Static and dynamic externalities, industry composition, and state labor productivity: a panel study of states.
Rickman, Dan S.
1. Introduction
The recent popularity of macroeconomic endogenous growth models has
spurred interest in regional economic growth. A primary focus of the
endogenous growth literature is the relationship between geographic
concentration of production and regional productivity.(1) Geographic
concentration of firms within an industry can facilitate spillovers of
knowledge and innovations among them, increasing the industry's
productivity in the area. These spillovers have become commonly referred
to as localization or Marshall-Arrow-Romer (MAR) externalities (e.g.,
Romer 1986). Similarly, spillovers also may occur among firms of
different industries that are located in close proximity, which are
commonly referred to as urbanization or Jacobs externalities (Jacobs
1969). In addition, geographic proximity also may reduce costs of
transporting intermediate inputs, representing a pecuniary spillover (Krugman 1991).
Several empirical regional studies related to geographic
concentration of economic activity and economic spillovers emphasize
their relationship to employment growth, only indirectly testing the
externality-productivity relationship (e.g., Glaeser et al. 1992;
Henderson, Kuncoro, and Turner 1995; Partridge and Rickman 1996;
Henderson 1997). Also, studies of regional productivity differences
typically focus on static urbanization and localization economies and
not on dynamic externality effects emphasized in the endogenous growth
literature (e.g., Moomaw 1983, 1986). In addition, although Ciccone and
Hall (1996) examined the relationship between density of production and
state labor productivity, they relied on cross-sectional analysis.
Cross-sectional analyses ignore unobserved fixed factors that may
underlie the productivity differences, such as those arising from the
region's history, leaving open the possibility that the estimated
determinants of productivity are biased.(2)
Previous regional productivity studies also did not isolate the two
different ways that a region's productivity can be above the
national average: (i) having a mix of industries that are highly
productive and (ii) having existing industries more productive than
their respective industry's national average. This distinction is
important if the alternative sources of externalities affect the
composition of industries differently than they affect productivity for
all existing industries. For example, suppose industry concentration
tends to attract a more productive concentration of industries, while
industry diversity raises the productivity for all existing industries.
The offsetting effects of industry concentration and industry diversity
economies would be unobservable when only examining total productivity.
In this paper, we use panel data for the contiguous states of the
U.S. to examine directly the relationship between externalities and
labor productivity. Although urban areas are thought to be most
associated with economic externalities (Lucas 1988), there are
advantages to using state data. Foremost, because production is reported
annually at the state level, we can consider directly predictions of
recent growth models that emphasize productivity, whereas county and
metropolitan studies must rely on employment growth (an indirect test of
the productivity-externality link). Likewise, if there are economic
spillovers across county or metro borders, examining state data captures
most of these effects. Finally, studies examining cities or metro areas omit rural areas. Yet if urbanization is an important phenomenon, a
state like North Dakota would be at a significant productivity
disadvantage, making it a valuable observation in a regional
productivity study.(3)
Our empirical approach involves fixed effects estimation of state
panel data, which controls for the influence of omitted time-invariant
state-level variables. This approach also allows us to distinguish
between the effects of static externalities versus dynamic
externalities.(4) Using a novel two-stage approach, we search for both
contemporaneous static effects and dynamic effects that either persist
or take longer to develop. In another innovation, we assess the
influence of externalities on productivity in each industry as well as
determine whether externality effects influence a state's
composition of industries. The distinction has public policy
implications in that states have choices related to attracting
high-productivity industries versus increasing productivity in all
existing industries.
2. Theoretical Framework
Because of state policy makers' interest in wage rates and per
capita income, we focused on the determinants of labor productivity. In
so doing, we followed other studies (e.g., Ciccone and Hall 1996) by
directly relating labor productivity to its determinants. This avoided
estimating a production function, which typically involves imposing
restrictions to derive total factor productivity estimates or estimates
of returns to scale.(5) Nevertheless, the disadvantage of our approach
was that we were unable to address the precise production channel
through which variables influenced labor productivity. In addition,
consistent with the literature on regional and national productivity, we
examined productivity aggregates, which implies that caution should be
exercised in interpreting the results.(6)
Measuring Labor Productivity
Because states differ in theft composition of industries, it is
likely that some of the state differences in productivity are due to
their relative concentrations of high- and low-productivity industries.
To be sure, in a survey of the regional productivity literature, Gerking
(1994, p. 182) suggests that future research on productivity adjust for
industry mix to better understand "the forces that contribute to
productivity growth rates." At best, past productivity studies have
included one-digit industry shares in productivity regression equations (e.g., Carlino and Voith 1992) or examined the determinants for
particular detailed industries (e.g., Moomaw 1986). As far as we know,
no study has separated regional productivity differences into the
portion due to regional differences in industry concentration and the
portion due to productivity differences in each industry across regions.
