p sufficiently small, the latter event
becomes arbitrarily more likely than the former, and as a result the
restricted auction becomes the revenue-maximizing format. Further
intuition can be obtained by comparing the surplus the seller can
extract under the two formats. When both resellers are present in the
restricted auction, the seller extracts the full surplus from the market
(minus the marketing cost). An auction in which a single consumer
participates has the worst possible surplus extraction properties from
the point of view of the seller: He obtains zero revenue. Therefore, the
restricted auction is preferred by the seller when the marketing cost is
small, the probability of reseller participation high, and participation
of consumers low, because such an auction has superior surplus
extraction properties under such conditions. Furthermore, when the
probability of reseller participation is equal to 1, the restricted
auction is almost always preferred by the seller, in the sense that it
generates higher revenue for all "reasonable" values of the
marketing cost.
Note that results analogous to those in Proposition 1 do not exist
for the probability of reseller participation, q, and the marketing
cost, c. That is, it is not true that no matter what p and q are, there
exists some value of c at which the seller would prefer the restricted
auction. This is somewhat intuitive: If the probability of consumer
participation is near 1 and the probability of reseller participation is
near zero, a seller would never want to use a restricted auction even if
c is very low. Similarly, it is not true that no matter what p and c are
there exists some q so that the seller would prefer to use the
restricted auction.
An easy way to demonstrate these results is to observe Figures 1
and 2. (9) Figure 1 plots, for various values of c, the values of p and
q for which the restricted auction yields the same revenue as the
unrestricted auction. The area below each line corresponds to the region
where, for that particular value of c, the restricted auction yields
higher expected revenue than does the unrestricted auction. It can be
readily seen that for, say, p = 0.8 and = 0.75 there exists no q for
which the restricted auction is preferred to the unrestricted one.
Figure 2 plots, for various values of q, the values of p and c. for
which the restricted auction yields the same revenue as the unrestricted
one. The area below each line corresponds to the region for which the
restricted auction yields higher expected revenue than the unrestricted
one. It can be readily seen that for p = 0.5 and q = 0.5 there exists no
for which the restricted auction yields more revenue than the
unrestricted one.
5. Welfare Implications
Preventing consumers from bidding in the seller's auction
means that, if either reseller participates, then the item will for sure
be eventually awarded to the highest valuation consumer. If consumers
are allowed to bid then it is possible that the consumer who purchases
the item is not the highest valuation consumer. (10) On the other hand,
the cost of preventing the consumers from bidding is that the marketing
cost, c, will be incurred more often, and that, if neither reseller
participates, the item goes unsold. The socially optimal choice of
auction format, then, depends on the difference between the valuations
of the highest and lowest valuation consumer, the probabilities of
consumer and reseller participation, and the value of the marketing
cost.
We now turn to the formal analysis of the welfare ranking of the
two auction mechanisms. In the restricted auction the presence of one or
both intermediaries will ensure that the item will ultimately be bought
by the highest valuation consumer. The winning intermediary will incur
the marketing cost equal to c. Therefore, the expected social surplus
from the restricted auction is equal to:
[W.sub.r] [1 - [(1 - q).sup.2]][E{max([v.sub.i])} - c].
In the unrestricted auction, the expected social surplus is equal
to
[W.sub.u] = [(1 - p).sup.2][W.sub.r] + 2p(l - p)E{[v.sub.i]} +
[p.sup.2]E{max([v.sub.i])}.
The first term corresponds to the surplus if no consumer shows up
in the seller's auction, the second term corresponds to the surplus
if a single consumer shows up, and the last term corresponds to the case
in which both consumers show up. In the rest of this discussion it will
be helpful to define [rho] as the ratio of the expected value of the
highest valuation over the expected value of the lowest valuation:
[rho] = E{max([v.sub.i])}/E{min([v.sub.i])}
which can take values in the open interval (l,[infinity]).
Proposition 2 below gives the critical probability for which, when it
exists, the social surplus is the same for both auction mechanisms.
