Public Goods, Tax Policies, and Unemployment in LDCs.
Michael, Michael S.
Panos Hatzipanayotou [*]
Michael S. Michael [+]
We build a general equilibrium model of a small open economy
characterized by unemployment and producing two privately traded goods
and one nontraded public consumption good. The provision of public good
is financed with an income tax or an excise tax on the manufactured good
or an import tariff. Within this framework, the paper examines the
effects of such policies on the country's unemployment ratio and
welfare, and it derives the efficiency rules for public good provision
for each policy instrument. It shows, among other things, that the
private marginal cost of the public good always overstates its social
marginal cost in the case of income taxes and may overstate it in the
case of an excise tax on the manufactured good or a tariff even if the
taxed good and the public good are substitutes in consumption.
1. Introduction
Traditionally, an analytically convenient and widely used
assumption in the international trade and development economics
literature has been that of lump-sum distribution of direct (e.g.,
income) or indirect (e.g., consumption, tariff) tax revenue when various
policy implications of such instruments (e.g., terms of trade or welfare
effects) were to be examined. This analytical shortcut, however, hardly
ever constitutes a real-world practice either in rich developed or in
poorer developing economies.
On the other hand, another extensive branch of economics, the
public finance literature, has adopted a more realistic approach
regarding the economic activity of a government. A government is viewed,
among other things, as a provider of public (collective) consumption
goods and/or of public inputs that enhance the productive capacity of
the private sector. Being so, it can use revenues from nondistortionary
(e.g., lump-sum) taxes or distortionary (e.g., consumption) taxes to
finance the provision of such goods and services. Within this public
finance context, a long-standing proposition states that when
nondistortionary taxes are used to finance the provision of a public
good, the first-best efficiency rule requires that the sum of the
marginal rates of substitution (i.e., the social marginal benefit) equal
the marginal rate of transformation (i.e., the social, marginal cost)
(e.g., see Samuelson 1954). When distortionary taxes are used to finance
the provision of the public good, Pigou (1947) argued that th e social
marginal cost exceeds the private marginal cost because of the induced indirect cost from raising tax revenue through distortionary taxation.
Stiglitz and Dasgupta (1971), Atkinson and Stern (1974), and Wildasin
(1984), among others, demonstrate that in certain cases (e.g., when the
taxed and the public goods are complements in consumption), Pigou's
argument fails to hold and the social cost may fall short of the private
marginal cost. [1]
Because of its more realistic appeal, this public finance approach
to the use of tax revenue has been subsequently adopted by the relevant
international trade and development economics literature. Recently, the
efficiency rule for public good provision has been examined in the
context of a small open economy by, among others, Feehan (1988) when
tariff revenue finances the provision of the public good in an economy
producing two traded goods and a nontraded public consumption good.
Michael and Hatzipanayotou (1995) examine the same issue and derive the
formulae for the optimal tax rates on traded or nontraded goods in an
economy producing many traded and nontraded goods and where consumption
tax revenue finances the provision of the public good. Michael and
Hatzipanayotou (1997) demonstrate the failure of the first-best
efficiency rule when lump-sum taxes are used to finance the provision of
a public good in a small open economy in the presence of trade
restrictions (i.e., a tariff or a VER).
Two features in the above reviewed studies of the international
trade/development economics and public finance literature motivate the
present paper. First, all these studies derive the efficiency rule for
public good provision in the context of a small open or closed economy
with full employment. Unemployment, however, to a lesser or to a larger
extent remains a structural feature of many developed or developing
economies. From an analytical standpoint, the existence of such a
distortion may alter both the optimal tax formulae and the efficiency
rule for public good provision. Second, the above reviewed literature
considers the case where a government uses a single policy instrument
(e.g., lump-sum taxes, income taxes, tariffs) to finance the provision
of the public good. More than often, however, governments may have at
their disposal several tax instruments that they can simultaneously use
in order to raise revenue for financing the provision of public
consumption goods.
Capitalizing on these two realizations, the present paper
constructs a general equilibrium trade model of a small open developing
economy characterized by Harris-Todaro (1970) (HT) type of unemployment
and producing two privately traded (an exported and an imported) goods
and a nontraded pure (i.e., noncongestible) public consumption good. We
assume that in order to finance the provision of the public good, the
government raises tax revenue through the imposition of separately an
income tax, an excise tax on the manufactured good, or an import tariff.
Within this context, we examine the effects of each policy regime on
welfare, and we derive the efficiency rule for public good provision in
each case. We show that in the presence of unemployment when income tax
or lump-sum tax revenue is used to finance the provision of the public
good, the private marginal cost always overstates its social marginal
cost. When an excise tax on the manufactured good or a tariff is used,
then the private marginal cost of public good provision may overstate
its social marginal cost even if the taxed and public goods are
substitutes.
2. The Model
In this section we develop a two sector (an urban and- a rural)
general equilibrium trade model of a small developing economy with
identical consumers characterized by HT unemployment. In the urban
sector, two goods are produced: an import competing manufactured good
(M) and a nontradable pure, public consumption good (g). An exported
agricultural good (A) is produced in the rural sector, which is also
chosen as the numeraire commodity. The exported good (A) is freely
traded, while a tariff may be imposed on the imports of the manufactured
good (M). All commodity markets are assumed competitive, and both goods
are assumed normal in consumption. The government, in order to finance
the provision of the public good, levies, independently or in
combination, a tax on income from production of all goods at a rate
([rho]), an excise tax on the manufactured good at a rate ([tau]), and
an import tariff at a rate (t). [2]
The Structure of Production
Labor is the intersectorally mobile factor, capital (K) is sector
specific in the production of the manufactured good (M), and land (E) is
sector specific in the production of the agricultural good (A).
