The role of innovation in the postentry performance of new small firms: evidence from Italy.
Vivarelli, Marco
1. Introduction
The aim of this paper is to relate the start-up decision to the
postentry performance of new small firms. Hence, this paper is part of
economic research in industrial organization, more specifically of the
study of industrial dynamics.
In the literature focusing on industry dynamics, there are at least
two different strands relevant to the object of this study. On the one
hand, there is the literature devoted to entry and to the start-up
decision; this line of the economic thought has typically examined the
characteristics external to the firm, such as profit expectations in a
given sector, entry barriers, and financial constraints. In this field,
the basic research questions concern the "pull factors" that
can stimulate the entry flow into a given industry. On the other hand,
other studies have tried to link the decision to start a new enterprise
to characteristics specific to the individual founder and his/her
personal background, personal motivation, and sociological environment.
In this field, the basic research issues regard the "push
factors" that can stimulate entry into a given industry. A common
thread running through both strands is that the decision-making horizon
is essentially bounded by the point of entry. In other words, the object
of the story is simply the entry into a given market.
More recently, a growing literature focusing on the postentry
performance of firms has developed. Within this third strand of
literature, research topics include the measurement and determinants of
survival rates, early exit, and the firm's growth. Although the
literature on entry does not pay attention to issues like early exit and
chances of survival, papers on postentry performance generally take
entry as an exogenous occurrence, in some way preliminary to the
analysis. How and why the new firm entered the market is generally
considered to be beyond the scope of such studies.
Nevertheless, one can suppose that the initial population of new
entrants (entrepreneurs) is not likely to be homogeneous in terms of
personal characteristics, motivation, and previous experiences, and it
is plausible to suppose a possible link between these preentry features
and the firm's subsequent postentry performance. In other words,
this paper will address questions such as: does an innovative
entrepreneur have the same chances of postentry profitability as a
conservative one? Does a former blue collar worker have the same chances
as a former manager? Does a defensive motivation for the start-up of a
new firm - such as the avoidance of unemployment - tend to be related to
an inferior postentry performance? Thus, the purpose of this paper is to
provide some insight into the relationship between the decision to start
a new firm and the subsequent postentry performance. In particular, we
relate those factors that are decisive in leading an economic agent to
leave a mother company to start a new firm to the postentry performance
of the new-born enterprise. This enables us to distinguish between the
types of motivation leading to the better or poorer postentry
performance. Although policy conclusions will not be explicitly drawn in
this particular study, the results presented in the following sections
may be of some help in designing national and local industrial policies.
In the second section of this paper a survey of previous studies on
entry and postentry performance will be presented. The dataset, which
consists of a sample of 147 Italian spin-offs, is described in the third
section. In the fourth section the hypothesis that different factors
inducing new-firm start-ups have a disparate effect on the postentry
performance is tested. Finally, the main findings of this study are
briefly summarized.
2. Start-Up of Small Firms and Their Subsequent Early Performance:
A Review of the Literature
Entry has an important role in the model of perfect competition
since an excess level of profitability induces entry into the industry;
that is, if excess profits occur - caused by the opening of a market
niche, a cost-saving innovation, or product differentiation - additional
agents are attracted into the market. In this view, a queue of
well-informed potential entrepreneurs is supposed to be waiting outside
the market, and the expected level of profit is the "pull
factor" determining entry (Khemani and Shapiro 1986; Acs and
Audretsch 1989a; Geroski 1991; Geroski and Schwalbach 1991).
In most of the conventional entry models, the maximization of
expected profits is discounted by taking into account barriers to entry.
In these models, entry is still driven by expected profits, but it is
also hindered by factors such as initial sunk costs, minimum efficient
size, industry-specific features such as innovation, and advertising
expenditure (Mansfield 1962; Orr 1974; Baldwin and Gorecki 1987). More
recently, "strategic barriers to entry" have attracted the
attention of many scholars: in these models entry barriers play a
preemptive role in a game between incumbents and potential entrants
(Tirole 1989, ch. 8). The main shortcoming of this traditional approach
to industrial organization is that by treating the industry market as
the essential unit of observation, it is virtually impossible to take
into account individual characteristics of the potential founder (push
factors). In fact, while the diversification of an existing firm into a
new market can be fully explained through the consideration of expected
profits and (strategic) entry barriers, the study of the foundation of a
new small firm by a single entrepreneur requires a wider perspective.
