The effectiveness of vehicle safety inspections: an analysis using panel data.
Sutter, Daniel
1. Introduction
Economists have extensively analyzed the efficacy of policies
intended to improve traffic safety. These policies include mandatory
seat belt use, the speed limit, motorcycle helmet laws, the drinking
age, and vehicle safety inspections. In this paper, we present new
evidence on the effectiveness of state vehicle inspections. Since
vehicle maintenance can confer an external benefit to other drivers by
reducing the accident rate, individuals may voluntarily provide less
than the efficient level of maintenance. Safety inspections attempt to
correct the externality by ensuring that vehicles meet a specified
maintenance standard. To examine the effect of inspection laws on
fatality and injury rates, we used a panel of the 50 states for the
years 1981-1993. Our empirical approach paid particular attention to the
problem of omitted variables. Many factors causing driving conditions to
vary across states can be difficult to quantify or may escape the
attention of the researcher. The panel allowed us to control for these
state-specific factors by estimating a fixed-effects model. In contrast,
previous studies of safety inspections have not allowed for
state-specific effects and are therefore vulnerable to omitted variables
bias.
Contrary to a number of existing studies, our results indicated
that inspections fail to significantly reduce fatality rates. We also
went beyond the typical approach by estimating the effect of inspections
on nonfatal injuries. Again, we found inspections ineffective. These
results held whether the models used variables in their levels or in
first differences. While our main empirical innovations pertain to inspections, our results also provide evidence of the effects of other
policy variables such as speed limits and seat belt laws. We also found
support for the Peltzman (1975) hypothesis that income and wealth
increase accidents by stimulating driving "intensity"
(heedlessness and speed).
Our estimates demonstrate the importance of modeling state-specific
effects. The estimated fixed effects differ very significantly from zero
and can affect inferences regarding the effectiveness of inspections.
Specifically, if our empirical model omits fixed effects in the levels,
the estimates attribute a significant reduction in fatalities to
systematic inspections; this result disappears, however, if the model
includes fixed effects.
This paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the
econometric model. It also includes a brief history of state inspection
programs and describes previous studies of safety inspections. Section 3
presents our results, and section 4 provides some estimates of the cost
of annual inspections and discusses some implications of our research.
2. Modeling State Safety Inspection Programs
Two types of inspection programs exist: mandatory annual
inspections and spot inspections, where law enforcement officers can at
their discretion stop and inspect a vehicle. Annual inspections take
place at a state-licensed repair shop, usually for a fee set by the
state. In addition to the fee, drivers bear a time cost of inspection
that includes queuing and the inspection itself (and reinspection if the
vehicle fails). The inspection typically requires safety features such
as headlights, turn signals, horn, and brakes to meet designated
standards.(1)
Many states initiated spot or annual inspections after Congress in
1966 mandated withholding federal highway funds from states failing to
adopt vehicle inspection programs. In 1977, Congress eliminated the
threat to withhold highway funds, and several states subsequently
eliminated inspection requirements.(2) Table 1 summarizes the changes in
state inspection regimes during the period covered by our investigation.
The number of annual inspection programs declined from 30 in 1980 to 23
in 1993. States made 20 shifts of inspection regime during the period;
15 different states experienced some form of regime shift. The variation
in inspection regimes over time provided the basis for our econometric tests, described below.
Previous studies of the effectiveness of safety inspections have
produced conflicting results. In fact, sorting these studies into
categories corresponding to the use of time-series, cross-sectional, or
pooled data shows that conflicting results exist within each category.
Using cross-sectional data on the 50 states, Loeb (1985, 1988) found
inspections effective while Crain (1980) did not. Keeler (1994) used
county-level data and found inspections effective in 1970 but not in
1980. Loeb and Gilad (1984) found evidence that inspections were
effective using time-series data for New Jersey. In national-level time
series, Garbacz and Kelly (1987), Garbacz (1990), and Fowles and Loeb
(1995) reported that inspections did not lower the fatality rate,
whereas Loeb (1990) found inspections effective. Using pooled data,
Leigh (1994) generated evidence against the effectiveness of
inspections; Saffer and Grossman (1987) concluded that inspections
reduced the fatality rate among young drivers.