Production technologies of the two private goods exhibit constant
returns to scale with positive and diminishing marginal products of
factors and positive cross-partials. The production functions of the two
private goods are given by
M = M([L.sup.M], K), and (1)
A = A([L.sup.A], E), (2)
where [L.sup.i], i = M, A denotes, respectively, the amounts of
labor employed in the production of the two privately traded goods and K
and E, respectively, are the fixed endowments of the sector-specific
capital and land.
For simplicity, we assume that labor is the only factor in the
production of the public good and that the labor input per unit of
output is one. Thus,
g = [L.sup.g] (3)
is the amount of the public good produced and [L.sup.g] is the
amount of labor used in its production. [3]
We define R(q, [lambda], K, E) to be the gross national product
(GNP) function, representing the maximum attainable revenue from
production of the private and public goods, given (i) the producer
domestic relative price for (M) q(=[p.sup.*]) in the case of only income
or excise tax and q(=[p.sup.*] + t) in the case of an import tariff,
where [p.sup.*] is the constant world price for the manufactured; (ii)
the urban unemployment ratio [lambda](=[L.sup.u]/([L.sup.M] +
[L.sup.g])), where [L.sup.u] is the number of urban unemployed workers;
and (iii) the endowments of the sector-specific capital (K) and land
(E). [4] For the rest of the analysis, K and E are omitted from the GNP
function since they do not affect the results of the paper. The variable
[lambda](=[lambda]([rho], [tau], t); see the Appendix for derivations)
enters as an argument into the GNP function to capture the loss to the
economy due to unemployment, measured by the shadow wage of labor (e.g.,
see Beladi and Chao 1993). Since [lambda](=[L.sup.u]/([L.sup.M] +
[L.sup.g])), the loss to the economy due to a one-unit increase in
[lambda] is [R.sub.[lambda]] = -[w.sup.A]([L.sup.M] + [L.sup.g]), where
[w.sup.A] is the rural wage. The partial derivative of the GNP function
with respect to q (i.e., [R.sub.g](q, [lambda])) is the supply function
of the manufactured good. Because [lambda] = [lambda]([rho], [tau], t)
and p* is assumed constant, the supply function for the manufactured
good can be written as [R.sub.q](q(t), [lambda](t)) = [R.sub.q](q(t))
for the case where only import tariff is used. [5] The R(q, [lambda])
function is assumed to be strictly convex in q (i.e., [R.sub.qq]
[greater than] 0). For the rest of the analysis, subscripts denote partial derivatives.
The Wage-Setting and Labor Market Equilibrium
According to the HT paradigm, the rural wage ([w.sup.A]) is
competitively determined ensuring full employment in that sector. In the
urban sector, the existence of an institutionally fixed minimum wage (w)
above the market-clearing level results in sectoral unemployment. [6]
Assuming that each worker has the same chance of being hired, the
probability of finding urban employment equals the ratio of employed
labor (i.e., [L.sup.m] = [L.sup.M] + [L.sup.g]) to the labor force in
that sector (i.e., [L.sup.m] + [L.sup.u]). Then, the expected urban wage
([w.sup.e]) equals the minimum wage (w) multiplied by the probability of
finding employment (i.e., [L.sup.m]/([L.sup.m] + [L.sup.u])).
Intersectoral labor migration, which is the factor connecting the
rural-urban areas, ensures the equalization of expected wages in the two
sectors and labor market equilibrium. That is,
[w.sup.A] = [w.sup.e] = [[L.sup.m]/([L.sup.m] + [L.sup.u])]w. (4)
Using the definition of the urban unemployment ratio
[lambda](=[L.sup.u]/[L.sup.m]), the labor market equilibrium condition
in Equation 4 can be rewritten as
W = (1 + [lambda])[w.sup.A]. (5)
Labor is assumed homogeneous, and because perfect competition
exists in product markets, it is paid the value of its marginal product
in each sector. That is,
W = q[M.sub.L]([L.sup.M], K), and [w.sup.A] = [A.sub.L]([L.sup.A],
E), (6)
where [M.sub.L](=[partial]M/[partial][L.sup.M]) and
[A.sub.L](=[partial]A/[partial][L.sup.A]), respectively, are the
sectoral marginal products of labor. Since labor is free to move
throughout the economy, the fixed labor endowment (L) must equal the sum
of employment in the urban sector (manufactured employment plus
employment in the production of the public good) and agriculture plus
the number of urban unemployed. Using the definition of [lambda], the
economy's labor endowment constraint can be written as
(1 + [lambda])[L.sup.m] + [L.sup.A] = L. (7)
Demand Conditions, Trade, and the Government
We assume identical consumers whose utility depends positively on
the consumption of the two traded goods (i.e., M and A) and the public
consumption good (g). Demand conditions are described by the expenditure
function E(p, g, u), denoting the minimum private spending on
consumption required to achieve a level of utility u, given the consumer
domestic relative price of the manufactured good p(=[p.sup.*] [tau] + t)
and the level of public good provision (g). [7] The partial derivative
of the expenditure function with respect to p (i.e., [E.sub.p]) denotes
the compensated demand function of the manufactured good, which is
assumed strictly concave in p (i.e., [E.sub.pp] [less than] 0).
Moreover, [E.sub.g] is negative, denoting that an increase in the
consumption of the public good reduces expenditure on the private goods
required to achieve the level of utility u. In the public economics
literature (i.e., King 1986), -[E.sub.g] is called the "marginal
willingness to pay for the public good."
Let Z(p, g, u) be the trade expenditure function, which is defined
as the difference between domestic minimum expenditure and revenue from
production of the private and public goods. That is,
Z(p, g, u) = E(p, g, u) - R[q, [lambda](t)]. (8)
The trade expenditure function is assumed strictly concave in
prices (i.e., [Z.sub.pp] [less than] 0), and its derivative with respect
to p (i.e., [Z.sub.p] = [E.sub.p] - [R.sub.p]) is the demand for imports
function. Note that for the case where the government collects only
tariff revenue to finance the provisions of the public good, we have p =
q(=[p.sup.*] + t).