Indeed, if the unit of observation is the level of the market, this
obscures the decision-making process at the level of the individual
(Winter 1991) and underestimates the factors shaping the
entrepreneur's motivation in starting a new business (McClelland
1961).
As a complement to the simplified view of entry discussed so far, a
different tradition can be singled out in the history of economic
thought: Schumpeter (1911), Knight (1921) and Oxenfeldt (1943) drew
attention to the subjective characteristics of the actual founder of a
new firm. Their well-known definitions of entrepreneurship opened the
way to a more general framework where pull factors are studied together
with some push factors concerning the environment and the particular
situation of the potential founder (for a discussion of push factors
contrasted with pull factors, see Kilby 1971).
This literature is mainly empirical in nature and gives interesting
insights into the actual process of entry. For instance, according to the results of the surveys carried out by Storey (1982) and Johnson
(1986), the founder of a new firm is heavily influenced by his/her own
background, with particular reference to his/her previous job experience
(it has to be taken into account that the vast majority of new firms
originate through spin-off from a mother company: 60% in Storey [1982]
and 68% in Vivarelli [1991]). In other words, his/her entrepreneurial
project is dependent on technical and managerial competence acquired in
the previous job: technical savoir faire, organizational skills,
knowledge of the market, and so on (Bates 1990). Thus, spin-off results
can be affected by the previous hierarchical job position of an
ex-employee (for instance, successful entrepreneurs are more likely to
have been managers involved in supervisory functions). As regards the
personal characteristics of the founder, family background is also
singled out as a key factor by econometric estimates explaining new firm
formation as an act of self-employment (Evans and Leighton 1989; De Wit
and Van Winden 1989). However, other empirical studies tend to play down
the relative importance of this factor in shaping the start-up decision
(Vivarelli 1991).
An interesting way to model entry decision to encompass both pull
and push factors is the so-called "income choice" approach
(Creedy and Johnson 1983; Storey and Jones 1987; Blanchflower and Oswald
1990; Evans and Leighton 1990; Blanchflower and Meyer 1994). In this
theory, a potential founder compares his present income and prospects as
an employee with the expected income from the independent activity; if
this difference is more than a given threshold, whose level depends on
the individual's risk aversion and on particular psychological
aptitudes such as a strong desire to be independent, the new firm will
be founded. While this approach encompasses the traditional view whereby
entry is pulled by expected profits, it also explains some situations
where the founding of the new firm is induced either by uncertainty
about future career perspectives or by a strong psychological motivation
to be independent (for an application of this model to the Italian case,
see Foti and Vivarelli 1994; for a general view of entry and survival
processes in Italy, see Contini and Revelli 1992; Santarelli and
Sterlacchini 1994). Obviously, this model is of particular interest in
modeling the spin-off of previously dependent workers who opt for
self-employment (for theoretical models based on the income choice, see
Lucas 1978; Kihlstrom and Laffont 1979; Blau 1987; Holmes and Schmitz
1990).
In addition, the income choice approach can be adapted to some
situations where the decision to start a new firm is induced either by
unemployment or by fear of becoming unemployed; that is, by a very low
expected income from the present employment. Indeed, this kind of
start-up has been called "escape from unemployment" (Oxenfeldt
1943, cb. 10). Storey and Jones (1987) discovered a percentage of
previously unemployed founders varying between 25 and 50%, whereas
Highfield and Smiley (1987) found evidence for a counter-cyclical
feature of new firm formation (for critical reviews of the escape from
unemployment hypothesis, see Hamilton 1989; Storey 1991).
The literature on the entry process has roots in the history of
economic thought, but a new strand of literature on the postentry
performance of firms has emerged in the last few years (see, for
instance, Reid 1991; Boeri and Cramer 1992; Dunne and Hughes 1994;
Audretsch and Mahmood 1995; Baldwin and Rafiquzzaman 1995; Mata,
Portugal, and Guimaraes 1995). These studies have drawn attention to
issues of industry dynamics such as postentry patterns of survival,
growth, and early exit. In these analyses, cohorts of new firms are
tracked over time and their postentry performance is theoretically
modeled and empirically observed. Here it will be sufficient to focus
attention on those studies that have attempted to relate postentry
performance to some newly founded firms' initial characteristics.