Also, it has been unexplored whether a state's composition of
industries is related to dynamic externalities. The significance of this
point is that it may be more difficult for states to contemporaneously alter their industrial compositions if dynamic externalities exist since
dynamic externalities make state industrial compositions dependent on
their histories (Henderson 1997).
Therefore, using Bureau of Economic Analysis Gross State Product
(GSP) data, we construct a measure of relative state labor productivity
(PROD) as GSP or output (Q), divided by labor input (L), all divided by
the same for the nation. An advantage of normalizing by the nation is
that it nets out national business cycle effects and long-term
productivity trends that are common across all states. We then decompose PROD into two components. The first component of relative state labor
productivity relates to its concentration of industries (PROD_MIX). The
second component is then calculated as the remaining productivity
difference, which is the average relative productivity in each industry,
or relative productivity competitiveness (PROD_COMP). The corresponding
mathematical expressions are:
[PROD.sub.k] = ([Q.sub.k]/[L.sub.k])/([Q.sub.u]/[L.sub.u]), (1)
[PROD.sub.k] = PROD_[MIX.sub.k] x PROD_[COMP.sub.k], (2)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], (3)
PROD_[COMP.sub.k] = [PROD.sub.k]/PROD_[MIX.sub.k], (4)
where
[Q.sub.ki] = [[Sigma].sub.j] [Q.sub.kij], (5a)
[Q.sub.k] = [[Sigma].sub.i] [Q.sub.ki], (5b)
[Q.sub.ui] = [[Sigma].sub.j] [Q.sub.uij], (5c)
[Q.sub.u] = [[Sigma].sub.i] [Q.sub.ui], (5d)
[L.sub.ui] = [[Sigma].sub.j] [L.sub.uij], (5e)
subscripts k and u denote state and nation, respectively, subscript i indicates two-digit standard industrial classification (SIC) industry,
and subscript j refers to a firm within industry i.(7)
By normalizing relative to the nation, Equation 1 exceeds unity
when a state has above-average productivity. Equation 2 decomposes total
productivity differentials into industry mix differences and average
productivity differences across all industries. Equation 3 shows that
PROD. MIX is obtained by weighting U.S. industry productivity by the
state share of output in that industry in the numerator, and the U.S.
share of output in that industry in the denominator.(8) Equation 4
reveals that PROD_COMP is derived from the total level of productivity
(PROD) and PROD_MIX. If a state has an above-average concentration of
nationally high-productivity industries, PROD_MIX exceeds unity. Yet if
all industries on average in the state have higher productivity than
they do nationally (i.e., PROD [greater than] PROD_MIX), PROD_COMP will
be greater than one.
Taking natural logs of Equation 2, the log of relative productivity
equals the sum of the log of productivity mix and the log of
productivity competitiveness:
ln[(PROD).sub.k]= ln[(PROD_MIX).sub.k] + ln(PROD_COMP).sub.k], (6)
in which values above zero now reflect productivity advantages.
From Equation 6, differences in state productivity depend on factors
that increase its mix of high-productivity industries plus those that
increase productivity in each industry above the industry's
national average level. When multiplied by 100, PROD.MIX is
approximately the percentage point difference in average productivity
from the nation attributable to the state concentration of
high-productivity industries. Likewise, PROD_COMP multiplied by 100 is
the percentage point deviation attributable to the state's relative
average productivity difference in all industries.
Model
Given a positive marginal product of capital, labor productivity is
an increasing function of the capital-to-labor ratio (K/L). Similarly,
if there are (internal) increasing returns to scale in all inputs,
increased firm size increases labor productivity. So at the aggregate
level, average firm size may be positively related to aggregate
productivity. Firm size also may affect productivity if it is related to
market power (Glaeser et al. 1992). The effect of market power is a
priori ambiguous. On the one hand, a large monopolistic firm may have
more incentive to conduct research and development because of a higher
probability of appropriating the returns (Romer 1990). Alternatively,
smaller competitive firms may face more market pressures to innovate (Porter 1990).
Scale at the industry level that is external to firms, but internal
within an industry, may also influence labor productivity. Increasing
scale that is internal within an industry but not the firm can result
from what are commonly known as MAR externalities in a dynamic sense, or
localization economies in a static sense. Localization economies will
occur if there are scale economies from intraindustry specialization
(Moomaw 1986) or labor market economies from reduced search costs for
workers with specific skills. Correspondingly, MAR externalities may
result from a buildup of local firms in an industry (Romer 1986), which
raises future productivity of firms within that industry. To be sure,
Ellison and Glaeser (1997) found that all U.S. industries were somewhat
geographically concentrated. In addition to the potential role of
natural advantages, they argue that the concentration suggests the
presence of localization/MAR economies. The existence of localization or
MAR externalities can both increase average productivity in all
industries (PROD_COMP) or induce a greater concentration in nationally
productive industries if externalities particularly occur in them.