It is assumed, as noted earlier, that the government collects
revenue from (i) a tax on income from the production of the private and
public consumption goods, (ii) an excise tax on the manufactured good,
and (iii) an import tariff. Such tax revenue is used to finance the cost
of providing the public good. The government net tax revenue (i.e., B)
is written as follows:
B = [rho]R(q, [lambda]) + [tau][E.sub.p](p, g, u) + t[Z.sub.p](p,
g, u) - w[L.sup.g] (9)
where [rho]R(q, [lambda]) is the income tax revenue,
[tau][E.sub.p](p, g, u) is the excise tax revenue. t[Z.sub.p](p, g, u)
is the tariff revenue, and w[L.sup.g] is the cost of the public good. We
assume that the government maintains a balanced budget, so that B = 0.
PROPOSITION 1. Consider a small open economy characterized by HT
unemployment and by local provision of a public consumption good. Then,
government net tax revenue (B), ceteris paribus, increases with a
decrease in the unemployment ratio and an increase in the income tax
rate. Changes in the level of the public good have an ambiguous effect
on (B), depending on whether the manufactured and public goods are
complements or substitutes in consumption. Finally, a small excise tax
or import tariff on tile manufactured good increases government net tax
revenue.
PROOF. Totally differentiating Equation 9, recalling the properties
of the GNP function, and rearranging terms, we obtain
dB = ([tau] + t)[E.sub.pu]du - (w - [tau][E.sub.pg] -
t[E.sub.pg])d[L.sup.g] - [rho][W.sup.A][L.sup.m]d[lambda] + [[E.sub.p] +
([tau] + t)[E.sub.pp]d[tau] + ([Z.sub.p] + t[Z.sub.pp] + [rho][R.sub.q]
+ [tau][E.sub.pp])dt + Rd[rho], (10)
Equation 10 reveals that in the present context,
([partial]B/[partial][lambda]) = -[rho][w.sup.A][L.sup.m] [less than] 0
and ([partial]B/[partial][rho]) = R [greater than] 0. Moreover,
([partial]B/[partial][L.sup.g]) [less than] 0 when [E.sub.pg] [less
than] 0 that is, when the manufactured and public goods are substitutes
in consumption. When [E.sub.pg] [greater than] 0, then
([partial]B/[partial][L.sup.g]) may be positive or negative. [8]
Assuming no use of other policy instrument, Equation 10 gives for the
case of an excise tax on the manufactured good
([partial]B/[partial][tau]) = ([E.sub.p] + [tau][E.sub.pp]) and for the
case of the import tariff ([partial]B/[partial]t) = ([Z.sub.p] +
t[Z.sub.pp], from which the results of Proposition 1 follow. [9]
Some Benchmark Results
Total differentiation of Equation 11 yields
The country's income-expenditure identity (budget constraint)
requires that total private spending must equal net, after tax income
from production of all goods. That is,
E(p, g, u) = (1 - [rho])R(q, [lambda]). (11)
DEFINITIONS: Consider a small open economy characterized by HT
unemployment and provision of a public good financed through an income
tax or an excise tax on the manufactured good or an import tariff
Changes in any of the three policy instruments affects welfare directly
and indirectly through the, what we call, public good effect and
employment effect.
du = [-[E.sup.p] - [E.sub.g][[L.sup.g].sub.[tau]] + (1
-[rho])[R.sub.[lambda]][[lambda].sub.[tau]]]d[tau] + [-[Z.sub.p] -
[E.sub.g][[L.sup.g].sub.t] + (1 - [rho])
[R.sub.[lambda]][[lambda].sub.t]]dt + [-R - [E.sub.g] [[L.sup.g].sub.p]
+ (1 - [rho]) [R.sub.[lambda]][[lambda].sub.[rho]]]d[rho], (12)
where [E.sub.u] = 1 by choice of units, 4= [Z.sub.p] = [Z.sub.p] +
[rho][R.sub.p] [greater than] 0, [[L.sup.g].sub.t], and
[[lambda].sub.i], i = [rho], [tau], t are the total differentials of
[L.sup.g] and [lambda] with respect to the policy parameters [rho],
[tau], and t (see the Appendix for the detailed derivations). Consider,
for example, the case where d[tau] [greater than] 0 and dt = d[rho] = 0.
Then, from Equation 12, the right-hand-side expression for (du/d[tau])
comprises three components. The first (i.e., -[E.sub.p]) is the direct
effect capturing the negative impact of a higher excise tax on welfare
due to higher expenditure required to maintain a given level of
consumption of the manufacturing good. The second component (i.e.,
-[E.sub.g][[L.sup.g].sub.[tau]]) is the so-called public good effect,
capturing the impact of the higher excise tax on welfare through the
provision of the public good. The last component of the (du/d[tau])
expression in Equation 12 (i.e., (1 -
[rho])[R.sub.[lambda]][[lambda].sub.[tau]]) is the so-called employment
effect, capturing the impact of a higher ([tau]) on welfare through
changes in the unemployment ratio ([lambda]). Similarly, observing
Equation 12, changes in the other two tax rates (i.e., dt [greater than]
0 when d[tau] = d[rho] = 0, or dp [greater than] 0 when d[tau] = dt = 0)
affect welfare through the corresponding direct effect, public good
effect, and employment effect.
PROPOSITION 2. Assume a small open economy characterized by HT
unemployment and by local provision of a public consumption good. Then,
an income tax or a small excise tax on the manufactured good or a small
tariff unambiguously raises the provision of the public good. [10]
PROOF. Equations A3 to A5 provide the proof of this proposition.
Equation A3 shows that, ceteris paribus, an income tax always raises
government net tax revenue, thus the provision of the public good.
Equations A4 and A5, respectively, show that this is also true for the
case of a small excise tax (i.e., initially [tau] [approximate] 0) or a
small import tariff (i.e., initially t [approximate] 0). Moreover, the
import tariff, being a subsidy to the production of the manufactured
good, raises urban employment and incomes, thus further increasing
government net tax revenue and the provision of the public good.