Table 1. State Auto Inspection Programs, 1980-1993
Inspections States
Continuous Annual Inspection Arkansas, Delaware, Hawaii,
Louisiana, Maine, Massachusetts,
Mississippi, Missouri, New
Hampshire, New Jersey, New York,
North Carolina, Oklahoma,
Pennsylvania, Rhode Island, South
Carolina, Texas, Utah, Vermont,
Virginia, and West Virginia
Continuous Spot Inspection Alaska, Iowa, Michigan, Minnesota,
North Dakota, Oregon, and
Wisconsin
No Inspections Performed Arizona, Idaho, Illinois,
Kentucky, Montana, New Mexico, and
Wyoming
States Altering Inspection Regime Alabama: add spot (1982);
California: drop spot (1981);
Colorado: drop annual (1982);
Connecticut: add annual (1982);
Florida: drop annual (1982);
Georgia: drop annual (1982);
Indiana: drop annual (1981), add
annual (1982), drop annual (1984);
Kansas: drop annual (1982), add
spot (1984); Maryland: drop annual
(1982); Nebraska: drop annual
(1982); Nevada: add annual (1981),
drop annual (1982); Ohio; drop
spot (1989); South Dakota: drop
annual (1981); Tennessee: add spot
(1981), drop spot (1982);
Washington: drop spot (1987)
Our empirical model takes the form
[f.sub.it] = [[Alpha].sub.i] + [Beta][prime][multiplied
by][x.sub.it] + [[Epsilon].sub.it], (1)
where [f.sub.it] is the log of a casualty total in state i during
year t and [[Epsilon].sub.it] is a white noise disturbance. The
regressor matrix X consists of variables described below that may affect
the accident rate. Our approach featured several advantages relative to
prior studies of safety inspections. Most importantly, the panel enabled
us to use dummy variables to estimate state-specific shifts in the
fatalities intercept, [[Alpha].sub.i]. We wanted to allow for
state-specific effects because the explanatory variables in X might not
have captured all the factors influencing casualties across states. Many
factors such as geography or policing effort can vary across states in a
nonquantifiable manner. Tests using national-level time-series or
cross-sectional data cannot allow for such state-specific effects.(3) To
obtain consistent estimates, these studies require state-specific
effects to be zero or at least to be uncorrelated with the explanatory
variables. Our estimates indicate that the state-specific effects are
significantly nonzero, and Hausman tests imply that they are not
uncorrelated with the explanatory variables. Under these circumstances,
a fixed-effects model is appropriate.(4) The fixed-effects model uses
the variation in inspection regimes over time to separate the effects of
inspection from those of factors varying only across states. None of the
existing studies on the effectiveness of safety inspections have
estimated a fixed-effects model.
Our empirical specifications also feature a wider set of
explanatory variables, and our data cover more years and more recent
years than previous studies modeling fatalities with pooled data (e.g.,
Snyder 1989; Michener and Tighe 1992). Furthermore, we estimated models
of the rate of nonfatal injuries; previous research considered only
fatalities.(5) A policy variable such as inspection could conceivably have differing effects on fatalities and injuries, especially if
particular causal factors play a relatively greater role in certain
types of accidents. For instance, inspected features such as horn and
turn signals may reduce injuries by preventing low-speed accidents on
local roads but have little effect on deadly high-speed accidents caused
by factors such as reckless driving or environmental conditions.
We defined dummy variables, SPOT and ANNUAL, equaling I if a state
had the particular type of inspection program and 0 otherwise. These
variables permit the empirical model to attribute differing effects to
the two types of inspection.(6) In contrast, some researchers impose the
assumption that the different regimes have equivalent effects by
representing both types with a single dummy variable, and many studies
ignore spot inspection altogether.