For instance, Dixit (1989) and Hopenhayan (1992) both argue that
postentry performance may be affected by the level of sunk costs in the
industry: higher sunk costs should reduce the likelihood of early exit
since precommitment can be seen as a signal of superior entrepreneurial
capabilities. Other studies are more concerned with industrial rather
than firm characteristics; for example, Audretsch (1995) focuses on the
degree of scale economies in a given industry, arguing that new small
firms not able to grow and to approach the industry's minimum
efficient scale will presumably be characterized either by bad postentry
performance or by early exit (see also, Acs and Audretsch 1989b).
On the whole, although these studies are very useful in
representing the role of entry in determining evolutionary patterns at
industry level (industry differentiation and innovation, Gibrat's
law, patterns of early exit and population renewal, etc.), they say
little about the postentry performance of the single new-born firms. In
this paper, however, the focus of the analysis will be the
microperformances of newly founded firms and how their performances can
be linked to their initial characteristics.
Jovanovic's studies (1982, 1994) are based on the hypothesis
that the income decision resulting in a new entrepreneurial firm and
subsequent postentry performance are formed under a "veil of
ignorance." In this paper the hypothesis is that the determinants
of the starting of a new firm do not have a neutral influence on the
postentry performance. In Jovanovic's framework it is the postentry
learning that matters. In our analysis, postentry performance is
partially predetermined on the basis of the founder's preentry
features. For example (and taking into account both conventional entry
models and the income choice model), if the underlying motivation to
start a new firm is explicitly linked to innovative projects, then a
better postentry performance may be expected than if a new firm is
started on the basis of a purely defensive motivation, such as the fear
of becoming unemployed (for the role of innovation in making a new small
firm successful, see Audretsch 1991; Acs and Audretsch 1990). Similarly,
some deeply rooted psychological motivation, such as the strong desire
to be independent, can hinder a rational and objective consideration of
actual profit expectations for the new firm and jeopardize future
chances of business success. Moreover, a spin-off originated by a
managerial position may have better chances than a spin-off originated
by a low-skilled worker.
More generally (and taking into account that our sample is made up
of new-born firms originated through spin-off), it is important to see
that an individual economic agent's choice to start a new firm
rather than remaining employed in an incumbent organization can be
influenced by many different factors related to the founder's
previous job experience and learning within the mother company (Porter
1980; Storper and Salais 1997, 164 and ff.).
3. Data and Measurement Issues
A database of 147 new manufacturing firms originating through
spin-offs in the Italian province of Milano was constructed on the basis
of returned questionnaires collected in 1996. In order to avoid possible
bias, inconsistencies, and exaggeration which typically affect mail
surveys, questionnaires were filled in during direct phone interviews
conducted by interviewers previously trained by the authors.
The database includes only entirely new firms set up in 1989 and
1990 and surviving up to the time of the interview (1996). Thus, it
consists solely of surviving firms; this creates a particular bias in
that early failures are excluded from the analysis. However, a variance
in business performance within surviving firms was sufficiently large to
ensure that the survivor bias would not be particularly worrying for the
purposes of this study. We will not be able to address the issues
concerning early exit versus survival, but we will focus on performance
differentials among surviving spin-offs.
The firms included in the database were randomly selected according
to the local industrial structure with the assistance of lists from the
local Chamber of Commerce. From an initial sample of 439 new-born firms,
any start-up that was either a new branch of an incumbent enterprise or
simply a nominal legal transformation of an existing firm was eliminated
from the database. Next, the interviewers selected only the new founders
who were previously employed in existing firms (spin-off). The resulting
subsample consisted of 226 cases, out of which 147 entrepreneurs allowed
interviews.
As previously mentioned, the entire sample was found in the Milano
province, which is the most industrialized and advanced local economic
system in Italy. The province industrial structure is deeply diversified and does not exhibit idiosyncratic features such as a specific sectoral
specialization (in contrast with most industrial districts located in
northwest and central Italy), the presence of a dominant large firm (as
in Torino with the presence of FIAT), or the prevailing weight of the
public sector (as in the south of Italy). In addition, national and
local industrial policy, although not completely absent, does not appear
to have significantly affected the structure and the performance of the
local economy. Hence, the degree of generalizability of this particular
empirical study appears to be sufficiently high, though limited to
industrialized, advanced local economic systems.
