首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月28日 星期四
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Luxury Fever: Why Money Fails to Satisfy in an Era of Excess.
  • 作者:Walker, Douglas M.
  • 期刊名称:Southern Economic Journal
  • 印刷版ISSN:0038-4038
  • 出版年度:1999
  • 期号:July
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Southern Economic Association
  • 摘要:New York: The Free Press, 1999. Pp. x, 326. $25.00.
  • 关键词:Book reviews;Books

Luxury Fever: Why Money Fails to Satisfy in an Era of Excess.


Walker, Douglas M.


By Robert H. Frank.

New York: The Free Press, 1999. Pp. x, 326. $25.00.

Professor Frank's new book contains elements of his previous works, especially his 1995 book with Cook. I was somewhat hostile to the ideas of that book (Walker 1996), but after reading Frank's new one, I must admit - he's convinced me! This book is well written, effectively argued, and entertaining.

The primary focus of the book is on the importance of relative versus absolute consumption levels in affecting consumers' happiness. Frank reviews compelling biological and psychological evidence that happiness is not significantly linked to absolute levels of consumption but is linked to relative levels. (If readers are not swayed by Frank's appeal to scientific evidence, then perhaps they should read Seneca, Marcus Aurelius, or Boethius.) According to Frank, this aspect of human nature largely explains why many are compelled to spend money on luxuries just to appear to be more successful than others. He regards the increasing amount of luxury spending as wasteful, since these consumers could obtain the same benefits by consuming luxuries with lower price tags, so long as the positional aspect of the consumption remains unchanged. For example, if I am interested in signaling my financial success to others, I may be inclined to buy a Patek Philippe wristwatch for $20,000. But the quality of this as a signal of my wealth is not dependent so much on the high price tag as it is on the fact that it's a relatively expensive watch. I could just as easily signal my wealth in a different world, where 95% of people spend under $100 on a watch, by purchasing, say a $1,500 watch. If relative (not absolute) consumption patterns affect happiness, then many of the luxuries that are produced are wasteful, since much cheaper luxuries could be produced that still retain their high relative values. The resources currently dedicated to producing extravagant luxuries could alternatively be used in ways that would significantly improve our standards of living. Frank summarizes,

Considerable evidence suggests that if we all work longer hours to buy bigger houses and more expensive cars, we do not end up any happier than before. As for whether money could buy happiness, however, the evidence paints a very different picture. The less we spend on conspicuous consumption goods, the better we can afford to alleviate [traffic] congestion; the more time we can devote to family and friends, to exercise, sleep, travel, and other restorative activities; and the better we can afford to maintain a clean and safe environment. On the best available evidence, reallocating our time and money in these ways would result in healthier, longer, and more satisfying lives (p. 92).

There is an opportunity cost to producing $3 million, diamond dream bras.

The first part of the book is rather convincing in its point that the conspicuous consumption that characterizes our current society is worthy of concern and perhaps should be curtailed. Improvements (some suggestions are noted above) can be made simply by slowing the rate of growth in the consumption of luxuries. But if this rearrangement of spending patterns would be so beneficial, wouldn't people already be doing it? The root of the problem, Frank argues, is that conspicuous consumption is akin to negative externalities problems in the sense that it's "smart for one, dumb for all"; that is, the conspicuous spending is rational for the individual but harmful from a social perspective. (Frank explains this situation thoroughly, citing cases typically discussed by economists, e.g., overuse of common property resources.) To bring private incentives more in line with the social, government action is required.

Obviously, free-market advocates are likely to object to any government policy that attempts to curtail consumers' liberties. Frank fully anticipates these objections and is very effective in dispelling them.

The last part of the book is dedicated to explaining Frank's policy proposal. The anticipation of this was rather exciting. By the time he finally presents his solution, Frank has made a thoroughly convincing case that there is indeed a problem that needs correction and that with some very simple policy changes, the problem could be solved. Finally, the author suggests we adopt a steeply progressive consumption tax to replace the current system of income and sales taxes. A component of the tax structure would be a minimum level of consumption exempted from the tax (and possibly a lump-sum subsidy to those below a minimum income threshold). Of course, he goes into moderate detail about the mechanics of the tax, as well as benefits and typical objections to consumption taxes. This presentation is accessible to noneconomists and is effective in refuting objections and in arguing that it effectively solves the conspicuous-consumption problem highlighted in the first part of the book.

A sample tax rate schedule is offered, ranging from a 20% rate on consumption spending (above the exemption) up to $40,000 to a rate of 70% on consumption spending of between $500,000 to $1 million. In such a world, for example, half-million dollar Ferraris would become even more rare, and "the Porsche would acquire precisely the rarefied status of today's exotic cars, which was all that kept it from being attractive to Ferrari buyers in the first place" (p. 218). In this way, the wealthiest people would still have the most exotic cars, but those cars would be less expensive than before. Wouldn't this destroy certain firms and industries? "The point is not to put companies like Ferrari and Patek Philippe out of business, but simply to slow the rate at which additional resources are devoted to making all products - not just theirs - more opulent" (p. 221).

A major benefit of the consumption tax Frank describes is that it encourages savings. This, in turn, would enhance long-term economic growth, as well as consumers' future consumption possibilities. Significantly, the curtailed current spending on luxuries would make no one worse off, since the tax would not affect the positional nature of spending, on which the utility of consumption is (partially) dependent.

Frank is not the first author to propose a progressive consumption tax. However, his rationale for it is, I think, unique. That this tax could actually improve happiness is a very strong argument in its favor and should be included in the current debate over tax reform. Overall, Professor Frank's exposition is entertaining and controversial and should be enjoyed by all readers interested in public policy.

References

Frank, Robert H., and Philip J. Cook. 1995. The winner-take-all society. New York: The Free Press.

Walker, Douglas M. 1996. The winner-take-all society (book review). Southern Economic Journal 63:550-51.

Douglas M. Walker Georgia College & State University
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有