Our tests also provide new estimates of the effects of several
other policy variables.(7) Seat belt use reduces the probability of a
fatal or serious injury conditional on an accident of given severity,
but it can elevate accident likelihood and severity by increasing
driving intensity (Peltzman 1975). Following Michener and Tighe (1992),
we distinguished between two types of seat belt law: a primary law that
empowers officers to stop a vehicle for failure to wear seat belts and a
secondary law that requires additional justification for stopping a
motorist. Dummy variables PRIBELT and SECBELT indicate the presence of
primary or secondary seat belt laws. We also used variables representing
the legal speed limit on rural interstate highways (LIMIT) and average
vehicle speed (SPEED). The variable LIQUOR equals a state's legal
age for purchasing hard liquor.
The specification also includes real per capita income (INCOME) and
the percentage of new cars among registered autos (%NEWCARS). Income
increases the demand for both maintenance and driving intensity, which
exert opposing influences on fatalities. The percentage of new cars can
similarly reflect both demand for safety (new cars have more safety
features and experience fewer mechanical failures) and demand for
driving intensity. Peltzman (1975) found that the intensity effect
dominated (fatalities increased with income) in time-series regressions
but that the safety effect dominated in cross-sectional regressions. Our
panel data provided the opportunity for a new test of Peltzman's
hypothesis.
Several control variables complete the model. The variable VSPEED
measures the variance of speed; Lave (1985) found that this variable
affected the probability of an accident. The percentage of vehicle miles
traveled in urban areas (%URBAN) proxies for traffic density. Our
reported models used total vehicle miles (VMILES) as a measure of scale;
we also estimated models using state population as the scale variable.
To control for road quality, we used the level of highway maintenance
expenditures (MAINT) and also included a lagged value of this variable
since road projects require time to build and probably have persistent
effects on road quality. The population percentages of young and old
(%YOUNG, %OLD) and the percentage of males among registered drivers
(%MALE) proxy for driver skill and possible variation in preferences
toward risk or driving intensity.
We also performed tests that focused on changes in fatalities and
injuries at the time of changes in the law. We did this by estimating
the models in first differences, regressing changes in log fatalities or
log injuries on fixed-effect dummy variables, changes in the inspection
law, and changes in the other explanatory variables. The differenced
model may yield inferences more reliable than those of the levels model
if the fatality or injury time series contains a significant unit root
component. Moreover, estimating the model in first differences can
provide a check against the problem of omitted variables. If an omitted
variable changes over time, the fixed-effects model may suffer from bias
in the levels but not in first differences. As a pure hypothetical situation, consider a variable measuring the public's knowledge of
safe driving techniques. Suppose that the average growth rate of the
public's knowledge differs across states and that, all else equal,
states with high growth rates are relatively more likely to terminate
inspections or relatively less likely to adopt inspections. Then, in the
levels specification, knowledge correlates over time with the status of
the inspection regime, resulting in omitted variable bias. The fixed
effects in levels cannot model the effect of knowledge because its level
is not fixed. We can, however, model variation in the average growth
rate of knowledge across states as a fixed effect in first differences.
The differenced specification can yield consistent estimates since
states need not experience extraordinary knowledge growth during the
specific years they happen to change inspection regime.
3. Techniques and Results
The pooled nature of our data creates the potential for problems of
both heteroscedasticity and serial correlation. To help account for time
dependency that might exist in the data and hence reduce serial
correlation, we included a lagged dependent variable in all the models
displayed in Tables 2 and 3. We also included a time trend since
engineering improvements in roads and vehicles may create a downward
trend in accidents. To obtain asymptotically valid inferences, we
employed a Newey-West serial correlation and
heteroscedasticity-consistent covariance matrix. Table 2 presents
estimates of four econometric models of fatalities, in double log form,
and Table 3 presents analagous results for nonfatal injuries. In both
tables, columns a-c report ordinary least squares (OLS) coefficient estimates and Newey-West (1987) standard errors.(8)
Column d of Tables 2 and 3 presents maximum likelihood (ML)
estimates of models that explicitly account for heteroscedasticity as a
function of state size. The heteroscedastic models permitted us to
pursue asymptotically efficient estimates rather than merely rely on
consistency. Since efficiency requires specifying a correct functional
form for the heteroscedasticity, the approach best suits a case where
heteroscedasticity takes a simple form; hence, we assume a scedastic
function of a single variable, with state size an obvious candidate.