The questionnaire has a qualitative/quantitative nature: together
with personal qualitative characteristics and background, the founder
interviewed was asked to give a score (from 0 to 10) to motivations and
factors that had been relevant to shaping his/her start-up decision.
Most of the interviewed entrepreneurs had set up very small firms after
leaving larger but still small mother firms; 90.4% of those interviewed
had fewer than five employees at start-up, while 52.9% of the mother
companies had fewer than 10 employees (although 34.8% had more than 20
employees). All those interviewed had at least one employee, so pure
self-employment has been excluded from the analysis and the results
focused on the spin-off of a new (although small) firm from an incumbent
firm. In addition, mean start-up investment costs proved very low (about
U.S. $60,000) and only partially sunk (on average, 2/3 of the initial
investment was considered irreversible). On the basis of these results,
one can say that barriers to entry do not play an important role in
deterring spin-offs in Italian manufacturing.
The database was used to construct, through a factor analysis, a
joint measure of postentry performance. This measure takes into account
both annual postentry employment growth and the relative profitability
of the new-born firm (in comparison with the sectoral average). Although
the second measure is the standard way of appraising a firm's
performance, annual employment growth has been chosen as a second
objective measure of new-born firms' performance, since these firms
generally start very small and they decide to hire new employees only in
the case of very positive expectations regarding current and future
incomes. Although virtually all firms within this sample entered the
market at suboptimal size, and so all of them "needed to
grow," one can argue that in different sectors the specific levels
of the minimum efficient scale call for different paces of employment
growth for new entries that want to survive. These considerations
support the decision to check for sectoral fixed effects when a newly
founded firm's performance is analyzed. Thus, the regressions
explaining firm performance with different determinants will be
characterized by the inclusion of sectoral dummies (see below).
The empirical tests carried out in the following section will
follow a three step procedure.
(i) Answers to the questionnaire will be processed and resulting
rankings will be commented on, trying to underline the main determinants
of new firm formation with regard to both personal background and
motivation and to learning and competence accumulated in the mother
firm.
(ii) All factors will be grouped by factor and cluster analyses,
with the purpose of singling out some dominant profiles that may help to
construct a taxonomy of different categories of spin-offs.
(iii) Factors and clusters derived by steps i and ii will be used,
together with other isolated characteristics and checking by means of
sectoral dummies, as regressors of an econometric analysis for the
explanation of postentry performance across the sample of 147 spin-offs.
4. Empirical Results
Each entrepreneur ranked each factor from a scale of 0 (indicating
a minimal influence on the start-up decision) to 10 (indicating a
maximal influence on the start-up decision). The median ranking of those
factors influencing the decision to start a new firm is reported in
Table 1 together with means, standard deviations, and variation
coefficients for each answer (the ranking according to the average
scores would prove very similar to that shown in Table 1).
Although it is not explicitly the purpose of this study, it can be
seen that the ranking of factors shaping the entrepreneurial decision is
consistent with the findings in the literature discussed in section 2.
As Storey (1982), Johnson (1986), and Vivarelli (1991) found, the desire
to be independent turns out to be the most decisive factor underlying
the decision to start a new firm. Indeed, at the top of the ranking we
find the desire to manage one's working time and the refusal to
carry out tasks for others.
Although the perceived potential for income increase is somewhat
less important (median = 6), it still plays an important role;
interestingly enough, profit expectations are more related to demand
factors (the openness of a market niche) than to supply factors (belief
in introducing an innovation).
In fact, innovative motivation ranks in the middle of the list
(marketing innovation = 5; process innovation = 4; product innovation =
2). This result is consistent with previous research on the start-up of
Italian small firms (Vivarelli 1991, p. 220). However, although
innovative determinants are not dominant within the population of new
founders, they might be relevant to the superior postentry performance
of the subsample of better entrepreneurs (see below).
Turning attention to personal motivation connected with previous
job experience, the attempt [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 1 OMITTED] to create
a situation where an economic agent's human capital is more fully
deployed seems to play an important role in the entrepreneurial
decision. Disagreement about the general managing criteria of the mother
firm is the fifth factor in the ranking (median = 5), and undervaluation of skills is the seventh (median = 4). Other more specific forms of
disagreement with the management of the mother firm follow: the
undervaluation of technological opportunities (median = 3) and the waste
of market opportunities (median = 1).