Labor productivity also may be enhanced by urbanization economies
in a static sense, and by what are commonly referred to as Jacobs
economies in a dynamic sense (Jacobs 1969). Urbanization and Jacobs
economies are external to the firm and industry but internal within a
region. For example, they can result from knowledge or innovation
spillovers between industries that may occur with the greater diversity
of industries in more populated areas. Closer geographic proximity also
may produce pecuniary spillovers through lowering transportation costs
of intermediate inputs (e.g., Krugman 1991).
Taken together, we write productivity competitiveness (PROD_COMP)
and productivity mix (PROD.MIX) as:
ln[(PROD_COMP).sub.k] = g[((K/L).sub.k], [FIRM.sub.k],
[INDUSTRY.sub.k], [URBAN.sub.k], [Z.sub.k]), (7a)
ln[(PROD_MIX).sub.k] = h[((K/L).sub.k], [FIRM.sub.k],
[INDUSTRY.sub.k], [URBAN.sub.k], [Z.sub.k]), (7b)
where FIRM, INDUSTRY, and URBAN denote variables representing firm
size, economies of scale to industry size, and urbanization economies,
respectively, and Z denotes control variables.
3. Empirical Implementation
One concern of previous studies is the difficulty of separating
static externality effects from dynamic effects. For example, many
studies regress initial levels of the independent variables (e.g., total
population) on measures of long-term economic activity and characterize
the coefficients as the effects of dynamic externalities (e.g., Glaeser
et al. 1992). Yet, contemporaneous values of the independent variables
are often correlated with initial values of these variables, making it
difficult to sort out static from dynamic effects (a fact that is
usually acknowledged in the literature, e.g., Henderson [1997]).(9)
We approach this issue in a two-step fashion. We first regress
contemporaneous labor productivity on contemporaneous values of the
independent variables using fixed effects estimation. The fixed effects
slope estimates derive from within-state time series (or year-to-year)
changes in the variables. Thus, the slope estimates should primarily
reflect short-term static effects of urbanization, localization, or
other factors that affect current levels of productivity. This is most
akin to the traditional technique used in regional productivity studies
(e.g., Moomaw 1986). Yet, the estimated state fixed effects (dummy coefficients) contain information on persistent productivity differences
across states that result from long-run effects of various factors.
These effects may relate to resource endowments, cultural influences,
and proximity to neighboring states. More importantly, because dynamic
externalities (either MAR or Jacobs) are long-term, the fixed effects
also may reflect the existence of dynamic externality effects. To
explore this, we secondly regress the estimated state fixed effects on
the initial values of the independent variables.
Static Externality Equations
Using Equations 7a-b, we write our panel (first-step) regressions
as:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], (8a)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], (8b)
where t denotes time period; c and m denote competitiveness and
mix; [Alpha] represents the intercept; [Beta] a slope parameter;
[Gamma], [Phi], [Delta], [Theta] denote vectors of slope parameters;
[[Sigma].sub.t] and [[Sigma].sub.l] represent year and state fixed
effects; and e and v are stochastic terms. The year fixed effects
control for national cyclical and trend effects common across all states
in the independent variables (the dependent variables are centered
around the national average).(10) The state fixed effects are then used
as dependent variables in the second-step regressions discussed below.
Equations 8a, b are estimated using data for the 48 contiguous
states from 1972-1986. Capital (K) is total private nonfarm capital, and
labor (L) is total private nonfarm employment. Included in FIRM is the
natural log of average nonfarm private sector establishment size in the
state (Log Avg Firm Size). Included in URBAN is the percent of a
state's population that resides in a metropolitan area (%Metro). If
urbanization economies are associated with urban population (Moomaw
1983), then an increase in the urban share would be expected to increase
labor productivity. For example, increased urban share may be associated
with increased density of economic activity, which has been found to
explain cross-sectional differences in labor productivity in the U.S.
(Ciccone and Hall 1996).
Knowledge spillovers between industries may be particularly
associated with the high-tech sector, which may occur when high-tech
firms represent best-practice technology. Therefore, we also include in
INDUSTRY the percent of private nonfarm employment in high-tech
manufacturing (%High-Tech Manu).(11) In Equation 8a, high-tech share is
intended to capture innovations or knowledge that spill over from the
high-tech sector to other sectors. Note that these spillover effects are
separate from a greater effect of the high-tech share in directly
changing the productivity mix of the state's industries (i.e.,
PROD_MIX in Eqn. 8b).
Following Glaeser et al. (1992) and Henderson (1997), a Herfindahl
index variable is used to reflect the influence of either
within-industry spillovers (INDUSTRY) or between industry spillovers
(URBAN). Specifically, the Herfindahl index is a measure of industry
diversity or concentration and is calculated as the sum of squares of
the percentage of employment in each two-digit private sector industry.