Indeed, Goldfeld-Quandt tests strongly attest to the presence of
heteroscedasticity as an inverse function of state size. Given a
dependent variable in log form, the result implies that casualty totals
for smaller [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 2 OMITTED] [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 3
OMITTED] states experience larger random disturbances in percentage
terms. Further examination of the OLS residuals suggests multiplicative heteroscedasticity of the form
[[[Sigma].sub.it].sup.2] = [[Sigma].sup.2][[n.sub.it].sup.[Gamma]],
(2)
where [n.sub.it] corresponds to total vehicle miles in our reported
models and state population in other models.(9) We used the ML technique
to simultaneously estimate the scedastic parameter [Gamma] and the slope
coefficients of the mean equation. Before discussing the results, we
stipulate no relative preference for the ML or OLS results since the
efficiency of ML holds only asymptotically and is subject to correct
specification of the heteroscedasticity Equation 2. In any event, for
our purposes, the two methods yielded similar inferences, as shown
below.
To illustrate the role of fixed effects, we omit them from the
estimated model in column a of Tables 2 and 3. Estimates of the full
fixed-effects specification appear in column b. The fatality results
underscore the importance of modeling state-specific effects.(10)
Estimation of the model without fixed effects indicates that annual
inspection reduces the fatality rate by about 2%, a figure differing
significantly from zero at the 0.05 level. In the fixed-effect
specification, however, the estimated effects of annual and spot
inspections prove neither negative nor significant. The estimated
coefficients for ANNUAL and SPOT are quite small and are insignificantly
different from zero in the injury models, with or without fixed effects.
The statistical insignificance of inspections remains robust across
additional fixed-effect specifications, not reported, including those
using state population as the scale variable.
Estimating fixed effects also reverses inferences on some of the
other variables. Including fixed effects switches the income coefficient
from significantly negative to positive and significant at the 0.01
level in the fatalities model and not quite at the 0.05 level in the
injuries model. Omitting fixed effects suggests that raising the
drinking age significantly increases fatalities, contrary to intuition.
In the fixed-effect model, this result disappears as the coefficient
proves smaller and statistically insignificant. The time trend, current
maintenance expenditures, and %URBAN significantly affect fatalities
only in the fixed-effects model, and the coefficients all have the
intuitive sign.(11) The injuries models yield the reverse pattern for
%URBAN: significant without, but insignificant with, fixed effects. The
coefficient for %OLD proves significantly negative only in the
fatalities model without fixed effects.
Several other control variables have significant estimated
coefficients. The coefficient for lagged maintenance expenditures is
significantly positive in the fatalities models; this counter-intuitive
result may reflect the influence of some omitted variable or merely
indicate that the rate of change, not just the level, of maintenance
expenditures affects road quality. Lagged expenditures are not
significant in the injuries models. The coefficient for new cars proves
significantly positive in all fatalities and injuries specifications;
these results, as well as the positive coefficients for income, concur with Peltzman's driving intensity hypothesis. The coefficient of
the log of vehicle miles is significantly positive in the injuries
models but not in the fixed-effects fatalities model. A lagged dependent
variable proves very significant across models, indicating that
fatalities and injuries exhibit considerable persistence over time.
Column c omits SPOT in order to focus on the role of systematic
annual inspections. If spot inspections have no effect on casualty
rates, then omitting SPOT can increase the efficiency of the estimate of
the ANNUAL coefficient by eliminating the collinearity between ANNUAL
and SPOT (every state with spot inspections has no systematic
inspections). The model in column c also employs the legal speed limit
(LIMIT) as an alternative measure of the effect of vehicle speed. The
LIMIT variable is a positive and significant determinant of fatalities
but not injuries. Otherwise, the results in column c remain essentially
unchanged.
The ML estimates of the heteroscedastic models in column d reaffirm our inferences on the effectiveness of inspection. The estimates of the
coefficients of ANNUAL and SPOT are insignificant for both fatalities
and injuries. The remaining results concur with the OLS estimates,
except that log of vehicle miles and INCOME attain significance at the
0.05 level in both models. These inferences remain robust across
alternative specifications, including those using state population as
the scale variable influencing the heteroscedasticity.
Our results cast doubt on the effectiveness of seat belt laws. In
no regression presented here do the seat belt variables attain
significance; they do, however, achieve significance in some models not
reported here.(12)
The fixed-effect terms exhibit considerable joint significance, as
implied by the Wald test statistics displayed in Tables 2 and 3. We
could alternatively specify these state-specific effects as random,
rather than fixed, effects. The random-effects model treats the
state-specific effect, [[Alpha].sub.i], as a random component of a
composite error term [[Alpha].sub.i] + [[Epsilon].sub.it]. If the
assumptions of the random-effects model hold, the fixed-effects model
yields consistent, but inefficient, estimates. Consistent estimation of
the random-effects model, however, requires the state-specific effect,
[[Alpha].sub.i], to be uncorrelated with the other regressors, a
condition contradicted by our evidence. For instance, feasible generated
least squares estimation of the random-effects model for the full
fatalities specification breaks down by producing a negative estimated
variance of [[Alpha].sub.i], a symptom of insufficient variation in
[[Alpha].sub.i] independent of the regressors.(13) Further, the
assumptions of the random-effects model imply consistency of the pooled
estimates in a; the dramatic change in the estimates caused by adding
fixed effects to the model belies this notion. Hence, the data reject
the random-effects model in favor of the fixed-effects model.
To check that the models exhibit valid statistical properties, we
applied a Ramsey (1969) RESET test. The null hypothesis states that
E[[[Epsilon].sub.it][where][x.sub.it]] = 0, that is, that the model does
not suffer from bias due to omitted variables or misspecified functional
form.(14) At the 0.05 level, the RESET test rejects both the fatality
and injury models that omit fixed effects but fails to reject these same
models when the specification includes fixed effects. Thus, the RESET
tests highlight the importance of modeling fixed effects to avert
specification error.
Table 4 displays least squares estimates of models with variables
in first differences. Columns [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 4 OMITTED] a and b
present estimates using first differences of the log of fatalities as
the dependent variable; the estimates in columns c and d use the
differenced log of injuries as the dependent variable. The table
presents estimates of fixed-effects models in b and d and estimates
without fixed effects in a and c. The results again indicate no
significant negative effect of spot or annual inspections on fatalities
or injuries. The positive and significant estimated coefficients for
income, new cars, and the speed limit concur with the estimates in
Tables 2 and 3. The positive and significant estimated coefficients for
drinking age and annual inspection in the fatalities models are perhaps
difficult to rationalize. The results may reflect a driving intensity
effect or may arise from simultaneity between fatalities and the
inspection and drinking age policies. Hence, we must exercise caution
when interpreting the results of the differenced models. The failure of
the drinking age to significantly improve safety, a result consistently
affirmed by our estimates, does agree with recent work by Asch and Levy
(1990) and Michener and Tighe (1992).
The Wald and adjusted [R.sup.2] criteria reject the fixed-effects
terms in the differenced fatalities model, implying that the levels
specification does not suffer from omitted state-specific trends in
fatalities. Wald and RESET tests, however, suggest that the injuries
model in levels may suffer from omitted state-specific trends. In any
event, the fixed-effects terms in the differenced models do not have a
dramatic effect on the inferences.
4. Conclusions
Several things may account for the failure of safety inspections to
reduce accidents. First, inspections may induce an offsetting increase
in driving intensity. Second, drivers have a strong incentive to perform
maintenance to provide for their own safety: If replacement of a $5
light-bulb yields $6 worth of benefit to the automobile owner, any
external benefit conferred to other drivers becomes irrelevant. Third,
inspections can at best prevent only a small fraction of accidents since
most accidents do not involve mechanical failure: Crain (1980) reports
that failures of vehicle lights (headlights, brake lights, and turn
signals) cause less than 1% of accidents. Finally, annual inspection may
fail to eliminate even the small fraction of accidents caused by
mechanical failure. Annual inspection ensures only that tested parts
function on the date of inspection; if owners wait less than a year to
replace worn-out parts, then annual inspection detects only a portion of
the faulty parts. Additionally, inspectors can fail, intentionally or
unintentionally, to report defects. A Pennsylvania study found that no
type of inspection station (car dealership, service station, or chain
repair shop) managed to find more than 50% of defects in a sample of
vehicles (Crain 1980). Inspectors may fail to report defects to minimize
customer hassle and increase the number of inspections performed;
Hemenway (1989) found evidence that motorists tend to patronize repair
shops with a low failure rate on inspections.
If inspections are ineffective, their cost represents a social
loss. The cost includes fuel and vehicle costs of traveling to the
inspection site, drivers' time, resources used to perform the
inspection, and repairs made to comply with the law. These costs vary
across states according to the density of inspection sites and the set
of safety features subject to inspection. Garbacz and Kelly (1987)
estimated nationwide time and travel costs of $887 million for 1982.
This calculation used averages from New Jersey data of 1.17 hours and 20
travel miles per inspection. Compared to most states, New Jersey
authorizes only a small number of facilities to perform inspections, so
using New Jersey averages likely overestimates national averages. Thus,
we computed updated estimates of the time and travel costs using
conservative assumptions of 0.50 hours and a 10-mile trip. With 54
million automobiles subject to annual inspection and average hourly
earnings of $11.44, the total time cost of annual inspections equaled
$309 million in 1995. Using the Internal Revenue Service (IRS) business
deduction of 31.5 cents per mile for fuel and vehicle wear yields an
annual travel cost of $170 million; hence, estimated time and travel
costs of inspection amounted to $479 million for 1995.(15)
We used inspection fees to estimate the costs of performing
inspections and administering the programs. Although fees are not market
determined and so do not necessarily reflect resource costs, they
provide the best readily available estimate.(16) The total annual
resource cost estimated in this manner is $553 million. The total annual
cost of inspections nationally is thus $1.032 billion, plus the cost of
additional repairs. As a basis for comparison, this sum amounts to about
half of total annual road and highway maintenance expenditures in
California and exceeds total maintenance expenditures summed across 11
small states. Our results suggest that these resources could be more
efficiently invested elsewhere.
Our findings parallel recent studies of the effectiveness of
automobile emission inspections. Emissions are more likely than vehicle
maintenance to be a relevant externality since they externalize a
relatively greater portion of their cost. Tests of emissions systems,
however, present many of the same difficulties as safety inspections.
For instance, the relatively small portion of internalized benefits
enhances the incentive for evasion of the law. In fact, recent studies
have found that emissions inspections are ineffective (Glazer, Klein,
and Lave 1995; Hubbard 1997). The emerging pattern of research suggests
that periodic auto inspection is a poor instrument for achieving policy
goals.
Appendix
FATALS. Log of motor vehicle fatalities. Source: Highway
Statistics.
INJURIES. Log of nonfatal motor vehicle injuries. Source: Highway
Statistics.
%OLD. Population age 65 and older as a percentage of total state
population. Source: Statistical Abstract of the United States.
%YOUNG. Population ages 18-24 as a percentage of total state
population. Source: Statistical Abstract.
SPEED. Mean speed in miles per hour. Source: Highway Statistics.
VSPEED. The speed at or below which 85% of vehicles are traveling
minus the mean speed. Source: Highway Statistics.
LIMIT. Legal speed limit on rural interstate highways. Source:
Digest of Motor Laws.
MAINT. Total highway maintenance expenditures in a state. Source:
Highway Statistics.
INCOME. Real per capita income. Source: Statistical Abstract.
%NEWCARS. New vehicles registered divided by the total number of
registered vehicles. Source: Ward's Automotive Yearbook.
SECBELT. Dummy variable equaling 1 if state has a secondary seat
belt law for at least six months of a given year and 0 otherwise.
Sources: Traffic Safety Facts and Digest of Motor Laws.
PRIBELT. Dummy variable equaling 1 if state has a primary seat belt
law for at least six months of a given year and 0 otherwise. Sources:
Traffic Safety Facts and Digest of Motor Laws.
%MALE. Number of licensed male drivers as percentage of total
licensed drivers. Source: Highway Statistics.
VMILES. Miles traveled per capita in automobiles, buses, and trucks
but not motorcycles. Source: Highway Statistics.
%URBAN. Vehicle miles driven in urban areas divided by total
vehicle miles. Source: Highway Statistics.
LIQUOR. Legal age for purchasing hard liquor. Source: Digest of
Motor Laws.
ANNUAL. Dummy variable equaling 1 if a state requires annual
vehicle safety inspections and 0 otherwise. Source: Digest of Motor
Laws.
SPOT. Dummy variable equaling 1 if a state conducts spot
inspections and 0 otherwise. Source: Digest of Motor Laws.
We thank Tyler Cowen, Harvey Palmer, participants at the 1996
Public Choice Society meetings, and two referees for helpful comments on
an earlier draft of the paper. The conclusions herein do not necessarily
represent the views of the US Bureau of the Census.
1 Note that safety inspections are separate from auto emissions
tests.
2 See Crain (1980) for a detailed legislative history of safety
inspections.
3 Time-series studies evaluate the relationship between fatalities
and the nationwide percentage of cars subject to inspection. The
empirical model implicitly assumes that inspection regime changes in
different states have equivalent effects on fatality rates. But if
inspection has a fixed percentage effect on the fatality rate (i.e., the
relationship is log-linear), then the absolute effect depends on the
state's current fatality rate, which in turn depends on a number of
state-level variables. These time-series studies, however, account for
neither state-specific nor time-varying state-level variables.
4 See also Snyder (1989) and Michener and Tighe (1992) on the
importance of accounting for state-specific effects in an empirical
model of highway fatalities.
5 Loeb (1985) is an exception.
6 We need not allow for interaction effects between the two types
of inspection programs since no state simultaneously employed both
types.
7 See the Appendix for details on the variables and data sources.
8 Using conventional OLS standard errors does not substantively
alter our inferences.
9 We chose the functional form in Equation 2 by estimating a simple
linear regression of log [[[Epsilon].sub.it].sup.2] on [z.sub.it], where
[[[Epsilon].sub.it].sup.2] is the squared residual from an OLS estimate
of Equation 1, and [z.sub.it] measures the scale of state i at time t as
a function of either population or total vehicle miles (depending on the
specification of Eqn. 1). We find this regression to have relatively
more explanatory power with the scale measure [z.sub.it] equal to the
log, rather than the level, of either vehicle miles or population; the
result implies the functional form in Equation 2.
10 The data source for injuries contains a number of missing
observations; the estimates in Table 3 use 553 available observations on
the 50 states for 1981-1993. Note also that, to conserve space, none of
the tables report fixed-effect coefficients.
11 We also estimated models that allowed a more general time effect
by replacing the linear trend with year-specific dummy variables. These
results did not substantively differ from our reported results.
12 In particular, the seat belt variables tend to attain joint
significance in models with injuries measured in per capita terms.
13 Omitting lagged fatalities, which correlate particularly closely
with the state-specific effect, permits FGLS estimation of the
random-effects model to proceed. But in this case, a Hausman test
rejects uncorrelatedness of the remaining regressors and state-specific
effects; the resulting chi-square (17) equals 207.4, with a 1% critical
value of 33.4.
14 We performed a version of the RESET test that uses squares,
cubes, and fourth powers of the fitted values (Ramsey 1969); the
resulting test statistic distributes asymptotically as a chi-square with
three degrees of freedom.
15 We thank a referee for suggesting use of the IRS figure.
16 Delaware permits no fee for inspections, and New Hampshire,
Pennsylvania, and Vermont allow stations to set their own fee. For these
states, we used the average fee in the other states ($9.89). Mark Bertus
kindly supplied data on inspection fees.
References
Asch, Peter, and David T. Levy. 1990. Young driver fatalities: The
roles of drinking age and drinking experience. Southern Economic Journal
57:512-20.
Crain, W. Mark. 1980. Vehicle safety inspection systems: How
effective? Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute.
Digest of motor laws. Various years. Washington, DC: American
Automobile Association.
Fowles, Richard, and Peter D. Loeb. 1995. Effects of policy-related
variables on traffic fatalities: An extreme bounds analysis using
time-series data. Southern Economic Journal 62:359-66.
Garbacz, Christopher. 1990. How effective is automobile safety regulation? Applied Economics 22:1705-14.
Garbacz, Christopher, and J. Gregory Kelly. 1987. Automobile safety
inspection: New econometric and benefit/cost estimates. Applied
Economics 19:763-71.
Glazer, Amihai, Daniel B. Klein, and Charles Lave. 1995. Clean on
paper, dirty on the road: Troubles with California's smog check.
Journal of Transport Economics and Policy 29:85-92.
Hemenway, David. 1989. A failing grade for auto inspections - And
motorists like it that way. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management
8:321-5.
Highway statistics. Various years. Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Printing Office.
Hubbard, Thomas N. 1997. Using inspection and maintenance programs
to regulate vehicle emissions. Contemporary Economic Policy 15:52-62.
Keeler, Theodore E. 1994. Highway safety, economic behavior, and
driving enforcement. American Economic Review 84:684-93.
Lave, Charles A. 1985. Speeding, coordination, and the 55 MPH
limit. American Economic Review 75:1159-64.
Leigh, J. Paul. 1994. Non-random assignment, vehicle safety
inspection laws and highway fatalities. Public Choice 78:373-87.
Loeb, Peter D. 1985. The efficacy and cost-effectiveness of motor
vehicle inspection using cross-sectional data - An econometric analysis.
Southern Economic Journal 52:279-87.
Loeb, Peter D. 1988. The determinants of motor vehicle accidents -
A specification error analysis. Logistics and Transportation Review
24:33-48.
Loeb, Peter D. 1990. Automobile safety inspection: Further
econometric evidence. Applied Economics 22:1697-704.
Loeb, Peter D., and Benjamin Gilad. 1984. The efficacy and
cost-effectiveness of vehicle inspection: A state specific analysis
using time series data. Journal of Transport Economics and Policy
18:145-64.
Michener, Ron, and Carla Tighe. 1992. A Poisson regression model of
highway fatalities. American Economic Review 82:452-6.
Newey, Whitney K., and Kenneth D. West. 1987. A simple, positive
semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent
covariance matrix. Econometrica 55:703-8.
Peltzman, Sam. 1975. The effects of automobile safety regulation.
Journal of Political Economy 83:677-725.
Ramsey, James B. 1969. Tests for specification error in classical
linear least squares regression analysis. Journal of the Royal
Statistical Society B31:250-71.
Saffer, Henry, and Michael Grossman. 1987. Drinking age laws and
highway mortality rates: Cause and effect. Economic Inquiry 25:403-17.
Snyder, Donald. 1989. Speeding, coordination, and the 55-MPH limit:
Comment. American Economic' Review 79:922-5.
Statistical abstract of the United States. Various years.
Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office.
Traffic Safety Facts. 1996. Washington, DC: National Highway
Traffic and Safety Administration.
Ward's Automotive Yearbook. Various years. Detroit: Gale.