Fear of unemployment and scepticism about the future prospects of
the mother firm turn out to be minor motivations (median = 1), although
concern about future career developments scores higher (median = 3). On
the whole, defensive motivations are not very common, although they may
be relevant to a minority of new potential entrepreneurs. Finally, these
spinoffs were not supported by the mother firms (median score = 0).
As can be deduced from the reported standard deviation values, the
population of new founders shows a quite large variability in the
motivation leading to start-up. In other words, although motivation can
be ranked, new founders seem to be quite heterogeneous. It could
therefore be useful to construct a typology of entrepreneurs.
This exercise has been conducted with the help of a factor
analysis, with results being reported in Table 2. The results of the
statistical inference are both satisfactory (the explained variance is
more than 60%) and interesting.
The first factor (F1) is undoubtedly connected with innovative
motivation, expressed in all its different forms (four questions in the
questionnaire). Moreover, innovative factors are related to actual
market opportunities (two questions). F2 is made up of a group of
motivations related to the previous frustration within the mother
company and to the desire to better exploit different opportunities that
were inadequately valued in the mother firm. F3 is a defensive factor
both in terms of fear of losing one's job and of scepticism about
future career opportunities. Finally, factor F4 is a residual factor
mainly connected with the desire to be independent coupled with profit
expectations.
Table 2. Factor Analysis of Motives for Founding the New Firm
(Factor Scores [greater than] 0.40)
F1 F2 F3 F4
V11H 0.793
V11C 0.782
V11I 0.775
V11O 0.560
V11Q 0.518 0.445
V11E 0.824
V11B 0.781
V11D 0.488 0.691
V11L 0.881
V11N 0.776
V11G 0.747
V11P 0.810
V11F 0.776
V11A 0.598
V11M -0.458
Total variance explained: 60.1%; % of variance: F1 = 27.8;
F2 = 12.9; F3 = 11.8; F4 = 7.8.
Key: V11A, perceived potential for income increase; V11B,
disagreement about the general managing criteria of the mother firm;
V11C, belief in introducing a marketing innovation; V11D,
underestimation of technological opportunities by the mother firm;
V11E, underestimation of skills by the mother firm; V11F, desire to
manage one's working time; V11G, concern about future career
developments; V11H, belief in introducing a product innovation;
V11I, belief in introducing a process innovation; V11L, fear of
becoming unemployed; V11M, support from the mother firm; V11N,
scepticism about prospects of the mother firm; V11O, openness of a
market niche; V11P, refusal to carry out tasks for others; V11Q,
waste of market opportunities by the mother firm.
Table 3 is similar to Table 1, but it concerns the learning process
that occurred in the mother firm and that may have played a role in
shaping the start-up decision and in determining postentry performance.
As can be clearly seen, acquired technical capabilities are ranked
as the most important preconditions for start-up. On the other hand, and
consistent with the results shown in Table 1, innovative learning is not
so common among the founders interviewed (the four innovative forms of
learning are all among the last five items in the ranking list). In the
mid-ranking, there are both managerial learned competences
(organization, accounting, finance) and entrepreneurial abilities
(information, personal contacts, knowledge of the market and the
cost-benefit approach).
All these determinants linked to previous job experience are
grouped into three factors, according to the results of a second factor
analysis shown in Table 4.
The outcome of the factor analysis explains almost 55% of the
entire variance and singles out three factors. FF1 groups together all
technical capabilities and entrepreneurial skills, FF2 is clearly
defined and picks up the four forms of learning connected with
innovation, and FF3 consists of managerial skills.
In general, the two factor analyses (Tables 2, 4) are sufficiently
clear-cut and the seven factors can be used in an attempt to explain
postentry performance. The regression analysis is threefold: the first
regression relates postentry performance (as defined in the previous
section) to the four factors (F) derived from personal motivation; the
second regression relates postentry performance to the three factors
(FF) derived from learning in the mother firm; the third regression
relates postentry performance to three dummy variables, which have been
built on the basis of a cluster analysis run on the seven factors F and
FF. The resulting clusters are the [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 3 OMITTED]
innovative firms (19 firms, where F1 and FF2 are the dominant factors),
the experience firms (47 firms, where F2 and FF3 are dominant), and the
defensive plus residual firms (81 firms, where F3, F4, and FF1 are
dominant).