However, a larger excise tax on the manufactured good or an import
tariff affects negatively the consumption of this good and thus tax
revenue. If the overall effect of such a higher excise tax or of a
higher import tariff on government tax revenue is negative, then
production of the public good falls.
PROPOSITION 3. Assume that in a small open economy characterized by
HT type of unemployment, the government provided public good is financed
through an income tax, an excise tax on the manufactured good, or a
tariff. An increase in the income tax rate always increases government
net tax revenue and reduces the unemployment ratio. Similar effects are
induced by a small excise tax on the manufactured good or a small
tariff.
PROOF. Equations A6 to A8 provide the proof of this proposition.
Intuitively, an income tax or a small excise tax or a small import
tariff that raises government net tax revenue and public good provision
also increases employment and thus reduces the unemployment ratio. If
the policy of a higher excise tax or of a higher import tariff reduces
government net tax revenue and the level of the public good, then it
also reduces employment and raises the unemployment ratio.
When nondistortionary taxes (e.g., lump-sum taxes) are used to
finance the public good, then the first-best efficiency rule for its
provision requires that the social marginal benefit equal the social
marginal cost. When distortionary taxes (e.g., consumption taxes) are
used to finance the provision of the public good, then Pigou argued that
the private marginal cost understates the social marginal cost. This,
however, as subsequent authors have shown, is not always true (e.g., see
Introduction). [11]
In the remainder of this paper, we examine the effects of an
increase in each of the policy instruments on welfare in the presence of
HT unemployment when the government uses an income tax, an excise tax on
the manufactured good, or an import tariff to finance its provision. We
also derive the efficiency rules for public good provision under each
policy regime.
3. Income Tax Policy, Welfare, and the Efficiency Rule
Now we assume that the government's policy instrument to raise
revenue and finance the provision of the public good is a tax on incomes
from production of the private and public consumption goods.
Setting d[tau] = t = dt = 0, but [tau] [greater than] 0 in Equation
12, and using Equations A3 and A6 of the Appendix, after some algebraic manipulations, we obtain
([delta][R.sup.-1])(du/d[rho]) = [[delta].sub.2](w + [E.sub.g]) +
[[delta].sub.1][R.sub.[lambda]] - [tau][[delta].sub.2]][E.sub.pg], (13)
where the expressions for [delta] [less than] 0, [[delta].sub.1]
[greater than] 0 and [[delta].sub.2] [greater than] 0 are explicitly
defined in the Appendix.
Consider the case where [tau] = 0. Then, Equation 13 indicates that
the higher income tax affects welfare through the induced (i) public
good effect (i.e., [[delta].sup.-1]R[[delta].sub.2](w + [E.sub.g])) and
(ii) employment effect (i.e.,
[[delta].sup.-1]R[[delta].sub.1][R.sub.[lambda]]). [12] Through the
public good effect, the higher p, which raises government net tax
revenue and public good provision, affects welfare positively if the
public good is undersupplied. [13] For the rest of the analysis, we
assume this to be the case. Through the employment effect, the higher p
exerts a positive effect on welfare since, by increasing the public good
provision (i.e., [L.sup.g]), it reduces the unemployment ratio (see
Eqns. A3 and A6), and thus it increases income. Thus, the higher income
tax rate improves welfare since the public good is assumed
undersupplied. [14]
Next we obtain the efficiency rule for the provision of the public
good in the present policy regime as follows:
PROPOSITION 4. Consider an economy characterized by unemployment of
the HT type and where the sole instrument of financing the provision of
an undersupplied public good is an income or a lump-sum tax. Within this
model, the private marginal cost of the public good always overstates
its social marginal cost.
PROOF. Setting (du/d[rho]) = 0 in Equation 13, we obtain [15]
-[E.sub.g] = w + ([[delta].sub.1]/[[delta].sub.2])[R.sub.[lambda]]
- [tau][E.sub.pg]. (14)
The left-hand side of Equation 14 is the social marginal benefit of
public good provision, while the right-hand side is its social marginal
cost. The second right-hand-side term of Equation 14 is negative. Thus,
we conclude that in the present context of unemployment and public good
provision, when the income tax is the sole policy instrument (i.e.,
[tau] = 0), the private marginal cost of public good provision (i.e., w)
always overstates its true social marginal cost. [16] Intuitively, the
social marginal cost of the public good is less than the private
marginal cost in this case since an increase in the income tax rate to
finance the provision of public good decreases the unemployment rate and
increases income and welfare. When full employment exists, then the
private marginal cost equals the social marginal cost. [17]
This is an important new result in terms of the relevant
literature. As noted in the Introduction, contrary to Pigou's
intuitive result, subsequent studies (e.g., Atkinson and Stern 1974;
Wildasin 1984) concluded that when distortionary taxes are used to
finance the provision of the public good, under certain conditions
(e.g., when the taxed and public goods are complements in consumption)
the social marginal cost of the public good falls short of the private
marginal cost. In the present case of HT unemployment and public good
provision solely financed through income or lump-sum taxation, the
social marginal cost of the public good is always smaller than its
private marginal cost regardless of the relationship between private and
public goods in consumption.
4. Excise Tax on the Manufactured Good, Welfare, and the Efficiency
Rule
Next we turn to the welfare effects of a higher excise tax on the
manufactured good (i.e., d[tau] [greater than] 0) in the presence of HT
unemployment and public good, and we derive the efficiency rule for
public good provision.