Increased diversity (lower Herfindahl) may lead to greater knowledge
spillovers between industries, whereas increased concentration (larger
Herfindahl) may lead to greater within-industry spillovers. Thus, the
sign of the Herfindahl index coefficient indicates whether
within-industry spillovers are more prevalent than between-industry
spillovers in a static sense.
Control variables (Z) include the percentage of the population over
the age of 24 that are high school graduates but not four-year college
graduates (%HS Grad), and four-year college graduates (%College Grad).
Besides the productivity effects directly associated with a better
educated worker, there also may be positive externalities associated
with concentrations of educated workers. For example, there may be
sharing of knowledge and skills between workers that occurs through
formal and informal interactions, making human capital accumulation a
group activity (Lucas 1988; Rauch 1993).
Several variables are included as static or cyclical determinants
of productivity. First, the percentage of the civilian labor force that
are union members is included (%Union). Unions reduce PROD_COMP in
Equation 8a if they are associated with rigid work rules; however, if
there are union voice effects, productivity is enhanced (Freeman and
Medoff 1984). Similarly, by changing relative business costs and
altering industry composition, unions may change PROD_MIX in Equation
8b. As a measure of structural change, we include the variance of
two-digit employment growth rates each year (Industry Var). A larger
variance is likely associated with increased costs of adjusting capacity
utilization and labor utilization, reducing productivity. Finally, we
include the total annual criminal offenses per 100,000 people (Crime
Rate). Higher crime is likely to cause firms to devote significant
resources to protection, decreasing total labor productivity. Higher
crime also may lead to reduced worker productivity for related reasons
or through a psychological toll. In Equation 8b, higher crime may repel high-productivity industries.
Dynamic Externality Equations
The estimated state fixed effects in Equations 8a, b are used as
dependent variables in a second set of regressions to examine potential
dynamic externality effects:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], (9a)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], (9b)
where 72 denotes beginning of period 1972 values. The coefficients
in these equations will reveal whether there are persistent growth
effects associated with beginning of period conditions (i.e., dynamic
externality effects). Most of the same variables used in Equations 8a, b
as contemporaneous values to examine static externalities are used as
initial values in Equations 9a, b to examine dynamic externalities.
However, the education variables are the only Z variables included
because they have the potential for dynamic effects on productivity in
addition to contemporaneous effects. In addition, while we account for
static urbanization effects (aside from industry diversity) using the
percentage of the state's population living in metropolitan areas,
we partition this factor into two separate categories in the fixed
effect regressions to better identify the sources of dynamic
externalities.(12) First, we add the log of the 1972 state population to
account for urbanization scale effects, market-size threshold effects,
and urban hierarchy effects.(13) Second, the 1972 log state employment
per square mile is included to measure employment density or
concentration factors (Ciccone and Hall 1996), which may proxy for both
closer proximity to different inputs and better information exchange.
4. Empirical Results
Table 1 shows the results of fixed effects estimation of the panel
data, which we use to assess static externality effects on productivity.
Column 1 contains the unweighted descriptive statistics. For example, it
shows that over the 1972-1986 period, the average metropolitan share of
the population was
about 60.3%, and the average share of nonfarm employment in high-tech
manufacturing was 7.7%. Columns 2-4 present the pooled cross-sectional
regression results (using fixed effects estimation) for the log
competitiveness productivity index (from Eqn. 8a), and columns 5 and 6
contain the corresponding results for the log industry mix productivity
index (from Eqn. 8b). Preliminary analysis suggested significant
(within-state) first-order autocorrelation of the residuals (0.5 [less
than] [Rho] [less than] 0.6). Hence, all five reported regressions are
corrected for first-order autocorrelation using the Cochrane-Orcutt
procedure in LIMDEP 7.0, resulting in the loss of the first observation
for each state.
Static Externality Results
Competitiveness Productivity
Column 2 of Table 1 shows that the competitiveness productivity
index is positively related to capital intensity with a corresponding
static elasticity of 0.07. Thus, an increase of one standard deviation in the capital/labor ratio increases the state's competitiveness
component of productivity by about 2.5%.(14) Conversely, average firm
size was statistically insignificant, suggesting no strong internal
return-to-scale productivity effects or possible benefits from more
competitive small firms.
There is evidence that static externalities increase the
productivity levels of all existing industries. First, regarding
urbanization effects, a greater share of the population living in
metropolitan areas is positively related to competitiveness
productivity. With economic diversity or concentration accounted for
with the Herfindahl index, the metropolitan coefficient reflects other
effects, such as product market size, closer proximity to markets, or
density of production. Yet, the positive and significant Herfindahl
coefficient suggests that positive static localization externalities
(i.e., within industry) dominate urbanization externalities that result
from a diverse range of industries and input suppliers.