Table 4. Factor Analysis of Competence Accrued in the Mother Firm
(Factor Scores [greater than] 0.40)
FF1 FF2 FF3
V25B 0.815
V25A 0.797
V25E 0.762
V25D 0.718
V25C 0.688
V25G 0.681
V25H 0.517
V25F 0.436
V25L 0.816
V25P 0.736
V25Q 0.682
V25I 0.679
V25O 0.794
V25N 0.733
V25M 0.648
V25S 0.426 0.489
Total variance explained: 54.9%; % of variance: FF1 = 34.2;
FF2 = 11.8; FF3 = 8.8.
Key: V25A, knowledge of the final market; V25B, specific technical
skills, V25C, personal contacts; V25D, knowledge of competing firms;
V25E, knowledge of the market of raw materials and intermediate
goods; V25F, knowledge of unexploited opportunities; V25G, technical
knowledge; V25H, production process management; V25I, experience in
developing new products; V25L, experience in new equipment
engineering; V25M, general management competence; V25N, marketing
skills; V25O, administrative skills; V25P, involvement in advanced
technological projects; V25Q, opportunity to check product/process
innovation; V25S, cost-benefit analysis of new entrepreneurial
projects.
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 5 OMITTED]
All regressions have been controlled for both sectoral effects
(dummy variables included in all the regressions reported in Table 5,
except e) and objective characteristics of the newborn firm: initial
size, size of the mother firm, number of business partners, years of
previous founder's job experience, founder's level of
education, founder's previous hierarchical job position. Among all
these variables, only the last was positively and significantly
connected with postentry performance and has been retained in the final
regression analysis. The status of the previous job position of the
entrepreneur (position) has been measured on a scale from 1 (low-skilled
worker) to 6 (top manager). All regressions have been submitted to
heteroscedasticity tests, and White's correction has been used when
necessary.
Regressions a and b refer to the four factors derived from the
revealed motivation leading to the start-up. A clear-cut result is that
innovative motivation (F1) is positively and significantly (99%)
connected with superior postentry performance. Although the other three
factors were not significant, it is of some interest to notice that
defensive motivation (F3) is characterized by the lowest coefficients
and degrees of significance. The inclusion of the previous job position
does not affect the results and confirms the positive role of previous
managerial experience in supporting better postentry performance
(although the coefficient is just barely significant).
Regressions c and d are instead based on factors that have been
derived from the revealed importance of different job experience within
the mother firm. Again, learning connected with innovative activities
(FF2) is strongly linked with better postentry performance and shows a
high degree of statistical significance. On the other hand, the other
forms of learning, although characterized by positive coefficients, do
not exhibit a sufficient degree of significance. The inclusion of the
additional regressor "position" does not change the results
and consistently shows the positive influence of previous job experience
in a higher hierarchical position.
Interestingly enough, both regressions a and c throw some light on
what is commonly known as managerial efficiency. Indeed, factor analyses
presented in Tables 2 and 4 are built on the different features that may
cause different degrees of managerial efficiency within the spin-off
firm. Instead of treating managerial effects as dummy variables,
regressions a and c directly relate factors to the firm's
performance. However, one can argue that these regressions might be
affected by the omission of an additional direct measure of managerial
effort. In order to check for this possible bias, regressions a and c
have been rerun including an additional regressor measuring the weight
of managerial and coordination expenditure as a percentage of the
firm's total expenditure. Both regressions are robust regarding
this additional control: results reported in Table 5 remain virtually
unchanged, both in terms of coefficient values and in terms of their
statistical significance, while the additional regressor turns out to be
of the expected sign (positive), but not significant (t = 1.39 in the
modified regression a and t = 1.11 in the modified regression c).
Regression e is based on the cluster analysis described above and
shows, once again, the positive and significant effect of an innovative
background (innovative motivation plus innovative experience). This
result is not surprising and is consistent with the positive effect of
F1 and FF2, the "constituent factors" of the innovative
cluster. In addition, the defensive cluster shows a negative, though
barely significant, influence on postentry performance. This result
gives some support to the hypothesis that when avoidance of unemployment
or career concern are motivating forces behind the entrepreneurial
decision, the subsequent postentry performance tends to be worse.