Letting in Equation 12 [rho] [greater than] 0 and d[rho] = t = dt =
0 and using Equations A4 and A7 of the Appendix, after some algebraic
manipulations we obtain
[delta](du/d[tau]) = [[delta].sub.2](w + [E.sub.g])[E.sub.p] +
[[delta].sub.1][R.sub.[lambda]][E.sub.p] -
[tau][[[delta].sub.2]([E.sub.p][[E.sup.-1].sub.pp][E.sub.pg] -
[E.sub.g]) - [[delta].sub.1](1 - [rho])[R.sub.[lambda]]][E.sub.pp]. (15)
Equation 15 indicates that a higher excise tax affects welfare
through (i) changes in the level of public good provision (i.e.,
[[delta].sub.2](w + [E.sub.g])[E.sub.p]), which we call the public good
effect; (ii) changes in income due to changes in the unemployment ratio
(i.e., [[delta].sub.1][R.sub.[lambda]][E.sub.p] = -
[[delta].sub.1][w.sup.A][L.sup.m][E.sub.p]), which we call the
employment effect; and (iii) changes in government net tax revenue due
to changes in consumer prices, the level of public good provision, and
the unemployment ratio (i.e., -
[tau][[[delta].sub.2]([E.sub.p][[E.sup.-1].sub.pp][E.sub.pg] -
[E.sub.g]) - [[delta].sub.1](1 - [rho])[R.sub.[lambda]]][E.sub.pp]),
which we call the tax revenue effect.
Through the public good effect, the impact of the higher [tau] on
welfare by and large follows that of the previous case of the income
tax. Through the employment effect, the higher [tau], which raises
government revenue, affects positively [L.sup.g] reduces [lambda] (see
Eqns. A4 and A7), and increases incomes, thus exerting a positive impact
on welfare. When such an excise tax on the manufactured good is the only
source of financing the provision of the public good (i.e., [rho] = 0)
and the excise tax rate is small (i.e., [tau] [approximate] 0), it is
expected that the public good is undersupplied (i.e., g [approximate] 0)
and -[E.sub.g] [greater than] w). In this case, an increase in [tau]
raises welfare since the public good effect and the employment effect
dominate the tax revenue effect. For a larger tax (i.e., [tau] [greater
than] 0), a further increase in its rate may exert, through the tax
revenue effect, a positive or negative impact on welfare, in part
depending on whether the manufactured and pub lic consumption goods are
substitutes (complements) in consumption (i.e., [E.sub.pg] [less than] 0
([greater than] 0)). For example, if [E.sub.pg] [less than] 0, then this
revenue effect of a higher [tau] on welfare is negative. In this case,
if also [tau] is large, then a further increase in the excise tax
reduces welfare if the tax revenue effect dominates the public good
effect and employment effect.
Next, we obtain the second-best excise tax rate (i.e.,
[[tau].sup.*]).
PROPOSITION 5. Consider a small open economy providing an
undersupplied public good. When only an excise tax on the manufactured
good is chosen optimally to finance its provision, then there is a
positive, second-best excise tax rate that maximizes welfare. This
result holds regardless of the existence of HT unemployment or of a
suboptimally chosen income tax rate.
PROOF. Setting (du/d[tau]) = 0 in Equation 15 and solving for
[tau], we get
[[tau].sup.*] = [(w + [E.sub.g])[[delta].sub.2] +
[[delta].sub.1][R.sub.[lambda]]][E.sub.p]/[[[delta].sub.2]([E.sub.p][
[E.sup.-1].sub.pp][E.sub.pg] - [E.sub.g]) - [[delta].sub.1](1 -
[rho])[R.sub.[lambda]]][E.sub.pp]. (16)
Equation 16 shows that since (w + [E.sub.g]) [less than] 0, then
[[tau].sup.*] [greater than] 0 regardless of whether a suboptimal income
tax rate exists (i.e., [rho] [greater than or equal to] 0). [18] If,
however, [rho] [greater than] 0, then the corresponding [[tau].sup.*] is
greater to that when [rho] = 0, assuming everything else is the same.
With full employment (i.e., [R.sub.[lambda]] = 0), since (w + [E.sub.g])
[less than] 0, the optimal policy is again [[tau].sup.*] [greater than]
0. [19]
When [E.sub.pg] [greater than] 0, it is possible for the
denominator of Equation 16 to be positive. In this case, one could
conclude that the optimum excise tax is negative. This, however, is
wrong. The negative excise tax is the one that minimizes welfare. When
the denominator of Equation 16 is positive, that is, the third term on
the right-hand side of Equation 15 is negative, it means that as the
excise tax increases, welfare increases at an increasing rate, and in
this case we may have a corner solution or implicit determination of the
optimum tax rate. When [E.sub.pg] [less than] 0, this possibility does
not exist.
PROPOSITION 6. Assume an economy with unemployment described by the
HT model. When an excise tax on the manufactured good is used to finance
the public good, then the private marginal cost of the public good may
overstate its social marginal cost even if the public and the
manufactured good are substitutes in consumption. [20]
PROOF. Setting (du/d[tau]) = 0 in Equation 15, we get
-[E.sub.g] = w + ([[delta].sub.1]/[[delta].sub.2])[R.sub.[lambda]]
- [tau][([E.sub.p][[E.sup.-1].sub.pp][E.sub.pg] - [E.sub.g]) -
([[lambda].sub.1]/[[lambda].sub.2])(1 -
[rho])[R.sub.[lambda]]][E.sub.pp][[E.sup.-1].sub.p]. (17)
When we have full employment (i.e., [R.sub.[lambda]] = 0), we get
the well-known result. That is, when the public and the taxed goods are
substitutes in consumption (i.e., [E.sub.pg] [less than] 0), then the
private marginal cost understates its social marginal cost. When,
however, they are complements, then the private marginal cost may
overstate its social marginal cost. However, in the present framework,
with HT unemployment, the private marginal cost may overstate the social
marginal cost even if the public and the taxed goods are substitutes in
consumption.
Comparing Equations 14 and 17, we note the following point. When an
income tax is chosen as a policy instrument, the existence of an excise
tax on the manufactured good may alter the efficiency rule for public
good provision. In case that the selected policy instrument is an excise
tax, the presence of a suboptimal income tax has no bearing on the
respective efficiency rule.