The insignificant high-tech coefficient implies that productivity
levels of existing firms are not influenced by a greater share of
high-tech employment. That is, once industry mix effects are taken into
account (PROD_MIX), there is no evidence of information transfers from
the high-tech sector that raises productivity for other industries (in a
static sense).
Both educational attainment coefficients are positively related to
average state productivity in each industry at the 1% level of
significance. Unionization, variation in growth rates across industries,
and crime rates are statistically insignificant. However, the industry
variance coefficient is negative and nearly significant at the 10%
level, weakly suggesting that reallocating labor across sectors may
produce training problems or create imperfect labor force utilization
rates (Lilien 1982).
Although not always considered in productivity studies, the model
in column 3 of Table 1 considers whether employment growth influences
contemporaneous levels of productivity. For example, faster economic
growth may allow firms to fully utilize both their capital resources and
publicly provided capital (or over-utilize them). Correspondingly,
faster growth may be associated with increased market size and improved
access to markets (Mullen and Williams 1990). Notwithstanding, greater
hiring may reduce the average quality of the applicant pool, reducing
current productivity levels.
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 1 OMITTED]
An empirical concern with the model, shown in column 3 of Table 1,
is that above (below) average levels of productivity can in turn affect
business location and employment growth, which could bias the
coefficients. This possibility is tested with a Hausman test. The null
hypothesis is that any potential endogeneity of employment growth is not
biasing the coefficients. The bottom of column 3 shows that the null
hypothesis can be rejected (5% level), suggesting that two-stage least
squares (2SLS) should be used. Thus, the results in column 3 reflect the
use of 2SLS treating employment growth as endogenous.(15)
The 2SLS results show that employment growth is positively related
to labor productivity. The positive coefficient suggests that in a tight
labor market characterized by strong employment growth, productivity
gains could somewhat offset wage increases to moderate price effects,
which may be one explanation for the relatively low inflation rates
during the latter 1990s. Most of the other results are basically
unchanged except for the college graduate coefficient losing some
statistical significance and the variance of industry growth measure
becoming significant at the 10% level.
Another possible concern is that the capital/labor ratio may be
endogenous. If so, it is not clear in which direction its coefficient is
biased. For example, higher average worker productivity due to human
capital may reduce the demand for capital, but a more productive labor
force may attract more capital to a state. Yet, given that we do not
have suitable exogenous instruments for capital, we re-estimated the
model shown in column 4 of Table 1 by omitting the capital/labor ratio
from the equation. Regarding capital intensity, this model is akin to
treating capital/labor in a reduced-form fashion.(16) Generally, the
coefficients in column 4 are similar to those in column 3, suggesting
little if any bias (although there were modest changes in the values of
some of the t-statistics).
Industry Mix Productivity
The log industry mix productivity index for each state is the
dependent variable in the models shown in columns 5 and 6 of Table 1.
Except for the omission of the capital/labor ratio due to endogeneity
concerns, the model in column 5 corresponds to the competitiveness model
in column 2.(17) Likewise, the model in column 6 corresponds to the
competitiveness model in column 4.
Because both sets of productivity mix results are similar, the 2SLS
findings in column 6 of Table 1 will be emphasized.(18) The support for
static externality effects on industry composition is weaker, which is
not surprising since industry composition likely changes more gradually
(suggesting more of a dynamic process) than the time it takes
productivity effects to be realized in existing industries.
Nevertheless, if one is willing to accept the 20% statistical
significance level (two-tail test) as evidence, there is some indication
that larger average firm size leads to a more productive mix of
industries. Likewise, the negative coefficient on the metropolitan share
coefficient suggests that certain urbanization effects do not play a
role in attracting a productive industry mix (in a static sense), where
perhaps urban congestion effects dominate. However, the negative
coefficient on the Herfindahl index weakly suggests that industry
diversity is conducive to attracting a productive industry composition,
which is consistent with certain urbanization effects overwhelming
localization effects. Finally, even at the 20% level, there are no
static advantages of having a greater share of high-tech manufacturing
employment.
The educational attainment variables are positively and
significantly related to a state's productive mix at the 1% level.
The crime rate was negatively and significantly related to industry mix
productivity, suggesting that industries with high average levels of
productivity avoid locating in areas with high crime rates. Finally,
productivity mix is positively related to employment growth (at the 1%
level), perhaps due to market proximity effects. Thus for expanding
areas, there may be a virtuous cycle of faster employment growth
increasing productivity, which in turn stimulates further employment
growth.