PROPOSITION 2. Let p be defined as:
p = 1 + [1 - [(1 - q).sup.2]]([rho] - c) - [rho]/[1 - [(1 -
q).sup.2]]([rho] - c) - 1
where c is the normalized marketing cost, q is the probability of
reseller participation, and [rho] is the ratio of expected value of the
highest to the second-highest valuation. Suppose that for some values of
the parameters c, q, and [rho], p [member of] (0,1). Then at those
parameter values, the social surplus obtained under the restricted
format equals that obtained unrestricted format. Furthermore, for
consumer participation probabilities p > p the unrestricted format
yields higher social surplus than the restricted format, whereas the
converse is true for p < p .
Note that p depends on [rho], whereas [p.sup.*] does not. This
makes sense since revenues in a second-price auction depend on the value
of the second-highest valuation. Welfare, however, depends on the
highest valuation. The bigger the difference between the expected values
of the highest and the second-highest consumer valuations, the more
important it becomes, from the social surplus point of view, that both
consumers have a chance to bid for the item. Therefore, for higher
values of [rho] the restricted auction will be socially optimal even for
relatively high values of p. This, along with other properties of this
critical probability, are summarized in Corollary 1 below.
COROLLARY 1. p is (i) increasing in the dispersion of bidder
valuations, (ii) decreasing in the value of the (normalized) cost, (iii)
increasing in the probability of consumer participation, and (iv)
asymptotes, as [rho] goes to infinity, to [p.sub.max], where
[p.sub.max] = 1 - [(1 - q).sup.2]/1 - [(1 - q).sup.2].
Part (i) of Corollary 1 formalizes the intuition discussed above.
Parts (ii) and (iii) indicate that p relates to changes in normalized
marketing costs and the probability of intermediary participation in
qualitatively the same way as [p.sup.*]. Finally, part (iv) indicates
that there is a limiting value of the critical probability as [rho] goes
to infinity, and this limiting probability depends only on the
probability of intermediary participation. This also makes intuitive
sense; as [rho] goes to infinity only the probability that the item goes
to the highest valuation consumer matters. In fact, it can be shown
that, in the limit, the socially optimal auction format is the one that
maximizes this probability (and is, therefore, independent of the
marketing cost and the probability of consumer participation).
We now turn to the comparison of p and [p.sup.*]. This is best done
by plotting the relevant probabilities in the same graph. At first, this
seems impossible since p depends on [rho] in addition to q and c.
However, Corollary 1 indicates that p is monotonically increasing in
[rho] and asymptotes to a particular function as p goes to infinity. One
can also observe that when [rho] is low enough, p goes to zero. (11)
This suggests the following strategy for constructing a figure: Plot
[p.sub.max] against q. Clearly, it is never socially optimal to exclude
the consumers when the probability of consumer participation exceeds
[p.sub.max]. For p < [p.sub.max] it will be socially optimal to
exclude the consumer for sufficiently low values of p, that is, when the
variance of consumer valuations is relatively low.
Figure 3 plots [p.sub.max] p, and [p.sup.*] for [rho] = 2, and c =
0.25. It can be readily seen that depending on the value of q and p we
might have any of the four possible combinations of socially optimal and
revenue-maximizing policies. That is, it is possible that the restricted
auction yields (i) higher social surplus and revenue, (ii) lower surplus
and revenue, (iii) higher surplus but lower revenue, and (iv) lower
surplus but higher revenue. This important result is summarized in the
following proposition.
PROPOSITION 3. The revenue ranking of the two auction formats does
not necessarily coincide with the socially optimal ranking. In
particular, the restricted auction may yield (i) higher social surplus
and revenue, (ii) lower surplus and revenue, (iii) higher surplus but
lower revenue, and (iv) lower surplus but higher revenue.
Note that higher values of p make the restricted auction more
desirable from the social point of view. This is because, as mentioned
above, for big relative differences between the highest and
second-highest valuation, it is more important that both consumers have
a chance to bid on the item. It is worth pointing out that, as Figure 4
shows, even if q = 1, we can get all four possible combinations of
optimal policies for different values of [rho].