5. Import Tariff and Welfare
Most LDCs are frequently revenue constrained in financing
government activities (e.g., the provision of public goods), for this,
an import tariff, despite its known heavier deadweight losses compared
to other policy instruments (e.g., income taxes), is a relatively
effective and administratively low-cost policy choice for generating
government revenue and financing public sector activities. In this
section, assuming the absence of income taxes, we briefly note the use
of only tariff revenue to finance the provision of the public good.
Using Equations 12 and A5, the welfare effect of raising the tariff rate
is given as follows:
[delta](du/dt) = [[delta].sub.2](w + [E.sub.g])[[Z.sub.p] -
[(q[M.sub.LL]).sup.-1] [M.sub.L]w][R.sub.[lambda]] -
t[[[delta].sub.2]([Z.sub.p][[Z.sup.-1].sub.pp][E.sub.pg] - [E.sub.g]) -
[[delta].sub.1][R.sub.[lambda]](1 + [xi])][Z.sub.pp], (18)
where [xi] = [(q[M.sub.LL][Z.sub.pp]).sup.-1] [M.sub.L][E.sub.pg]
[greater than] ([less than])0, depending on whether [E.sub.pg] [greater
than] ([less than])0. Equation 18 shows that the higher tariff rates
affects welfare through an induced (i) public good effect (i.e.,
[[delta].sup.-1][[delta].sub.2](w + [E.sub.g])[Z.sub.p]), (ii)
employment effect (i.e., [[delta].sup.-1][[delta].sub.1][[Z.sub.p] -
[(q[M.sub.LL]).sup.-1] [M.sub.L]w][R.sub.[lambda]]), and what we call
(iii) tariff revenue effect (i.e., -
[[delta].sup.-1]t[[[delta].sub.2]([z.sub.p][[z.sup.-1].sub.pp][E.sub.
pg] - [E.sub.g]) - [[delta].sub.1][R.sub.[lambda]](1 + [xi])][Z.sub.pp].
[21]
Through the public good effect, the higher tariff, which raises
government revenue, affects welfare positively if the public good is
undersupplied. Through the employment effect, the higher tariff entails
a positive effect on domestic employment, thus incomes and welfare.
First, as in the case of an excise or an income tax, the higher tariff
raises government revenue, which affects positively [L.sup.g], reduces
[lambda], and raises incomes and welfare (i.e.,
[[delta].sup.-1][[delta].sub.1][R.sub.[lambda]][Z.sub.p]). Second, a
tariff, which acts as a subsidy to manufactured production, raises
employment in that sector, thus further reducing [lambda], increasing
urban incomes and overall welfare (i.e.,
-[[delta].sup.-1][[delta].sub.1][(q[M.sub.LL]).sup.-1]
[M.sub.L]w[R.sub.[lambda]]).
Like in the case of an excise tax, when the tariff is the only
policy instrument and it is small (i.e., t [approximate] 0), it is
expected that the public good is undersupplied. In this case, an
increase in its rate is welfare improving since the public good effect
and employment effect dominate the tariff revenue effect.
Setting (du/dt) = 0 in Equation 18, we get the efficiency rule for
public good provision when the government uses only tariff revenue to
finance its provision as follows:
-[E.sub.g] = ([[delta].sub.1]/[[delta].sub.2])[[Z.sup.-1].sub.p][[Z.sub.p] - [(q[M.sub.LL]).sup.-1] [M.sub.L]w][R.sub.[[lambda] -
t[([Z.sub.p][[Z.sup.-1].sub.pp][E.sub.pg] - [E.sub.g]) -
([[delta].sub.1]/[[delta].sub.2])[R.sub.[[lambda](1 +
[xi])][Z.sub.pp][[Z.sup.-1].sub.p]. (19)
Careful examination of Equation 19 reveals that Proposition 6 also
applies in this case. That is, the private marginal cost of the public
good may overstate its social marginal cost even if the taxed and the
public good are substitutes in consumption. When full employment exists
(i.e., [R.sub.[lambda]] = 0), then we get the well-known result. That
is, when the public and the taxed goods are substitutes in consumption
(i.e., [E.sub.pg] [less than] 0), then the private marginal cost
understates its social marginal cost.
6. Concluding Remarks
By now it is broadly accepted in the literature of international
trade and economic development that governments seldom lump-sum
distribute to domestic households revenues generated from the imposition
of taxes (e.g., income) or tariffs. Instead, such tax revenues, by and
large, are used to finance the provision of public goods and public
inputs. As a result, the recent surge in this literature has evolved
around this premise.
Within this existing trade literature of public good provision, the
paper notes and incorporates two issues. The first is that of the
existence of unemployment, an assumption particularly relevant in the
context of a LDC. The second recognizes that, more than often,
governments may use policies jointly (e.g., income and excise tax
policies) to finance the provision of the public good or input. Either
issue, when accounted for, alters nontrivially existing analytical
results and provides some newer ones. For this, we construct a general
equilibrium trade model of a small open economy characterized by
Harris-Todaro type of unemployment, producing two privately traded goods
and a nontraded public consumption good. [22] For the provision of the
later commodity, the government generates the required revenue through
the imposition of an income and/or an excise tax on the manufactured
good or of an import tariff. The paper then examines the effect of such
tax policies on the unemployment ratio and the level of welf are and
derives the efficiency rules for public good provision.
Among other findings, we note the following. First, given the
undersupply of the public good, with or without unemployment and the
presence of a suboptimally chosen income tax, the government's
second-best policy is an excise tax or an import tariff on the
manufactured good when each instrument alone is optimally chosen. Under
either policy regime, because of unemployment, even if the taxed and
public goods are substitutes in consumption, it is possible for the
private marginal cost of the public good to overstate its social
marginal cost. In the case of full employment, such a possibility does
not exist when the two goods are substitutes in consumption. Second,
with income taxes alone, the private marginal cost of the public good
always overstates its social marginal cost with unemployment, but the
two are equal with full employment.
(*.) D.I.E.E.S., Athens University of Economics and Business, 76
Patission Street, Athens 104 34, Greece and CESifo; E-mail
hatzip@aueb.gr.
(+.) Department of Economics, University of Cyprus, P.O. Box 20537,
CY-1678 Nicosia. Cyprus and CESifo; E-mail m.s.michael@ucy.ac.cy:
corresponding author.
The authors gratefully acknowledge the insightful comments by the
Editor and two referees of the Journal. Responsibility for remaining
shortcomings lies entirely with the authors.
(1.) Michael and Hatzipanayotou (1995) for the case of a
consumption tax and Michael (1997) for the case of an import tariff show
that the social cost of the public good may understate its private
marginal cost when the public good and the taxed good are general
equilibrium complements.
(2.) In LDCs, by and large, imported (manufactured) goods are
primarily luxury goods whose consumption is usually taxed, while the
consumption of agricultural (necessity) goods, constituting a large
portion of spending by the poorer segments of their population, is
usually untaxed. Moreover, the use of import tariffs is historically
consistent with the efforts of LDCs to raise public sector revenue.
Recent trends, however, of global and regional trade liberalization have
forced these countries to reduce such trade taxes and to resort to less
distortionary means (e.g., income and excise taxes) of raising public
sector revenue.
(3.) In part, the results depend on the assumed linear production
function for the public good. For expositional purposes, however, we
think that this approach is reasonable.
(4.) It can be shown that the comparative static's analysis
using R(q, [lamda], k, E) as the GNP function are the same as those
using a more conventional writing, for example, R(q, [L.sup.M],
[L.sup.g], [L.sup.A], K, E).
(5.) Note that in the case of an excise tax, [R.sub.q[tau]] =
([partial]M/[partial][L.sup.M])([partial][L.sup.M]/[partial][tau]) 0.
Similarly, in the case of an income tax, [R.sub.qp] = 0 (see the
Appendix). That is, the supply of the manufactured good is unaffected by
changes in the excise or the income tax.
(6.) Alternatively, the urban wage rate can be indexed in terms of
consumer prices. The essence of the results, however, remains the same.
(7.) Since employed and urban unemployed households enjoy different
levels of utility, equal in expectation to the rural utility level, a
standard practice of the HT literature is to assume identical and
homothetic demands for all (i.e., rural and urban employed or
unemployed) households.
(8.) Assuming that [E.sub.pg] = 0, that is, assuming that the
private and public goods are separable in consumption, then
unambiguously ([partial]B/[[partial][L.sup.g]) = -w [less than] 0.
(9.) It does not add much to the results of the paper to consider
the other taxes as nonzero constants.
(10.) The result that for a small (t), (d[L.sup.g]/dt) [greater
than] 0, holds regardless of whether initially [rho] [greater than or
equal to] 0, (see Equation A5).
(11.) For example, when the taxed and the public goods are
complements in consumption or when we have a backward-bending labor
supply, then the private marginal cost may overstate the social marginal
cost.
(12.) Identical results emerge when [tau] = 0 and lump-sum taxes
are used to finance the provision of the public good.
(13.) In the following analysis when -[E.sub.g] [greater than] w,
we say that the public good is undersupplied. When -[E.sub.g] = w, we
say that the public good is supplied at its first-best level. To compare
our results with some standard results of the public economics
literature, note that the economy-wide consumer marginal willingness to
pay for the public good (i.e., -[E.sub.g]), which is the social marginal
benefit, is also the sum of the marginal rates of substitution over all
individuals (i.e., [sigma]MRS). Similarly, the marginal cost, which
presently equals the minimum wage w, equals the marginal rate of
transformation (i.e., MRT). Thus, our efficiency rule -[E.sub.g] = w is
the same as the conventional efficiency rule [sigma]MRS = MRT (see Rosen 1998 for a simple analysis relating these concepts).
(14.) In the presence of an excise tax, an increase in the income
tax has an additional effect on welfare through its effect on excise tax
revenue. That is, through this effect, an increase in the income tax
increases revenue, and the public good provision increases, causing
excise tax revenue to increase (decrease) if the public good and the
taxed good are complements (substitutes) in consumption. The increases
(decrease) in excise tax revenue affects positively (negatively)
welfare.
(15.) Setting (du/d[rho]) = 0 in Equation 13, the first-best income
tax rate ([[rho].sup.*]) cannot be explicitly determined but only
implicitly since p is included in g(=[L.sup.g]) [E.sub.g](p, g, u),
[R.sub.[lambda]](=-[w.sup.A]([L.sup.M] + [L.sup.g])), and so on.
(16.) In the present context of unemployment, the identical
efficiency rule applies when the public good is financed through
lump-sum taxes (see note 12). However, this equivalency between an
income and a lump-sum tax breaks down in more detailed models (e.g., one
incorporating labor/leisure decision).
(17.) In the presence of an excise tax, the private marginal cost
overstates its social marginal cost when the manufactured and the public
goods are complements in consumption. If, however, they are substitutes,
then the private marginal cost may understate its social marginal cost.
(18.) The second-best policy unambiguously is also [[tau].sup.*]
[greater than] 0 in the special case where the public good is and the
public and manufactured goods are neutral in consumption (i.e.,
[E.sub.pg] = 0).
(19.) When a suboptimal income tax rate finances the provision of
the public good and w = -[E.sub.g], then the second-best policy is still
an excise tax with HT unemployment, but it is a zero tax with full
employment.
(20.) With distortionary taxation, the marginal cost of public
funds (MCF) is usually greater than one. When, however, the private
taxed good and the public good are complements in consumption, then the
MCF could be less than one (Atkinson and Stern 1974). Sandmo (1998)
shows that MCF could be less than one in a model with heterogeneous consumers and redistribution from high-wage to low-wage workers. In the
present model with unemployment, the MCF is always less than one with
income or lump-sum taxes and can be less than one with excise taxes or
tariffs even if the taxed good and the public good are substitutes in
consumption. For the definition of MCF, see, for example, Sandmo (1998).
(21.) The analytical interpretation of Equation 19 does not change
despite the presence of additional terms when [rho] is not zero. To
simplify the exposition of the results, however, we set [rho] = 0.
(22.) Similar but not identical results can be obtained when
unemployment is due to a rigid minimum real wage rate in both sectors of
the economy. The exact results depend on the tax instrument and on the
details of the model. The rigid real wage model is frequently used in
the literature (e.g., for a recent application of this model, see Hoel 1997).
References
Atkinson, Anthony, and Nicolas Stern. 1974. Pigou taxation and
public goods. Review of Economic Studies 41:119-28.
Beladi, Hamid, and C-C. Chao. 1993. Non-traded goods, urban
unemployment and welfare in LDCs. European Journal of Political Economy
9:281-92.
Feehan, James. 1988. Efficient tariff financing of public goods.
Journal of 25:155-64.
Harris, John, and Michael Todaro. 1970. Migration, unemployment and
development: A two Sector analysis. American Economic Review 60:126-42.
Hoel, Michael. 1997. Coordination of environmental policy for
transboundary environmental problems? Journal of Public Economics
66:199-224.
King, Michael. 1986. A pigovian rule for the optimum provision of
public goods. Journal of Public Economics 30:273-91.
Michael, Michael S. 1997. The Optimal tariff for public good and
public input provision. Public Finance Review 25:117-33.
Michael, Michael S., and Panos Hatzipanayotou. 1995. On public good
provision with distortionary taxation. Public Finance/Finances Publiques
50:292-302.
Michael, Michael S., and Panos Hatzipanayotou, 1997. Public good
production, nontraded goods, and trade restrictions. Southern Economic
Journal 63:1100-7.
Pigou, A. C. 1947. A Study in Public Finance. 3rd edition. London:
Macmillan.
Rosen, Harvey. 1998. Public Finance. 2nd edition. New York: Irwin.
Samuelson, Paul. 1954. The pure theory of public expenditures.
Review of Economics and Statistics 36:387-9.
Sandmo, Agnar. 1998. Redistribution and the marginal cost of public
funds. Journal of Public Economics 70:365-82.
Stiglitz. Joseph, and Partha Dasgupta. 1971. Differential taxation,
public goods, and economic efficiency. Review of Economic Studies
38:151-74.
Wildasin, David. 1984. On public good provision with distortionary
taxation. Economic Inquiry 22:227-43.
Appendix
Equations 5, 6, 7, 9, and 11 constitute a system of six equations
in the endogenous variables u, [L.sup.M], [L.sup.g], [L.sup.A],
[lambda], and [w.sup.A], solved as functions of the policy parameters
[rho], [tau], and t. Total differentiation of these equations and
rewriting Equation 12 as
du + [E.sub.g]dg - (1 - [rho])[R.sub.[lambda]]d[lambda] = -
[E.sub.p]d[tau] - [Z.sub.p]dt - Rdp (A1)
produces the following matrix system:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (A2)
Recall that when [rho] is nonzero, then [Z.sub.p] = [Z.sub.p] +
[rho][R.sub.p] and ([partial]B/[partial]t) = [Z.sub.p] + t[Z.sub.pp].
For stability, the determinant [delta] = - [[delta].sub.1][[rho] + 1(1 -
[rho])[tau][E.sub.pu]][R.sub.[lambda]] - [[delta].sub.2][w -
[tau]([E.sub.pg] - [E.sub.g][E.sub.pu])] must be negative;
[[delta].sub.1] = q[M.sub.LL][A.sub.LL][(1 + [lambda]).sup.2] [greater
than] 0 and [[delta].sub.2] = q[M.sub.LL][(1 +
[lambda])[L.sup.m][A.sub.LL] - [w.sup.A] [greater than] 0. The following
results are obtained: Policy Effects on Public Good Provision
Income tax: (d[L.sup.g]/d[rho]) = [[L.sup.g].sub.p] =
-[[delta].sup.-1][[delta].sub.2](1 - [tau][E.sub.pu])R [greater than] 0
(A3)
Excise tax: (d[L.sup.g]/d[tau]) = [[L.sup.g].sub.[tau]] =
-[[delta].sup.-1][[delta].sub.2](1 - [tau][E.sub.pu])[E.sub.p] +
[tau][E.sub.pp]] (A4)
Import tariff: (d[L.sup.g]/dt) =
-[[delta].sup.-1]{[[delta].sub.2][(1 - t[E.sub.pu])[Z.sub.p] +
t[Z.sub.pp]] + [[delta].sub.1][[(p[M.sub.LL])].sup.-1][M.sub.L][[rho] +
(1 - [rho])t[E.sub.pu]][R.sub.[lambda]]} (A5)
Policy Effects on the Unemployment Ratio
Income tax: [delta](d[lambda]/d[rho]) = [[delta].sub.1](1 -
[tau][E.sub.pu])R [less than] 0 (A6)
Excise tax: [delta](d[lambda]/d[tau]) = [[delta].sub.1][(1 -
[tau][E.sub.pu])[E.sub.p] + [tau][E.sub.pp]] (A7)
Import tariff: [delta](d[lambda]/dt) = [[delta].sub.1]{(1 -
t[E.sub.pu])[Z.sub.p] + t[Z.sub.pp] -
[[(p[M.sub.LL])].sup.-1][M.sub.L][w - t([E.sub.pg] -
[E.sub.g][E.sub.pu])]} (A8)
Note that (1 - t[E.sub.pu]) [greater than] 0 and (1 -
[tau][E.sub.pu]) [greater than] 0 since both goods are normal in
consumption.