首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月08日 星期五
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:An Exponential Family of Lorenz Curves.
  • 作者:Slottje, Daniel J.
  • 期刊名称:Southern Economic Journal
  • 印刷版ISSN:0038-4038
  • 出版年度:2001
  • 期号:January
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Southern Economic Association
  • 关键词:Economic policy;Family;Lorentz transformation;Lorentz transformations

An Exponential Family of Lorenz Curves.


Slottje, Daniel J.


Jose-Maria Sarabia [*]

Enrique Castillo [+]

Daniel J. Slottje [++]

A new method for building parametric-functional families of Lorenz curves, generated from an initial Lorenz curve (which satisfies some regularity conditions), is presented. The method is applied to the exponential family since they use the exponential Lorenz curves as their generating curves. Several properties of these families are analyzed, including the population function, inequality measures, and Lorenz orderings. Finally, an application is presented for data from various countries. The family is shown to perform well in fitting the data across countries. The results are very robust across data sources.

1. Introduction

The purpose of this paper is to introduce a parametric family of Lorenz curves that are obtained by a general method. In a recent paper, Sarabia, Castillo, and Slottje (1999) (SCS) introduced a method that allowed for the building of hierachies of Lorenz curves when some regularity conditions are satisfied. They introduced the Pareto family, which was found to be a flexible form and which fits actual income distribution data well. This paper introduces another family, the exponential family, which also has interesting characteristics. The exponential family involves more complex estimation with a form that is somewhat less flexible but in return gives a robust performance in fitting actual data across countries, as we will show here. The researcher or policy maker is provided another effective tool in the ongoing effort to quantify, analyze, and understand economic inequality.

The strategy used here is to apply a Lorenz curve hierarchy that contains (as special cases) Lorenz curves derived from this general method. In section 2 we introduce the notation and some necessary background information. The general method is presented in section 3, which starts from an initial Lorenz curve [L.sub.0](p) (which is called the generating curve) and builds a family with an increasing number of parameters. These in turn can be interpreted in terms of elasticities of [L.sub.0](p). Also in section 3 we introduce the exponential family of Lorenz curves and discuss some of its properties as population functions and inequality measures and for undertaking Lorenz orderings. In section 4 we present a method for estimating Lorenz curves and apply it to the two families specified previously. Since the goodness of fit is one important criterion in the evaluation of these (and any) models, we use a method due to Gastwirth (1972) and actually incorporate his procedure into the estimation process, as will b e clear in section 4. An example of an application of our new methodology is presented in section 5. Finally, in section 6 we conclude the paper.

2. Notation and Previous Results

In this section we use the Lorenz curve as defined by Gastwirth (1971). That is,

DEFINITION 1. Given a distribution function F(x) with support in the subset of the positive real numbers and with finite expectation [micro], we define a Lorenz curve as

[L.sub.F](p) = [[micro].sup.-1] [[[integral].sup.p].sub.0] [F.sup.-1](x) dx, 0 [less than or equal to] p [less than or equal to] 1, (1)

where

[F.sup.-1](x) = sup{y: F(y) [less than or equal to] x}.

A characterization of the Lorenz curve that is attributed to Gaffney and Anstis by Pakes (1981) is given by the following theorem:

THEOREM 1. Assume that L(p) is defined and continuous in the interval [0,1] with second derivative L"(p). The function L(p) is a Lorenz curve i.f.f.

L(0) = 0, L(1) = 1, L'([0.sup.+]) [greater than or equal to] 0 for p [epsilon] (0, 1) [L.sup.n](p) [greater than or equal to] 0. (2)

Lorenz curves allow establishing a ranking in a set of distributions functions. If two distribution functions have associated Lorenz curves that do not intersect, then they can be ordered without ambiguity in terms of welfare functions that are symmetric, increasing, and quasiconcave (Atkinson 1970; Dasgupta, Sen, and Sarret 1973; Shorrocks 1983). A distribution function [F.sub.x](x) is said to have less inequality in the Lorenz sense than a distribution function [G.sub.Y](y) if their Lorenz curves [L.sub.F](p) and [L.sub.G](p) satisfy the condition [L.sub.F](p) [greater than or equal to] [L.sub.G](p) for all p, where the sign [greater than] applies for at least one p [epsilon] (0, 1)'. In this case we write X [[less than or equal to].sub.L] Y. From the definition of the Lorenz curve (Eqn. 1), it is evident that the Lorenz partial order is invariant with respect to scale transformations, that is, X [[less than or equal to].sub.L] Y i.f.f. [lambda]X [[less than or equal to].sub.L] vY for all [lambda], v [grea ter than] 0.

THEOREM 2. Let L(p) be a Lorenz curve and consider the transformation

[L.sub.[alpha]](p) = [P.sup.[alpha]]L(p), [alpha] [greater than or equal to] 0. (3)

Then, if [alpha] [greater than or equal to] 1, [L.sub.[alpha]](p) is a Lorenz curve, too. In addition, if 0 [less than or equal to] [alpha] [less than] 1 and [L.sup.m](p) [greater than or equal to] 0, [L.sub.[alpha]](p) is also a Lorenz curve.

THEOREM 3. If L(p) is a Lorenz curve,

[L.sub.[gamma]](p) = L[(p).sup.[gamma]], [gamma] [greater than or equal to] 1 (4)

is a Lorenz curve. Since [L.sub.[gamma]](p) is an increasing convex transform of L(p) and [L.sub.[gamma]](0) = 0 and [L.sub.[gamma]](1) = 1, [L.sub.[gamma]](p) is a Lorenz curve as well. We now present several examples to demonstrate the usefulness of these theorems.

One well-known form of the Lorenz curve is that attributable to Rasche et al. (1980). Other forms are due to Kakwani and Podder (1973) and Kakwani (1980). Rasche et al. (1980) showed that Kakwani's Lorenz curve does not satisfy all the requirements for a Lorenz curve. Using our Theorem 1, we find a modified Lorenz curve:

L(p; a, [beta]) = p - ap[(1 - p).sup.[beta]], 0 [less than or equal to] a [less than or equal to] 1; 0 [less than] [beta] [less than or equal to] 1. (5)

Then, using Theorems 2 and 3, we generate a new family of Lorenz curves:

[L.sub.a,[alpha],[beta],[gamma]] (p) = [p.sup.[alpha]+[gamma]][[1 - a[(1 - p).sup.[beta]]].sup.[gamma]]; 0 [less than or equal to] a [less than or equal to] 1, [alpha] [greater than or equal to] 0, 0 [less than] [beta] [less than or equal to] 1, [gamma] [greater than or equal to] 1. (6)

3. Hierarchical Families of Lorenz Curves

The previous theorems suggest a method for obtaining hierarchical families of Lorenz curves. Towards this aim, we start with an initial generating Lorenz curve [L.sub.0](p) and consider the following parametric hierarchy:

[L.sub.1](p; [alpha]) = [p.sup.[alpha]][L.sub.0](p), ([alpha] [greater than or equal to] 1) or [0 [less than or equal to] [alpha], 1, [[L.sup.m].sub.0](p) [greater than or equal to] 0] (7)

[L.sub.2](p; [gamma]) = [L.sub.0][(p).sup.[gamma]], [gamma] [greater than or equal to] 1 (8)

[L.sub.3](p; [alpha], [gamma]) = [p.sup.[alpha]][L.sub.0][(p).sup.[gamma]], ([alpha], [gamma] [greater than or equal to] 1) or [0 [less than or equal to] [alpha] [less than] 1, [gamma] [greater than or equal to] 1, [[L.sup.m].sub.0](p) [greater than or equal to] 0]. (9)

Families 7 and 8 were obtained using Theorems 2 and 3 and Family 9 arises by combining both results. Note that Families 7 and 8 are ordered with respect to their parameters [alpha] and [gamma]. It is clear that

(a) [L.sub.1] is ordered with respect to [alpha] since if [[alpha].sub.1] [greater than or equal to] [[alpha].sub.2] [greater than] 0, then [L.sub.1](p, [[alpha].sub.1]) [less than or equal to] [L.sub.1](p, [[alpha].sub.2]).

(b) [L.sub.2] is ordered with respect to [gamma] since if [[gamma]..1] [greater than or equal to] [[gamma].sub.2] [greater than] 0, then [L.sub.2](p, [[gamma].sub.1]) [less than or equal to] [L.sub.2](p, [[gamma].sub.2]).

(c) If [L.sub.0](p) = [L.sub.0](p; k) is ordered with respect to parameter k, that is, if [k.sub.1] [less than or equal to] [k.sub.2], we have

[L.sub.0](p; [k.sub.1]) [less than or equal to] [L.sub.0](p; [k.sub.2]). (10)

Then

(i) If [[alpha].sub.1] [greater than or equal to] [[alpha].sub.2], then

[p.sup.[[alpha].sub.1]][L.sub.0](p; [k.sub.1]) [less than or equal to] [p.sup.[a.sub.1]][L.sub.0](p; [k.sub.2]) [less than or equal to] [p.sup.[a.sub.2]][L.sub.0](p; [k.sub.2]; (11)

that is, we have new ordering with respect to [alpha].

(ii) If [[gamma].sub.1] [greater than] [[gamma].sub.2], then

[[L.sup.[[gamma].sub.1]].sub.0](p; [k.sub.1]) [less than or equal to] [[L.sup.[[gamma].sub.1]].sub.0](p; [k.sub.2]) [less than or equal to] [[L.sup.[[gamma].sub.2]].sub.0](p; [k.sub.2]); (12)

that is, we have new ordering with respect to y.

(d) Combining the previous results, we can also obtain a new ordering for family [L.sub.3]. The new parameters that are sequentially incorporated in the hierarchy can be interpreted in terms of the curve elasticities. For example,

[epsilon]([L.sub.3]; p) = [alpha] + [gamma][epsilon]([L.sub.0]; p), (13)

where [epsilon](L; p) represents the elasticity of L.

The Exponential Lorenz Curve Family

The family we discuss is the exponential Lorenz curve family. This family is generated from the initial Exponential Lorenz curve.

[L.sub.0](p; k) = [C.sub.k]([e.sup.kp] - 1), 0 [less than or equal to] p [less than or equal to] 1, (14)

with [[c.sup.-1].sub.k] = [e.sup.k] - 1, which satisfies Theorem 2. This curve is called the exponential Lorenz curve since it is generated from the suitably normalized exponential function g(p; k) = exp(kp), k [greater than] 0, and yields the Lorenz curve [L.sub.0](p, k) = [g(p; k) - g(0; k)]/g(1; k) - g(0; k)]. This curve has been recently proposed by Chotikapanich (1993) and gives excellent fitting results with grouped data. The model [L.sub.0](p, k) includes as a particular case the egalitarian model L(p) = p. This is a limiting case for k going to zero, that is, [L.sub.0](p; k) = p. The model [L.sub.0](p; k) can also be interpreted as a linear convex combination of an infinite set of potential Lorenz curves, [p.sup.i], j = 1, 2, with weights decreasing with i, that is,

[L.sub.0](p; k) = [e.sup.kp] -1/[e.sup.k] -1 = [[[sigma].sup.[infinity]].sub.i=1] [w.sub.i][p.sup.i] (15)

where

[w.sub.i] = [k.sup.i]/i!([e.sup.k] - 1)' [w.sub.i] [greater than or equal to] 0, [[[sigma].sup.[infinity]].sub.i=1] [w.sub.i] = 1. (16)

In some cases the fit is even better than that associated with some biparametric families. Using previous results again, we can consider the hierarchy of exponential Lorenz curves:

[L.sub.1](p; k, [alpha]) = [c.sub.k][p.sup.[alpha]]([e.sup.kp] - 1); k [greater than] 0, [alpha] [greater than or equal to] 0 (17)

[L.sub.2](p; k, [gamma]) = [c.sub.k,[gamma]][([e.sup.kp] - 1).sup.[gamma]]; k [greater than] 0, [gamma] [greater than or equal to] 1 (18)

[L.sub.3](p; k, [alpha], [gamma]) = [c.sub.k,[gamma]][p.sup.[alpha]][([e.sup.kp] - 1).sup.[gamma]]; k [greater than] 0, [alpha] [greater than or equal to] 0, [gamma] [greater than or equal to] 1, (19)

where [c.sub.k,[gamma]] - [([e.sup.k] - 1).sup.-[gamma]].

Population Functions

The quantile functions of the exponential hierarchies are given by

[X.sub.0](p; k, [micro]) = [micro]k[C.sub.k][e.sup.kp] (20)

[X.sub.1](p; k, [alpha][micro]) = [micro][C.sub.k][[alpha][P.sup.[alpha]-1]([e.sup.kp] - 1) + [kp.sup.[alpha]][e.sup.kp]] (21)

[X.sub.2](p; k, [gamma][micro]) = [micro][gamma]k[C.sub.k,[gamma]][e.sup.kp][([e.sup.kp] - 1).sup.[gamma]-1] (22)

[X.sub.3](p; k, [alpha], [gamma], [micro]) = [micro][c.sub.k,[gamma]][[alpha][p.sup.[alpha]-1][([e.sup.kp] - 1).sup.[gamma]] + k[gamma][p.sup.[alpha]][e.sup.kp][([e.sup.kp] - 1).sup.[gamma]-1]]. (23)

In some particular cases we can obtain closed-form expressions for the distribution functions, as with [L.sub.0]. Again we can prove that the distribution function for Equation 20 becomes [F.sub.0](x; k, [micro]) = 0 if x [less than or equal to] [micro]u(k), [F.sub.0](x; k, [micro]) = 1 if x [greater than or equal to] [micro]v(k) and

[F.sub.0](x; k, [micro]) = 1/k log[x/[micro]u(k)] if [micro]u(k) [less than or equal to] x [less than or equal to] [micro]v(k), (24)

where, u(k) = k/([e.sup.k] - 1) and v(k) = k[e.sup.k]/([e.sup.k] - 1).

For the remaining families we also can obtain results. For example, for [L.sub.2] with [gamma] = 2, we obtain

[F.sub.2](x; k, 2, [micro]) = 1/k log[1/2(1 + [square root]1 + 4x/c)] if 0 [less than or equal to] x [less than or equal to] 2v(k)[micro], k [greater than] 0, and

[alpha] [greater than or equal to] 0 c = 2k[micro]/[([e.sup.k] - 1).sup.2] and

[F.sub.2](x; k, 2, [micro]) = 0 if x [less than or equal to] 0 and [F.sub.2](x; k, 2, [micro]) = 1 if x [greater than or equal to] 2v(k)[micro]. (25)

We present some inequality measures that correspond to these Lorenz curves in the Appendix. We now discuss estimation of these models.

4. Estimation

In inequality studies, several types of data are normally utilized: grouped data and micro data. Micro data can consist of a set of individual observations or a set of points on the empirical Lorenz curve, for example, income deciles. The estimation method that is presented here can be used for any of the three types of data. For estimating the parameters of Families 17 to 19, least squares is the most direct method to be applied. In all cases, we need to minimize a nonlinear function of the parameters. This method presents some well-known problems, such as the need for proving the existence of an absolute minimum and the need from initial values of the estimates for the iterative process to converge. We discuss these problems and propose solutions now.

The Proposed Method

The merits of parametric methods, as opposed to nonparametric methods, for the construction of indices and inequality measures for income probability distributions with grouped data have recently been discussed by Slottje (1990). Slottje concludes that the indices should be constructed using the parametric method and then the results checked using a nonparametric method. In this sense, Gastwirth's (1972) Gini bounds are nonparametric constraints that should be satisfied by the Gini index of any parametric family of Lorenz curves.

Consequently, any estimation method for the exponential family should lead to parameter values whose Gini indices satisfy Gastwirth's bounds. The usual estimation method consists of minimizing with respect to [theta] the sum of squares:

[[[sigma].sup.n].sub.i=1] [[[q.sub.i] - L([p.sub.i]; [theta])].sup.2]; [theta] [epsilon] [theta], (26)

where [theta] is the set of feasible parameters. Unfortunately, an estimation method based on Equation 26 does not guarantee a Gini satisfying the Gastwirth bounds. An empirical study on this problem has been done by Schader and Schmid (1994), who arrived at conclusions similar to those in Slottje (1990).

One possible solution to this problem consists of incorporating the Gastwirth bounds directly into the programming problem as one more constraint. Thus, we propose to minimize the function Equation 26 subject to

GL [less than or equal to] 2 [[[integral].sup.1].sub.0] [p - L(p; [theta])] dp [less than or equal to] GU (27)

where GL and GU are the Gastwirth bounds associated with the set of data ([p.sub.i],[q.sub.i]), i - 1,...,n, that is

GL = 1 - [[[sigma].sup.k+1].sub.j=1] ([p.sub.j] - [p.sub.j-1])([q.sub.j] + [q.sub.j-1]),

GU = GL + [m.sup.-1] [[[sigma].sup.k+1].sub.j=1] [([p.sub.j] - [p.sub.j-1]).sup.2]([a.sub.j] - [m.sub.j])([m.sub.j] - [a.sub.j-1])[([a.sub.j] - [a.sub.j-1]).sup.-1]

where [p.sub.0] = [q.sub.0] = 0, [p.sub.k+1] = [q.sub.k+1] = 1[[a.sub.j-1][a.sub.j]], are the limits of the income intervals, [m.sub.j] is the mean income of the interval, and m is the overall mean.

Constraint (Eqn. 27) can be incorporated with other alternative estimation methods, as, for example, that proposed in Castillo, Hadi, and Sarabia (1995, 1998).

5. Some Examples

To illustrate the method proposed here, we apply it to income distribution data on national samples of income recipients across countries. The data are from Shorrocks (1983). The data correspond to figures for cumulated income shares for 19 countries derived from Jain (1975). The 19 countries selected for analysis were chosen because they cover samples with relatively high, middle, and low income groups with varying degrees of inequality.

Using our approach, the Gastwirth lower bounds associated with the different countries are shown in Table 1. As can be seen, the lower bound varies significantly across the countries scrutinized in our study. These should be viewed in light of the overall estimates.

In Tables 2 to 3, we give the parameter estimates and the mean square error (MSE), the mean absolute error (MAE), the maximum absolute error (MAXABS) and the Gini index for each country, where

MSE = [[[sigma].sup.n].sub.i=1] [[q.sub.i], - L[([P.sub.i], k, [alpha], [gamma])].sup.2]/n (28)

is the mean squared error and

MAE = [[[sigma].sup.n].sub.i=1] [absolute val. of [q.sub.i] - L([P.sub.i], k, [alpha], [gamma])]/n (29)

is the mean absolute error. The maximum absolute error is

MAXABS = [max.sub.i=1....,n] [absolute val. of [q.sub.i] - L([p.sub.i]; k, [alpha], [gamma])].(30)

As can be seen in Tables 2 and 3, across all countries, the first model ([L.sub.1]) gives lower MAE, MSE, and MAXABS. The order of magnitude of the coefficients, however, is virtually the same. The differences in the measures of goodness of fit are not different until the fourth or fifth decimal place. In sum, [L.sub.1] appears to be a slightly better fitting model than [L.sub.2]. The Gini coefficients for the [L.sub.1] and [L.sub.2] models are essentially the same in both cases, but the Ginis are slightly higher in [L.sub.2]. In fact, it appears that [L.sub.1] is giving better precision of the model's description of inequality, yet [L.sub.2] yields Gini measures that are more sensitive to inequality. Thus, [L.sub.2] and [L.sub.1] appear to flip-flop across countries with respect to their relative Ginis vis-a-vis their goodness-of-fit measures.

6. Conclusions and Recommendations

In this paper we have introduced a new family of Lorenz curves that are generated from the exponential family. Several parameters are incorporated sequentially, keeping the Lorenz character of the resulting families of curves. Several properties of this family are analyzed, and a general estimation method has been proposed that guarantees the existence of unique estimates. The exponential models appear to be very good approximations to actual income distribution data. The results are robust to different data sets for different countries from various parts of the world. Perhaps the most attractive feature of the proffered estimation method is that it is robust. The only cost of this method is some loss of flexibility.

(*.) Department of Economics, University of Cantabria, Avda. de los Castros s/n, 39005-Santander, Spain

(+.) Department of Applied Mathematics and Computational Sciences, University of Cantabria Avda. de los Castros s/n, 39005-Santander, Spain

(++.) Department of Economics, Southern Methodist University, Dallas, TX 75275, USA; E-mail dslottje@mail.smu. edu; corresponding author.

Paper presented at the American Statistical Association meetings, August 9 to 13, 1998, Dallas, Texas. The authors are grateful to the Direccion General de Investigacion Cientifica y Tecnica (DGICYT) (project PB96-1261) for partial support of this work. Comments by two anonymous referees have greatly improved the paper. The usual caveat holds.

Received June 1998; accepted March 2000.

References

Abramowitz, Moses, and I. A. Stegum. 1970. Handbook of mathematical functions. New York: Dover Publications.

Atkinson, Anthony B. 1970. On the measurement of inequality. Journal of Economic Theory 2:244-63.

Castillo, Enrique, Ali S. Hadi, and Jose-Maria Sarabia. 1995. A method for estimating Lorenz curves. Actas del XXII Congreso Nacional de Estadistica e Investigacion Operativa: 131-2.

Castillo, Enrique, Ali S. Hadi, and Jose-Maria Sarabia. 1998. A method for estimating Lorenz curves. Communications in Statistics, Theory and Methods 27:2037-63.

Chotikapanich, Duankamong. 1993. A comparison of alternative functional forms for the Lorenz curve. Economics Letters 41:129-38.

Dasgupta, P., Amartya K. Sen, and David Starret. 1973. Notes on the measurement of inequality. Journal of Economic Theory 6:180-7.

Gastwirth, Joseph L. 1971. A general definition of the Lorenz curve. Econometrica 39:1037-9.

Gastwirth, Joseph L. 1972. The estimation of the Lorenz curve and Gini index. Review of Economics and Statistics 54: 306-16.

Jain, s. 1975. Size distribution of income. Washington, DC: World Bank Publications.

Kakwani, Nanak C. 1980. On a class of poverty measures. Econometrica 48:437-46.

Kakwani, Nanak C., and Nripesh Podder. 1973. On estimation of Lorenz curves from grouped observations. International Economic Review 14:278-92.

Pakes, Ariel G. 1981. On income distributions and their Lorenz curves. Technical Report, Department of Mathematics, University of Western Australia, Nedlands, WA.

Rasche, R. H., J. Gaffney, A. Koo, and N. Obst. 1980. Functional forms for estimating the Lorenz curve. Econometrica 48:1061-2.

Sarabia, Jose-Maria, Enrique Castillo, and Dan J. Slottje. 1999. An ordered family of Lorenz curves. Journal of Econometrics 91:43-60.

Schader, M., and F. Schmid. 1994. Fitting parametric Lorenz curves to grouped income distributions: A critical note. Empirical Economics 19:361-70.

Shorrocks, Anthony F. 1983. Ranking income distributions. Economica 50:3-17.

Slottje. Dan J. 1990. Using grouped data for constructing inequality indices: Parametric vs. non-parametric methods. Economics Letters 32:193-7.
 Gastwirth Lower Bounds for Different Countries
Country Lower Bound to G
Brazil 0.62105
Columbia 0.54710
Denmark 0.36215
Finland 0.46585
India 0.44925
Indonesia 0.43575
Japan 0.30660
Kenya 0.60635
Malaysia 0.50345
Netherlands 0.44210
New Zealand 0.36580
Norway 0.35740
Panama 0.44085
Sri Lanka 0.40395
Sweden 0.38205
Tanzania 0.52615
Tunisia 0.49645
United Kingdom 0.35790
Uruguay 0.49135
 Goodness-of-Fit Measures and Gini
 Indices Corresponding to Model [L.sub.1]
Country [kappa] MAE MSE MAXABS Gini Index
Brazil 6.11303 0.0672026 0.00670074 0.184059 0.677267
Columbia 4.40909 0.0446958 0.00353165 0.136717 0.571024
Denmark 2.36837 0.0103202 0.00014356 0.0223345 0.36215
Finland 3.27372 0.0184473 0.000568854 0.0520662 0.467785
India 3.23994 0.0499807 0.00423375 0.149348 0.46423
Indonesia 3.15391 0.0633097 0.00652695 0.184605 0.455043
Japan 1.96496 0.0146695 0.000358936 0.0371705 0.308185
Kenya 6.00083 0.0766118 0.00835894 0.202144 0.671678
Malaysia 3.7724 0.0343096 0.00203517 0.102055 0.51691
Netherlands 3.0776 0.023943 0.000997398 0.0704869 0.446732
New Zealand 0.39684 0.0132102 0.000240519 0.0297536 0.3658
Norway 0.33157 0.0150283 0.000283704 0.042860 0.3574
Panama 3.06741 0.0247178 0.00106703 0.0728711 0.445611
Sri Lanka 2.73551 0.0172091 0.000491571 0.0462995 0.407594
Sweden 2.5308 0.0146085 0.000328096 0.03686 0.382693
Tanzania 4.32115 0.0635603 0.00610748 0.173073 0.564087
Tunisia 3.72563 0.0276664 0.00104612 0.0608432 0.512564
United Kingdom 2.34177 0.0215614 0.000809624 0.0627512 0.35872
Uruguay 3.57844 0.0159616 0.000408415 0.0394658 0.498539
 Goodness-of-Fit Measures and Gini
 Indices Corresponding to Model [L.sub.1]
Country [kappa] [gamma] MAE MSE MAXABS Gini Index
Brazil 6.11300 1.00019 0.0672139 0.00670082 0.184018 0.677324
Columbia 4.41021 1.00000 0.0447035 0.00353165 0.136675 0.571111
Denmark 1.96676 1.12001 0.0107581 0.00016163 0.025593 0.363753
Finland 3.26489 1.00201 0.0184466 0.00056943 0.052112 0.467757
India 3.24050 1.00000 0.0499908 0.00423375 0.149326 0.464290
Indonesia 3.15433 1.00000 0.0633176 0.00652695 0.184589 0.455088
Japan 0.08593 1.89580 0.0342035 0.00136918 0.054208 0.323708
Kenya 6.00158 1.00004 0.0766221 0.00835896 0.202107 0.671729
Malaysia 3.77466 1.00004 0.0343362 0.00203522 0.101962 0.517135
Netherlands 3.07786 1.00003 0.0239475 0.00099742 0.070474 0.446772
New Zealand 1.47461 1.30012 0.0137192 0.00030297 0.035858 0.365800
Norway 1.44674 1.28799 0.0141477 0.00029580 0.035039 0.357400
Panama 3.06767 1.00001 0.0247216 0.00106704 0.072860 0.445644
Sri Lanka 2.73138 1.00148 0.0172602 0.0049237 0.046265 0.407800
Sweden 2.52290 1.00157 0.0145834 0.00032861 0.036961 0.382464
Tanzania 4.32084 1.00000 0.0635580 0.00610748 0.173085 0.564062
Tunisia 3.72630 1.00016 0.0276857 0.00104624 0.060793 0.512692
United Kingdom 2.34042 1.00086 0.0215970 0.00081023 0.062703 0.358960
Uruguay 3.57863 1.00009 0.0159672 0.00040845 0.039445 0.498597


Appendix

The Gini index of the exponential hierarchy can be expressed in terms of the confluent hypergeometric function, whose integral representation is given by (b [greater than] a):

[gamma](b - a)[gamma](a)/[gamma](b) M(a, b, z) = [[[integral].sup.1].sub.0] [e.sup.u][t.sup.a-1][(1 - t).sup.b-a-1] dt. (A.1)

[gamma](b - a)[gamma](a)/[gamma](b) M(a, b, z) = [[[integral].sup.1].sub.0] [e.sup.u][t.sup.a-1][(1 - t).sup.b-a-t]dt. (A.1)

The most important properties of the confluent hypergeometric can be found in Abramowitz and Stegum (1970, p. 503). We have the following theorem.

THEOREM Al. The Gini indices of the exponential hierarchy are given by

[G.sub.0](K) = k([e.sup.k] + 1) - 2([e.sup.k] - 1)/k([e.sup.k] - 1) (A.2)

[G.sub.1](k, [alpha]) = 1 - 2 [k.sup.c]/[alpha] + 1 [M([alpha] + 1, [alpha] + 2, k) - ] (A.3)

[G.sub.2](k, [gamma]) = 1 - 2[c.sub.k,[gamma]] [[[sigma].sup.[infinity]].sub.i=0] [gamma](i - [gamma])[[e.sup.k([gamma]-i)] - 1]/[gamma](i + l)[gamma](-[gamma])k([gamma] - i) (A.4)

[G.sub.3](k, [alpha], [gamma]) = 1 - 2[c.sub.k,[gamma]] [[[sigma].sup.[infinity]].sub.i=0] [gamma](i - [gamma])/[gamma](i + l)[gamma](-[gamma]) M[[alpha] + 1, [alpha] + 2, k([gamma] - i)], (A.5)

where B( ) and [gamma]( ) are the well-known beta and gamma functions.

PROOF, The index [G.sub.0](k) is given by Chotikapanich (1993). For [G.sub.1](k, [alpha]), we have

[G.sub.1](k, [alpha]) = 1 - 2[c.sub.k] [[[integral].sup.1].sub.0] ([p.sup.a][e.sup.kp] - [p.sup.a]) dp = 1 - 2[c.sub.k] [[gamma](1)[gamma]([alpha] + 1)/[gamma]([alpha] + 2)M([alpha] + 1, [alpha] + 2, k) - 1/[alpha] + 1]

= 1 - 2[k.sup.c]/[alpha] + 1][M([alpha] + 1, [alpha] + 2, k) - 1],

and for the index [G.sub.2], we can write

[L.sub.2](p; k, [gamma]) = [([c.sub.k,[gamma]][e.sup.kp[gamma]]).sup.[gamma]] = [c.sub.k,[gamma]][e.sup.kp[gamma]][(1 - [e.sup.-kp]).sup.[gamma]] [[[sigma].sup.[infinity]].sub.i=0] [gamma](i - [gamma])/[gamma](i + 1)[gamma](-[gamma])[e.sup.-kpi],

and integrating, term by term, we obtain the index [G.sub.2]. Finally, the index [G.sub.3] can be obtained in a similar form. QED.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有