Given that a state's log total productivity equals the sum of
the mix and competitiveness components (see Eqn. 6), adding the
coefficients in columns 4 of Table 1 to those in 6 illustrates each
variable's total static effect on average labor productivity. Some
variables have a reinforcing effect on total productivity, whereas other
variables have an offsetting effect. For example, the metropolitan
results suggest that static urbanization effects raise productivity for
all of the state's existing industries (column 4), but these
urbanization effects tend to (weakly) attract a mix of industries with
lower than average productivity (column 6). Likewise, the offsetting
Herfindahl results are consistent with competitiveness productivity
being favorably influenced by localization economies (column 4), but the
productivity mix of industries being more affected by diversity effects
(column 6). Perhaps the offsetting effects for urbanization and
localization economies explain the ambiguous results found when only
considering total productivity (or employment) in the previous
literature, which points to the advantage of our productivity
decomposition.
Dynamic Externality Results
The state fixed effects associated with the models in Table 1
reflect persistent differences in productivities (over the 1973-1986
period) that result from long-run processes (since short-term static
effects should be netted out in the first-step regressions). Endogenous
growth models with dynamic externalities hypothesize that particular
historical or initial conditions should influence productivity for long
periods of time, especially those conditions associated with MAR and
Jacobs externalities (Glaeser et al. 1992; Henderson, Kuncoro, and
Turner 1995). To examine this possibility, Table 2 presents results
using the state fixed effects from the models [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 2
OMITTED] shown in columns 3 and 6 of Table 1 as dependent variables. For
ease of comparison, each state's fixed effect is differenced from
the national average fixed effect. The corresponding independent
variables are the initial 1972 measures associated with dynamic
externalities.(19)
Column 1 of Table 2 shows the descriptive statistics. For example,
the standard deviation of competitiveness productivity across states are
about 9% due to state fixed effects, whereas the corresponding standard
deviation for industry mix productivity is about 12%. Column 2 presents
the competitiveness state fixed effect results using the state fixed
effect regression coefficients from the model reported in column 3 of
Table 1. Column 3 of Table 2 presents the industry composition state
fixed effect results using the state fixed effect regression
coefficients from the model shown in column 6 of Table 1. Table 2
reports White heteroscedasticity-corrected t-statistics because the
dependent variable consists of predicted state fixed effects, which can
introduce heteroscedasticity of an unknown form.
The results in Table 2 suggest that those states with a greater
initial capital/labor ratio had a higher concentration of more
productive industries (column 3) and higher long-run labor productivity
in all industries (column 2) (significant at the 1% level). The
high-tech manufacturing share coefficient is negative and insignificant
(at the 10% level) in the competitiveness state fixed effect model
(column 2), but positive and significant in the industry mix state fixed
effect model (column 3). This suggests that a greater initial high-tech
concentration is conducive to attracting more high-productivity
industries in the long run, perhaps due to a threshold or cluster effect in the labor market. Yet, a greater initial high-tech share did not
increase relative long-term productivity for all industries, suggesting
few long-term knowledge spillovers to other industries. Taken together
with the insignificant (static) high-tech coefficients in Table 1, it
appears that there are little short-term gains from government policies
aimed at attracting high-tech industries, but there may be long-term
gains in attracting high-productivity industries if a state can achieve
a certain threshold (consistent with Henderson, Kuncoro, and Turner
1995).
The insignificant Herfindahl coefficients in columns 2 and 3 of
Table 2 suggest that neither MAR localization economies nor (Jacobs)
diversity economies dominate in a dynamic sense. Similarly, average firm
size does not dynamically affect productivity. The college education
coefficients are both insignificant. The high school coefficients are
both negative, but only significant in the productivity mix fixed
effects model. This somewhat surprising pattern suggests that
education's positive effects on productivity are more immediate,
without any persistent residual effects.
The log state population coefficient is positive and significant in
the competitiveness model in column 2, but insignificant in the mix
model in column 3. Thus, greater initial population appears to have
persistent average productivity effects over all industries but does not
have any long-term influence on the productivity mix of industries that
locate in the state. This market-size result generally accords with the
findings of Henderson, Kuncoro, and Turner (1995). The initial
employment per square mile is positive and significant (at least at the
10% level) in both models. That is, greater employment density raises
the long-run productivity of all industries, as well as attracting a
more productive mix of industries in the long-term. With industry
diversity and concentration accounted for (Herfindahl), these results
are consistent with positive productivity effects resulting from
increased contacts between workers, greater access to specialized labor,
and reduced transportation costs (Krugman 1991). Summing the two
model's population size and employment density coefficients
together suggests that employment density has a greater effect on
long-term total productivity than state size. This supports the findings
of Ciccone and Hall (1996). Yet the benefit of our approach is that we
determined that employment density's primary advantage - compared
to state size - is through attracting a productive mix of industries.
The high [R.sup.2] coefficients (respectively, 0.52 and 0.77)
support our interpretation of the state fixed effects reflecting
persistent factors such as dynamic externalities. Nevertheless, for
further support we included three public policy variables in both models
to see if government policies explain the fixed effects results (not
shown). Specifically, we included a dummy variable for right-to-work
state, average 1973-1986 state and local welfare expenditures as a share
of personal income, and average 1973-1986 state and local taxes as a
share of personal income. These variables are often viewed as indicators
of a business-friendly environment. Except for the tax variable in the
competitiveness regression, the policy variables were nowhere near
statistically significant, supporting our contention that dynamic
externalities primarily underlie the state fixed effects.
5. Conclusion
Using panel data for the 48 contiguous U.S. states, we examined the
potential link between externalities and state labor productivity. In
the analysis, we separated state productivity differences into those due
to its composition of industries and those due to average productivity
differences in each industry. Moreover, we separated externalities into
static externalities (those that have more immediate effects) and
dynamic externalities (those that persist or take longer to unfold).
A primary finding is that static localization externalities, as
measured by industry specialization, dominated static economic diversity
externalities. Also in a static sense, increased urbanization through a
higher metropolitan population share led to increased average
productivity across all industries (effects not related to diversity of
urban areas), but this was offset by a less productive composition of
industries.
In the long run, consistent with the conclusions of Glaeser et al.
(1992), Jacobs dynamic externalities appear more important than MAR
dynamic externalities. Dynamic externalities across all industries
appeared related to employment density and population size. However,
only initial employment density was associated with a more productive
long-run industry composition. Neither initial-period industry diversity
nor initial-period industry specialization dominated regarding dynamic
effects. Despite no evidence of high-tech productivity spillovers to
other industries in the near- or long-term, a state's initial share
of high-tech industries appeared to influence its composition of
productive industries in the long run.
Appendix
Crime Rate: Various issues of the Statistical Abstract of the
United States.
Employment-based Variables - Total private nonfarm employment,
Employ Grth, Labor (L), Industry Var, Herfindahl: U.S. Bureau of
Economic Analysis.
Gross State Product: For years 1977-1986, see Trott, Dunbar, and
Friedenberg (1991), and for the earlier years, see Renshaw, Trott, and
Friedenberg (1988).
%High-Tech Manu: Manufacturing industries classified as high-tech
are from the U.S. Department of Commerce classification given in the
1993 Statistical Abstract of the United States. Employment in these
sectors are used to calculate the high-tech employment shares.
%HS Grad, %College Grad: U.S. Department of Commerce Census of
Population 1970, 1980, and 1990. Values for years between censuses are
obtained through linear interpolation.
Log Avg Firm Size: U.S. Department of Commerce County Business
Patterns Data.
%Metro, 1972 Log State Pop: U.S. Department of Commerce.
Private Capital (K), Public Capital: Munnell (1990).
State Land Area: 1993 Statistical Abstract of the United States.
%Union: U.S. Department of Commerce and Hirsch and Macpherson
(1993).
This paper benefitted from comments by an anonymous referee and
individuals attending presentations at the Federal Reserve Bank of
Dallas, Oklahoma State University, the Southern Regional Science
Association Meetings in Savannah, Georgia, the University of
Strathclyde, and the University of Wyoming. Particular thanks go to
Steve Brown, Shelby Gerking, Chuck Mason, Ron Moomaw, Edward Nissan,
Jamie Partridge, and Lori Taylor.
1 Romer (1994) contains a discussion of the endogenous growth
literature.
2 Henderson (1997) refers to these unobserved factors as location
fixed effects that arise from the region's history. He lists such
effects as regional resource endowments; cultural influences on legal,
political, and institutional arrangements; and skill-specific immobile portions of the labor force.
3 National and international studies have additional difficulties
in observing externalities associated with geographic concentration
(Pack 1994).
4 There is ambiguity in the literature regarding the terminology
for dynamic and static externalities. In what follows, we generally
follow the terminology used by Glaeser et al. (1992) and Henderson,
Kuncoro, and Turner (1995), although even here some ambiguity remains.
5 As Moomaw (1983) notes, regional comparisons of productivity
either assume constant returns to scale and attribute the labor
productivity differences to total factor productivity differences or
assume uniform total factor productivity and attribute the labor
productivity differences to differences in returns to scale. Similarly,
growth accounting studies (e.g., Hulten and Schwab 1984) assume that
inputs are paid their marginal revenue products and constant
returns-to-scale to estimate total factor productivity.
6 National and regional productivity studies have relied
exclusively on industry aggregations of firms and often national or
regional aggregations of industries. Yet as Fisher (1969) demonstrates,
conditions required for aggregation of firm production functions are
extremely restrictive and unlikely to be met in reality. For example,
even the case of homogeneity of outputs and inputs across firms does not
necessarily allow aggregation. With heterogeneity, aggregation is
theoretically supported if all firms are restricted to additively
separable production functions. And given heterogeneous capital and
nonadditively separable production, aggregation can occur if constant
returns to scale are assumed and technical differences across firms
augment capital. Despite the restrictive nature in these examples,
Fisher (1969) acknowledges that aggregate production functions often
give good results, possibly because other unidentified factors reduce
the dimensionality of the problem.
7 Moomaw (1998) shows that two-digit-level data do not exaggerate
estimated regional productivity differences when compared to
three-digit-level data, such that estimates of localization and
urbanization are not sensitive to the level of industry aggregation.
8 This is akin to the commonly used shift-share decompositions of
regional aggregates, such as employment and wage rates, found in other
studies (e.g., Partridge and Rickman 1995). In this manner, we also
employ shift-share terminology by referring to industry mix and
competitiveness effects.
9 A related problem in growth studies occurs when attempting to
estimate the rate of convergence between low-income and high-income
states and nations (Evans 1997).
10 Note that K/L is not included in Equation 8b because it is
likely to be influenced by industry mix (i.e., Eqn. 8b is a reduced
form). For example, both the capital/labor ratio and average
productivity are greater in a state with a large aircraft industry than
in a state with a large beautician industry. Because K/L and PROD_MIX
are so closely interrelated, including K/L would cause endogeneity
problems in econometric estimation, although we relax this assumption in
sensitivity analysis.
11 Manufacturing industries classified as high-tech are from the
U.S. Department of Commerce classification given in the 1993 Statistical
Abstract of the United States.
12 In both cases, the initial 1972 capital/labor ratio is included
to control for persistent effects of capital intensity, which may
include "embodied" technological progress. Unlike the pooled
time series cross-sectional models, we are less concerned with direct
endogeneity in the state fixed effects models because the 1972
capital/labor ratio was determined prior to the 1973-1986 fixed effect.
13 We also experimented with the log of the 1972 population of the
state's largest SMSA. Generally, the results for this variable were
similar to the results for state population, but using state population
resulted in a better fit.
14 Experiments were also conducted by adding the log of per capita highway public capital and the log of per capita public capital net of
highways. Highway public capital was negatively related to
competitiveness productivity and positively related to industry mix
productivity, where it was statistically significant in both cases.
Other public capital was statistically insignificant in the
competitiveness regression and negative and significant in the
productivity mix regression. Given this counterintuitive pattern, we did
not pursue public capital effects further, although it should be noted
that negative public capital effects on productivity have been found in
other studies (e.g., Holtz-Eakin 1994).
15 The Hausman test uses the predicted value of employment growth
from the first-stage regression, where the test statistic is the
t-statistic on the predicted employment growth variable when it is
included as an additional variable in the productivity ordinary least
squares regression. The exogenous instrument is the industry mix
employment growth rate, which is the state's employment growth rate
if all its industries grew at their respective national average growth
rates (i.e., it shows whether the state has a fast or slow growing mix
of industries and has often been used as an exogenous instrument for
employment growth [Bartik 1991]). As expected, the industry mix
coefficient t-statistic in the first-stage regression was 13.8 (not
shown), suggesting it
is a good instrument (Bound, Jaeger, and Baker 1995). We also
examined whether industry mix is improperly omitted as a variable in the
second-stage regression by using an artificial regression technique
(MacKinnon 1992). These tests suggested that the industry mix employment
growth rate was properly omitted in the second stage.
16 By comparison, Ciccone and Hall (1996) substituted capital out
of their state labor productivity model by assuming that the price of
capital was identical across states. More typically, the influence of
capital is ignored in recent regional studies of "new" growth
models.
17 To examine the sensitivity of the results, we re-estimated an
industry mix productivity model that included the capital/labor ratio,
in which the capital/labor coefficient and t-statistic were almost zero,
and the other results were virtually unchanged.
18 The Hausman test statistic at the bottom of column 6 of Table 1
indicates that potential endogeneity of employment growth also may bias
the productivity mix results. Thus, we utilize 2SLS, where industry mix
employment growth is the exogenous instrument. The artificial regression
technique discussed in footnote 15 suggested that the industry mix
employment growth rate was properly omitted in the second-stage model.
19 It is possible that the control variable coefficients in Table 1
may have captured some of the long-term effect of the state fixed
effects. This suggests that the fixed effect regressions in Table 2 may
understate the influence of dynamic externalities. Likewise, using the
estimated fixed effects introduces measurement error in the dependent
variable of the regressions in Table 2. This does not bias the resulting
variable coefficients, yet it can bias the t-statistics toward zero.
References
Bartik, Timothy J. 1991. Who benefits from state and local economic
development policies? Kalamazoo, MI: Upjohn Institute.
Bound, John, David A. Jaeger, and Regina M. Baker. 1995. Problems
with instrumental variable estimation when correlation between the
instruments and the endogenous explanatory variables is weak. Journal of
the American Statistical Association 90:443-50.
Carlino, Gerald A., and Richard Voith. 1992. