Hard Ball: The Abuse of Power in Pro Team Sports.
Siegfried, John J.
By James Quirk and Rodney Fort.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1999. Pp. xi, 233.
$22.95.
This engaging book is about the sickness plaguing professional
sports in America. The diagnosis is a bad case of chronic monopoly.
The four high-revenue men's professional team sports each
currently operates with a single monopoly league. The source of monopoly
differs among the leagues, however. Major League Baseball (MLB) was
formed by a 1902 merger that predates the anti-merger section of the
1914 Clayton Act. In 1922, baseball was exempted from antitrust coverage
by the Supreme Court because "baseball is not a business." The
National Football League (NFL) is the product of a 1969 merger with the
rival American Football League (AEL)' which opened for business in
1960. At the NFL's request, the combination of rival football
leagues was explicitly exempted from the Clayton Act by congressional
action. The current National Basketball Association (NBA) and National
Hockey League (NHL) are products of 1970s mergers between rival
leagues--the NBA with surviving parts of the American Basketball
Association and the NHL with a few survivors from the World Hockey
Association. Neither merger was challenged by antitrust authorities. The
result is entrenched monopoly leagues in all four major professional
men's team sports today (and since 1999, also in women's
professional basketball).
The monopolies are more entrenched today than ever before. Since
confronting rival leagues in the 1960s, the NFL, NBA, and NHL have
recognized that restricting entry to support the scarcity value of
franchises is not without risk. Over the past four decades, there has
been sufficient expansion in all four sports to place a franchise in
many (but, importantly, not all) cities that can financially support a
team. Unlike in 1960, today no league leaves enough locations vacant to
tempt an entirely new league. In addition to the shortage of locations
sufficient for an entire league, a new league today would also have to
figure out how to bid for top player talent against established teams
that earn huge monopoly rents from the collective sale of television
broadcast rights and receive large subsidies from local governments (in
the form of playing facilities with concessionary leases).
Because I agree wholeheartedly with the authors' diagnosis of
what ails the sports industry, I want to praise this book and recommend
it enthusiastically. I suspect the book would have been more persuasive
if the authors had not only identified the symptoms of the disease
plaguing professional team sports--exorbitant player salaries, the
blackmailing of cities, and competitive imbalance--and diagnosed the
ailment--monopoly power--but also had reported the long-term
consequences of the disease. Is the disease fatal, and if so, to whom?
Monopoly control of franchise expansion and team relocation causes
both economic inefficiency and a redistribution of income. Monopoly
contributes to exorbitant player salaries (increasing the marginal
revenue component of marginal revenue product), provides credibility for
threats to leave a city (or never locate there in the first place) if
local residents do not pony up funds to build a revenue-maximizing
facility and lease it to the team for a pittance, and leads to the
skewed revenue potential that splits teams into haves and have-nots in
terms of playing talent. At the heart of all three symptoms is exclusive
territories assigned to team owners.
Quirk and Fort seem concerned primarily with the distributional
consequences of the monopoly power, as it has been used to restrain
league expansion, limit team relocations, raise ticket prices, and
inhibit access to major league sports in America. A leisure activity
that once was enjoyed by the lunch-pail crowd, more and more caters to
those who favor crepes and Chardonnay. Ordinary folk are being priced
out of live attendance at sporting events. The professional sports
industry is a for-profit business that has learned how to tap into the
wealth generated at the top of an increasingly disperse income
distribution.
Controlling the number of franchises and team relocations also
enables owners to extract large public subsidies from taxpayers
seemingly petrified of being disparaged as residents of a "minor
league town" if their major league franchise were to relocate. The
subsidies are raised from regressive sales taxes, lotteries, or sin
taxes, and they are divided between wealthy owners and players.
The economist-reader of Hard Ball might resonate more to a
discussion of how the monopoly leagues inhibit teams from moving from
lower valued to higher valued locations and refuse franchises to
locations where the net social value of a team would exceed the
opportunity cost of the resources necessary to operate it.
Hard Ball is fun to read. It is laced with anecdotes, humor, and
sarcasm. If readers view this as dismal economic science, nothing will
likely please them. This is about as good reading as it gets in the
world of professional economists.
The value of Hard Ball is its persuasive case for giving
competition a chance in professional sports. When the opportunity arose
with the successful entry of the AFL in the 1960s, Congress fumbled by
approving legislation exempting professional football from antimerger
prosecution. When the American Basketball League merged with the NBA and
the NHL absorbed the World Hockey Association in the 1970s, the
Department of Justice blew an open shot at monopoly in sport.
Ineffective antitrust efforts decades ago allowed successful upstarts to
join their established rivals in reestablishing monopoly control over
the number and distribution of franchises. The legacy of those decisions
is monopoly leagues that have grown more entrenched over time.
Quirk and Fort propose divestiture of the sports leagues, perhaps
into four separate leagues of at least eight teams each. (All four
leagues are approaching 32 franchises.) The leagues could continue to
hold a common playoff. What they could not coordinate is franchise
locations and league size. This is an attractive approach, but a
dominant league eventually may emerge if a winner-take-all mentality
among fans leads them to support only the league they believe to be the
best no matter how small the difference in average talent level across
leagues.
A more realistic proposal that does not falter if fans are obsessed with supporting only the number-one league is to prohibit existing
leagues from exercising collective control over team relocations. This
would reduce the disparity in revenue potential because some teams from
lower revenue potential markets would invade the territories of teams
currently monopolizing larger markets. The result could easily be four
baseball teams in New York and three in Los Angeles. Competitive team
imbalance would decline because the revenue potential would equalize across teams as the territories of current haves were invaded by current
have-nots. Subsidies from cities to teams would shrink because leagues
would be unable to prevent a city that lost a team from luring a
different team to fill the void. Player salaries would decline because
both local television revenues and government subsidies to teams would
decline.
Introducing competition in franchise locations decisions could be
accomplished by either congressional or judicial action. Although it
would not overcome problems caused by the artificial scarcity of
franchises, it would encourage teams to move from lower-valued to
higher-valued locations, overcome much of the competitive imbalance
problem, and begin to apply some brakes to escalating players'
salaries (assuming that is a meritorious goal). Most importantly,
exposing relocation decisions to a competitive market would be possible
to implement without revolutionary changes.