It is important to contrast the results of this paper with those in
Ausubel and Crampton (1998). They show that if the seller cannot
restrict supply and prevent resale, the revenue-maximizing auction
format is also efficient (it maximizes social welfare) when there is
costless consumer-to-consumer resale. [But also see Zheng (2000) for an
alternative treatment.] In our framework, the revenue- and
welfare-maximizing auction formats would not necessarily coincide even
if the participating consumer could costlessly resell the item to the
nonparticipating consumer. This is because, unlike in Ausubel and
Crampton (1998), our model incorporates (by assumption) an exogenous
"supply restriction:" Not all consumers participate in the
seller's auction.
6. Extensions to the Benchmark Model
Consumer Market of Arbitrary Size
The stylized model described in the preceding sections limits the
number of consumers to a maximum of two. Such a restriction allows us to
obtain closed-form solutions for the conditions under which a restricted
auction is revenue maximizing. It also allows us to evaluate the welfare
consequences of seller's choice of auction format and demonstrate
the conflict between revenue and welfare maximization. Finally,
restricting the retail market size to only two consumers makes it
possible to determine how changes in the market environment affect the
revenue-maximizing and welfare-maximizing choices of auction format.
In this section we demonstrate that the main results of the paper
remain valid, in a qualitative sense, even when the retail market
consists of an arbitrary number, N, of consumers. This is stated
formally below.
PROPOSITION 4. Consider a market that consists of (i) N > 2
consumers, each one of which independently participates in the
seller's auction with probability p. and (ii) two resellers, each
one of which independently participates in the seller's auction
with probability q [member of] [[q.sub.crit](N, c), 1], where 0 <
[q.sub.crit](N, c), < 1. Let the marketing cost of resellers, c, be
positive but sufficiently low so that the seller obtains positive
revenue from the restricted auction. Then, there exists some critical
probability of consumer participation [p.sup.*] [member of] (0,1) such
that for p < [p.sup.*] the seller would prefer to exclude the
consumers from the auction.
Notice that when there are more than two consumers in the market, a
sufficiently low probability that each of them participates in the
seller auction is not enough for the restricted auction to yield a
higher revenue than the unrestricted auction. It is also required that
the resellers participate with a sufficiently high probability. The
details of the proof are tedious and are relegated to the Appendix, in
which we also provide the expression for [q.sub.crit]((N, c). However,
an outline of the main argument is instructive. Let K denote the number
of consumers that participate in the seller auction in a particular
realization of this market. We first observe that when no consumer
participates (i.e., K = 0), the restricted and unrestricted auctions
yield the same revenue. We then show that when only a single consumer
participates in the seller's auction (i.e., K = 1) and each of the
two resellers participates with probability higher than [q.sub.crit]
where 1 > [q.sub.crit] > 0, the seller prefers to forbid that
consumer from bidding for all positive values of the marketing cost. The
preferences for the restricted auction is weak when it yields zero
revenue. We finally show that as the probability of consumer
participation, p, decreases, the probability that there are two or more
participating consumers goes to zero faster than the probability that
there is only one participating consumer. Indeed, the ratio of these two
probabilities goes to zero in the limit. Since the difference in the
revenue of the two auction formats is finite for all K, it follows that
for all values of p below some positive threshold the seller would
prefer the restricted auction to the unrestricted auction. Essentially,
Proposition 4 works by shrinking p to compensate for an increase in the
market size. (12)
We have derived this result without the explicit calculation of
optimal bidder strategies for arbitrary K. Such a
"brute-force" calculation would present two complications: The
first one is conceptual. Suppose there are N > 2 consumers, K > 1
of which participate in the seller's auction. A brute-force
calculation of the optimal strategy of the participating consumers
requires, as a first step, the calculation of the surplus that the
consumer with the highest valuation among them would obtain if he lost
the item to a dealer and were to compete for it in the retail market.
This surplus depends on whether or not the consumer with the
second-highest valuation (among the K participating consumers) would
return to compete for the item in the retail market. Formally, he is
indifferent between competing and not competing as his payoff is zero in
both cases. (13) Therefore, one would need to consider both
possibilities. The second complication of a brute-force analysis is that
one cannot obtain a closed-form expressio n for the "critical"
participation probability of the consumers that would make a seller
prefer to prevent their participation in his auction. Our approach
sidesteps these difficulties and allows us to demonstrate the existence
of such a critical probability, even though its complete
characterization is not possible in the N > 2 case.