On the whole, the most unambiguous result in Table 5 concerns the
positive roles of innovative motivation and experience in promoting a
better postentry performance of newly founded firms.
5. Conclusions
The start-up of new small firms is not a homogeneous phenomenon:
different motivation and different previous job experience lead to
different forms of spin-offs, which can be characterized by very
different postentry business performances.
One of the main conclusions of this study is that the postentry
performance of new firms originated by spin-off does not seem neutral
regarding the motivation and job experience that led the economic agent
to the decision to start a new firm. In other words, the questions posed
in the introduction of this study turn out to be relevant; that is,
innovative motivation and job experience in innovative activities tend
to be linked to a superior postentry performance.
In contrast, there is some evidence that defensive motivation such
as the avoidance of possible or actual unemployment seems to be a
predictor of a poorer postentry performance. Finally, a high position in
the previous job tends to be positively correlated with postentry
performance.
Since the sample used in this study does not appear to be
significantly biased by idiosyncratic local and institutional factors
(see section 3), these conclusions could be applied to other advanced
and industrialized local economic systems. However, this work opens the
way to further research on a subject that seems to be of some importance
in explaining industry dynamics.
We thank Elisabetta Arcaini for careful research assistance; the
financial contribution from the Chamber of Commerce of Milano is
gratefully acknowledged.
References
Acs, Zoltan J., and David B. Audretsch. 1989a. Small-firm entry in
US manufacturing. Economica 56:255-65.
Acs, Zoltan J., and David B. Audretsch. 1989b. Births and firm
size. Southern Economic Journal 56:467-75.
Acs, Zoltan J., and David B. Audretsch. 1990. Innovation and small
firms. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Audretsch, David B. 1991. New-firm survival and the technological
regime. Review of Economics and Statistics 73:441-50.
Audretsch, David B. 1995. Innovation and industry evolution.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Audretsch, David B., and Talat Mahmood. 1995. New firm survival:
New results using a hazard function. Review of Economics and Statistics
77:97-103.
Baldwin, John R., and Paul K. Gorecki. 1987. Plant creation versus
plant acquisition: The entry process in Canadian manufacturing.
International Journal of Industrial Organization 5:27-41.
Baldwin, John R., and Mohammed Rafiquzzaman. 1995. Selection versus
evolutionary adaptation learning and post-entry performance.
International Journal of Industrial Organization 13:501-22.
Bates, Timothy. 1990. Entrepreneur human capital inputs and small
business longevity. Review of Economics and Statistics 72:551-59.
Blanchflower, D., and B. Meyer. 1994. A longitudinal analysis of
young entrepreneurs in Australia and the United States. Small Business
Economics 6:1-20.
Blanchflower, D., and A. Oswald. 1990. What makes an entrepreneur?
NBER Working Paper No. 3252.
Blau, David M. 1987. A time series analysis of self-employment in
the United States. Journal of Political Economy 95:445-67.
Boeri, Tito, and Ulrich Cramer. 1992. Employment growth, incumbents
and entrants: Evidence from Germany. International Journal of Industrial
Organization 10:545-66.
Contini, Bruno, and Riccardo Revelli. 1992. Imprese, occupazione e
retribuzioni al microscopio. Bologna: il Mulino.
Creedy, J., and Peter S. Johnson. 1983. Firm formation in
manufacturing industry. Applied Economics 15:177-85.
De Wit, Gerrit, and Frans A.A.M. Van Winden. 1989. An empirical
analysis of self-employment in the Netherlands. Small Business Economics
1:263-72.
Dixit, Avinash. 1989. Entry and exit decisions under uncertainty.
Journal of Political Economy 97:620-38.
Dunne, Paul, and Alan Hughes. 1994. Age, size, growth and survival:
UK companies in the 1980s. Journal of Industrial Economics 42:115-40.
Evans, David S., and Linda S. Leighton. 1989. Some empirical
aspects of entrepreneurship. American Economic Review 79:519-35.
Evans, David S., and Linda S. Leighton. 1990. Small business
formation by unemployed and employed workers. Small Business Economics
2:319-30.
Foti, Alessandro, and Marco Vivarelli. 1994. An econometric test of
the self-employment model: The case of Italy. Small Business Economics
6:81-93.
Geroski, Paul A. 1991. Domestic and foreign entry in the United
Kingdom: 1983-1984. In Entry and market contestability: An international
comparison, edited by Paul Geroski and Joachim Schwalbach. Oxford: Basil
Blackwell.
Geroski, Paul A., and Joachim Schwalbach (eds.). 1991. Entry and
market contestability: An international comparison. Oxford: Basil
Blackwell.
Hamilton, R. T. 1989. Unemployment and business formation rate:
Reconciling time-series and cross-section evidence. Environment and
Planning 21:249-55.
Highfield, Richard, and Robert Smiley. 1987. New business starts
and economic activity: An empirical investigation. International Journal
of Industrial Organization 5:51-66.
Holmes, Thomas J., and James A. Schmitz, Jr. 1990. A theory of
entrepreneurship and its application to the study of business transfer.
Journal of Political Economy 98:265-94.
Hopenhayan, Hugo. 1992. Entry, exit and firm dynamics in long run
equilibrium. Econometrica 60:1127-50.
Johnson, Peter S. 1986. New firms: An economic perspective. London:
Allen & Unwin.
Jovanovic, Boyan. 1982. Selection and evolution of industry.
Econometrica 50:649-70.
Jovanovic, Boyan. 1994. Firm formation with heterogeneous
management and labor skills. Small Business Economics 6:185-91.
Khemani R. S., and D. M. Shapiro. 1986. The determinants of new
plant entry in Canada. Applied Economics 18:1243-57.
Kihlstrom, Richard E., and Jean-Jacques Laffont. 1979. A general
equilibrium entrepreneurial theory of firm formation based on risk
aversion. Journal of Political Economy 87:719-48.
Kilby, Peter (ed.). 1971. Entrepreneurship and economic
development. London: Freeprint.
Knight, Frank H. 1921. Uncertainty and profit. New York: Houghton
Mifflin.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr. 1978. On the size distribution of business
firms. Bell Journal of Economics 9:508-23.
Mansfield, Edwin. 1962. Entry, Gibrat's law, innovation and
the growth of firms. American Economic Review 52:1023-51.
Mata, Jose, Pedro Portugal, and Paulo Guimaraes. 1995. The survival
of new plants: Start-up conditions and post-entry evolution.
International Journal of Industrial Organization 13:459-82.
McClelland, D. 1961. The achieving society. Princenton: D. Van
Nostran.
Orr, Dale. 1974. The determinants of entry: A study of the Canadian
manufacturing industries. Review of Economics anti Statistics 56:58-66.
Oxenfeldt, A. R. 1943. New firms and free enterprise: Pre-war and
post-war aspects. Washington: American Council on Public Affairs.
Porter, Michael. E. 1980. Competitive strategy: Techniques for
analysing industries and competitors. New York: Free Press.
Reid, Gavin C. 1991. Staying in business. International Journal of
Industrial Organization 9:545-56.
Santarelli, Enrico, and Alessandro Sterlacchini. 1994. New firm
formation in Italian industry: 1985-1989. Small Business Economics
6:95-106.
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1911. Theorie der wirtschaftlichen
Entwicklung. Eine Untersuchung uber Unternehmergewinn, Kapital, Kredit,
Zins und den Konjunkturzyklus. Berlin: Duncker und Hublot (The Theory of
Economic Development. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1912).
Storey, David J. 1982. Entrepreneurship and the new firm. London:
Croom Helm.
Storey, David J. 1991. The birth of new firms: Does unemployment
matter? Small Business Economics 3:167-78.
Storey, David J., and A. M. Jones. 1987. New firm formation - A
labor market approach to industrial entry. Scottish Journal of Political
Economy 34:37-51.
Storper, Michael, and Robert Salais. 1997. Worlds of production.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Tirole, Jean. 1989. The theory of industrial organization.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Vivarelli, Marco. 1991. The birth of new enterprises. Small
Business Economics 3:215-23.
Winter, Sidney G. 1991. On coarse, competence, and the corporation.
In The nature of the firm: Origins, evolution and development, edited by
Oliver E. Williamson and Sidney G. Winter. Oxford: Oxford University
Press, pp. 179-95.