Other Extensions
In the basic model the probability of participation is exogenous.
Consumers participate in the seller's auction with probability less
than 1 because the seller was assumed to lack the marketing technology
to inform all consumers that there was a sale taking place. The
resellers possess a specialized marketing technology and could, at a
cost, access both consumers with probability one. This treatment views
the consumers as being passive receivers of marketing information. An
alternative would be to endogenize the consumer search for information
by postulating that the consumers can choose to be informed about the
presence of the seller's auction by incurring a search cost. One
can show that probabilistic consumer entry into the seller's
auction can arise endogenously. Furthermore, when the distribution of
bidder values exhibits only moderate dispersion, the symmetric mixed
strategy equilibrium is not pareto dominated by any pure strategy
equilibrium of the entry game. (14)
This paper purposefully ignores any heterogeneity in reseller
marketing costs. As a result the resellers obtain positive profits only
when one of them happens not to compete in the seller's auction.
The assumption of marketing cost homogeneity is made primarily for
simplicity. Introducing cost heterogeneity would have the effect of
shifting surplus from the seller to the resellers by lessening reseller
competition. However, it is clear that the results will not change
qualitatively even if one allows for cost heterogeneity, provided that
this heterogeneity is not excessive: The restricted auction revenue
would decline by more than the unrestricted auction revenue, but the
former would still exceed the latter for sufficiently low probability of
consumer participation.
A concern arising from the assumption of cost homogeneity is that
it facilitates reseller collusion. The resellers could agree not to bid
aggressively so as to earn positive profits even when both are present.
Instead, they could agree to bid up to a predetermined price and have
the item be awarded to one of them at random. Neither of the two
resellers would have an incentive to break such a collusive agreement:
In the event that one of them raises his bid above the predetermined
price, the other reseller would have a dominant strategy to also raise
his bid, resulting in zero surplus for the defecting reseller. Formally,
we do not consider the possibility of collusion but rather consider
purely noncooperative equilibria. We note, however, that reseller
collusion would not change the qualitative nature of the results
provided that the seller can post a reserve. Indeed, as we discuss
below, the restricted auction can yield higher revenue than the
unrestricted auction (in same cases) even when the seller and res ellers
can post optimal reserves. The auction with reserve is collusion proof:
The seller's reserve is set at the reservation value of the
resellers and, therefore, there is no scope for profitable collusion.
Less formally, the concern about collusive equilibria (in the absence of
a reserve) would be mitigated by the introduction of reseller
heterogeneity. As discussed above, such heterogeneity would not alter
the qualitative nature of the results and is only omitted for clarity.
With the introduction of reseller heterogeneity the restricted auction
would be no more susceptible to collusive behavior than any other
auction studied in the literature.
In the basic model we did not consider a reserve by either the
seller or the resellers. In doing so we follow a large part of the
theoretical literature. Ignoring a positive reserve is often meant to
reflect the institutional fact that many auctions are lacking of a
serious reserve. It is also meant to reflect the commitment of many
sellers to sell, a commitment that often arises endogenously as part of
an optimal strategy. (15) Nevertheless, one can show that allowing for a
positive reserve, though complicating the analysis substantially (in
part because the reseller can now use any information he obtains in the
seller's auction to set the reserve in his auction), does not alter
the main result of the paper: There are still conditions under which the
seller prefers to prohibit the participation of consumers in the
auction.
Finally, the main result of this paper is likely to also hold if
first-price auctions were used. Recall that the main driving force of
the results comes from the fact that the resellers bid less aggressively
in an auction in which the consumers are present because winning is
"bad" news about the valuation of the participating consumers.
If anything, we expect the resellers to bid even more cautiously in a
first-price environment since in such an environment they cannot observe the consumers' bidding behavior and thus update their estimates of
the resale value of the item. However, complete analysis of the game
with first-price auctions is too complicated for the following reasons:
First, the presence of a consumer in the seller's auction yields an
asymmetry between the two consumers in the reseller auction (in the
event that the resellers win the seller auctions). Solving for the
equilibrium in asymmetric first-price auction is an exceptionally
difficult exercise even when one considers particular distributio ns.
Second, the nature of the equilibrium strategies depends crucially on
features that are not important in an English auction. For example, it
would now be important for the consumer who fails to participate in the
first auction to know whether another consumer had participated in the
seller's auction and failed to win the item.
7. Conclusion
The central result of this paper is to show (in the context of a
private values environment) that it can be beneficial for a seller to
exclude final consumers from an auction when there is a potential set of
intermediaries that, upon securing the item, can gain access to an even
bigger market of consumers. This exclusion can sometime also be socially
optimal. However, it is possible that excluding consumers from the
auction is socially optimal but not revenue maximizing.
Appendix
PROOF OF PROPOSITION 1. The revenue from the restricted auction is
greater than the revenue from the unrestricted auction if
[q.sup.2][E{min([v.sub.i])} - c] > [p.sup.2]E{min([v.sub.i])} +
[(1 - p).sup.2][q.sup.2][E{min([v.sub.i])} - c].
Canceling out terms, simplifying, and factoring out p, we can
rewrite the above inequality as
0 > p[E{min([v.sub.i])} + [q.sup.2](E{min([v.sub.i])} - c)] -
2[q.sup.2][E{min([v.sub.i])} - c].
Given that E{min([v.sub.i])} > c for the intermediaries to
participate in any auction, we have:
p < [2q.sup.2](E{min([v.sub.i])} - c)/E{min([v.sub.i])} +
[q.sup.2][E{min([v.sub.i])} - c].
The fraction is greater than 0 as both the numerator and
denominator are positive. Furthermore, since E{min([v.sub.i])} >
[q.sup.2][E{min([v.sub.i])} - c], the fraction is bounded above by 1.
Dividing and denominator by E{min([v.sub.i])} yields the expression for
[p.sup.*]. Differentiating [p.sup.*] with respect to q we have:
d[p.sup.*]/dq = 4q1 - c/[[1 + [q.sup.2](1 - c)].sup.2] > 0.
Finally, differentiating [p.sup.*] with respect to c we get:
d[p.sup.*]/dc = -2[q.sup.2]/[[1 + [q.sup.2](1 - c)].sup.2] < 0
QED.
PROOF OF PROPOSITION 2. Note that since we have two draws from the
distribution we can write
E{[v.sub.i]} = E{max([v.sub.i])} + E{min([v.sub.i])}/2.
Then, the difference, [W.sub.u] - [W.sub.r], in the social surplus
between the two formats, can be written as
[[(1 - p).sup.2] - 1][W.sub.r] + 2p(1 - p)E{max([v.sub.i])} +
E{min([v.sub.i])}/2 + [p.sup.2]E{max([v.sub.i])}.
Suppose that there exists a value of p, p [member of] (0,1) such
that [W.sub.u] - [W.sub.r] = 0. Then, substituting the expression for
[W.sub.r], solving for p and simplifying yields
[FORMULA NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
[FORMULA NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
For the critical probability to be in the (0,1) interval, the
denominator and the numerator of the fraction in the right-hand side must be of different signs. Because the numerator is smaller than the
denominator, this implies that the former must be negative and the
latter positive. This also implies, considering the inequality above,
that for p > p the unrestricted auction will create higher social
surplus than the restricted auction. Dividing both the numerator and
denominator by the expected value of the lowest valuation, we finally
get
p = 1 + [1 - [(1 - q).sup.2]](p - c) - p/[1 - [(1 - q).sup.2]](p -
c) - 1
QED.
PROOF COROLLARY 1. (i) Taking the derivative of p with respect to
[rho] yields:
[FORMULA NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
[FORMULA NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
since both the numerator and denominator are positive.
(ii) Dividing through by [rho], the expression for the critical
probability can be rewritten as:
[FORMULA NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
The result follows from taking the limit as [rho] goes to infinity
and simplifying the numerator.
(iii) Taking the derivative of p with respect to c we have:
[FORMULA NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
This is negative since both terms are negative. [Recall that the
denominator of the first fraction is positive and the numerator of the
second fraction is negative for p [member of] (0, 1).]
(iv) Taking the derivative with respect to q we get
[FORMULA NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Factoring out the first term we have
[FORMULA NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Both terms of the product are positive; therefore, the critical
probability is increasing in the probability of reseller participation.
[Recall that the denominator of the first fraction is positive and the
numerator of the second fraction is negative for p [member of] (0, 1).
Also, [rho] > I, whereas c < 1.] QED.
PROOF OF PROPOSITION 4. As a first step we consider a particular
realization of the seller's auction in which only one of N
consumers participates. In other words, we, for the moment, condition on
the event that a single consumer shows up at the seller's auction.
Seller's revenue for both the restricted and unrestricted auction
formats depends on the size of the market, N, the marketing cost, c, and
on the number of resellers that participate, M. Denote by
[R.sup.S.sub.r](N, M, c) and [R.sup.S.sub.u](N, M, c) the seller's
revenue from the restricted and unrestricted auctions, respectively.
Then, the expected revenue from the restricted auction exceeds that of
the unrestricted auction if
[q.sup.2][R.sup.S.sub.r](N, w, c) > [q.sup.2][R.sub.S.sub.u[(N,
2, c)] + 2q(1 - q)[R.sup.S.sub.u](N, 1, c)
where the expectation has been taken over the participation of the
resellers. Notice that in the restricted auction the seller obtains
positive revenue only when both resellers participate (as there are no
consumers bidding in the auction). In the unrestricted auction the
seller obtains positive revenue if at least one reseller participates
(as there is also one consumer bidding in the auction).
The above inequality can be rewritten as
[q.sup.2][[R.sup.S.sub.r](N, 2, c) - [R.sup.S.sub.u](N, 2, c)] >
2q(1 - q)[R.sup.S.sub.u](N, 1, c).
Proposition 6 of Bose and Deltas (1999) shows that the expression
in the brackets of the left-hand side of the above expression is
non-negative. It is guaranteed to be positive if the revenue from either
auction format is positive and c > 0, that is, it is positive for the
range of marketing costs that we consider here. Simplifying the above
inequality and solving for q we obtain
[FORMULA NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Notice that the right-hand side of the above inequality, henceforth denoted by [q.sub.crit](n, c), is a non-negative number that is strictly
less than 1. Therefore, if a single consumer participates
(deterministically) in the seller's auction, the seller would
prefer to prohibit this consumer from participating if the probability
of reseller participation exceeds [q.sub.crit](N, c).We will next show
that when q >[q.sub.crit](N, c), there exists a p* such that for any
p < p* the seller prefers to sell by the restricted auction. We
generalize the notation: Denote by [R.sup.S.sub.u](N, M, c, K) the
revenue of the unrestricted auction in the event that K Out of N
consumers participate in the seller's auction. Next, observe that
for any finite N the revenue of the restricted and unrestricted auctions
is finite. Therefore, the difference in the revenue between the two
formats is also finite. Now, define
X = [E.sub.u][[R.sup.S.sub.r](N, M, c)] -
[E.sub.M][[R.sup.S.sub.u](N, M, c, 1)]
where the expectation is taken over the number of participating
resellers, M. It follows from the first part of the proof that X>0.
Next define
Y = [max.sub.K] [E.sub.M][[R.sup.S.sub.r](N, M, c)] -
[E.sub.M][[R.sup.S.sub.u](N, M, c, K)].
A sufficient condition for the seller to prefer the restricted
auction is
[E.sub.K]{[E.sub.M][[R.sup.S.sub.r](N, M, c)] -
[E.sub.M][[R.sup.S.sub.u](N, M, c, K)]} > 0.
Observe that when K = 0 the restricted and unrestricted auctions
are equivalent. Therefore, a sufficient condition for the above
inequality to be satisfied is
[FORMULA NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
We will show that this inequality is satisfied for sufficiently low
values of p, which will demonstrate the result in Proposition 4. In
particular, we will demonstrate that the right-hand side of the above
inequality has a limit of zero as p goes to zero, which ensures (since
the right-hand side is continuous in p) that there exists a p* such that
for all p < p* the restricted auction is preferred. First, observe
that both the numerator and the denominator of the fraction in the
righthand side of the above inequality go to zero as p goes to zero.
Then, using L'Hopital's Rule we have
[FORMULA NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
= N - N + 0/N - 0 = 0.
This completes the proof. QED.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Received April 2000; accepted July 2001.
(1.) There is also a strand of literature that partitions bidders
on the basis of the information they possess and their ability to
process it (e.g., Engelbrecht-Wiggans, Milgrom, and Weber 1983; Deltas
and Engelbrecht-Wjggans 2001). These models consider a static pure
common values framework. An explicit modeling of resale that constitutes
an important aspect of our model is absent from them.
(2.) One might be inclined to believe that the intermediaries,
being professionals, will be aware that the auction is taking place and
will attend with probability 1. However, intermediaries may be
"capacity constrained", that is, be already fully occupied
disposing other assets in their possession and be unwilling to purchase
other assets. Under this interpretation, the probability that an
intermediary participates is equal to the probability that he has an
interest in purchasing and reselling this particular item. By allowing
for this more general case, we show that our results do not depend on
the certainty of the intermediaries' participation.
(3.) Note that the item never goes unsold in the special case when
q = 1.
(4.) In Internet auctions, for instance, pasting of a bidder's
history and feedback ratings give an indication about whether a bidder
is likely to be an occasional consumer or a dealer. Nevertheless, we
believe that one could obtain similar results in (more complicated)
models in which the bidders do not know with certainty the identity of
their competitors: Resellers are likely to bid less aggressively in the
unrestricted auction as long as some of their competitors are likely to
be final consumers, regardless of whether the resellers know which among
their competitors are these final consumers.
(5.) For example, even though the winner of an item in an Internet
auction could, in principle, turn around and sell that item in the same
site, he is not likely to make a profit by doing so. In fact, the price
of an item typically declines in an immediate resale in the same
Internet site.
(6.) In practice, resellers often do not sell by auction, but
rather use posted prices or negotiations with individual consumers. For
example, vehicles purchased by resellers in wholesale auto auctions are
resold in used car dealerships, and rare books purchased by resellers in
book auctions are resold at antique stores or specialized bookstores. We
assume that the resellers use the same mechanism as the original seller
to isolate the effects arising from differences in their "marketing
technology" rather than any differences in their "selling
technology."
(7.) See section 6 for discussion of an extension with optimally
set reserves.
(8.) Bose and Deltas (1997) provide an example in which restricting
the participation of final consumers in a second-price sealed-bid
auction is also increasing the seller's expected revenue. Since
second-price sealed-bid and English auctions are not isomorphic in the
presence of resellers, this example suggests that the results obtained
here are not specific to the use of the English auction mechanism.
(9.) These statements can be verified analytically by solving for
the critical c and q instead of solving for the critical p.
(10.) This will happen if a single consumer shows up and this
consumer is not the highest valuation consumer.
(11.) From Proposition 2 the expression for p is equal to 1 plus a
fraction that has a negative numerator and positive denominator. As
[rho] becomes smaller the denominator shrinks toward zero. It therefore
follows that the fraction shrinks toward minus one and the critical
probability shrinks toward zero.
(12.) For most distributions, holding p constant while increasing
the size of the market would eventually make a seller prefer the
unrestricted to the restricted auctions.
(13.) One might argue in favor of assuming that he participates
since his possibility of winning the item would be positive if the
highest valuation consumer "trembles" and does not return to
compete for item (say, he drops dead between the two sales). On the
other hand, one might argue in favor of assuming that he does not
participate if participation entails even infinitesimal costs that are
omitted from the formal analysis.
(14.) This approach parallels the work on endogenous entry in
auctions by Levin and Smith (1994), Engelbrecht-Wiggans and Nonnenmacher
(1999), and Deltas and Engelbrecht-Wiggans (2001). However, even with
symmetric entry costs, there also exist asymmetric pure strategy
equilibria. In these equilibria, some bidders enter with probability
one, whereas others enter with probability zero. See McAfee and MeMillan
(1987) and Engelbrecht-Wiggans (1993).
(15.) For instance, Engelbrecht-Wiggans (1993) shows that the
optimal reserve in an auction with endogenous bidder participation
should be sufficiently close to zero so as not to deter any bidder from
participating. Recently, Engelbrecht-Wiggans and Nonnenmacher (1999)
have shown that the commitment to sell is particularly important when
different venues compete for potential bidders.
References
Ausubel, L. M., and P. Cramton. 1998. The optimality of being
efficient. Unpublished paper, University of Maryland.
Bikhchandani, Sushil, and Chi-Fu Huang. 1989. Auctions with resale
markets: An exploratory model of Treasury Bill markets. Review of
Financial Studies 3:311-39.
Bose, Subir, and George Deltas. 1997. A sealed-bid auction with
consumers and middlemen. Unpublished paper, Iowa State University and
University of Illinois.
Bose, Subir, and George Deltas. 1999. Welcoming the middlemen:
Restricting competition in auctions by excluding the consumers. In
Current trends in ecnomics: Theory and applications--Studies in economic
theory 8, edited by C.D. Aliprantis, A. Alkan, and N.C. Yannelis.
Heidelberg: Springer, pp. 119-31.
Bulow, J., and P. Klemperer. 1998. Prices and the winner's
curse. Unpublished paper. Stanford University and Oxford University.
Deltas, George, and Richard Engelbrecht-Wiggans. 2001. Auctions
with an inexpert bidder. Economics Letters 73:35-42.
Engelbrecht-Wiggans, Richard. 1993. Optimal auctions revisited.
Games and Economic Behavior 5:227-39.
Engelbrech-Wiggans, Richard, P. Milgrom, and R. Weber. 1983.
Competitive bidding and propriety information. Journal of Mathematical
Economics 11:161-9.
Engelbrecht-Wiggans, Richard, and T. Nonnenmacher. 1999. A
theoretical basis for 19th-century changes to the port of New York imported goods auction. Explorations in Economic History 36:232-45.
Gupta, Madhurima, and Bernard Lebrun. 1997. A simple model of first
price auction with resale. Unpublished paper, Northwestern University and University of Laval.
Gupta, Madhurima, and Bernard Lebrun. 1999. First price auctions
with resale. Economics Letters 64:181-5.
Haile, Philip A. 1996. Auctions with resale. Unpublished paper,
University of Wisconsin-Madison.
Haile, Philip A. 2000. Partial pooling at the reserve price in
auctions with resale opportunities. Games and Economic Behavior
33:231-48.
Haile, Philip A. 2001. Auctions with resale markets: An application
to U.S. Forest Service timber auctions. American Economic Review
92:399-427.
Haile, Philip A. 2002. Auctions with private uncertainty and resale
opportunities. Journal of Economic Theory. In press. Krishna, Vijay. and
John Morgan. 1997. (Anti-) competitive effects of joint bidding and
bidder restrictions. Unpublished paper, Pennsylvania State University and Princeton University.
Levin, Dan, and James Smith. 1994. Equilibrium in auctions with
entry. American Economic Review 84:585-99.
Lucking-Reiley, David. 2000. Auction in the internet: What's
being auctioned, and how? Journal of Industrial Economics 48:227-52.
McAfee, P., and J. McMillan. 1987. Auctions with entry. Economics
Letters 23:343-7.
Zheng, Charles Z. 2000. An optimal auction when resale cannot be
prohibited. Unpublished paper, Northwestern University.
Subir Bose * and George Deltas +
* Department of Economics, Iowa State University, Ames, IA 50011,
USA; E-mail bose@iastate.edu.
+ Department of Economics, University of Illinois, Champaign, IL
61820, USA; E-mail deltas@uiuc.edu; corresponding author.
We thank Thomas Jeitschko, Preston McAfee, and Martin Perry for
helpful discussion, two anonymous referees for insightful comments, and
Janet Fitch for editorial assistance. The usual caveat applies.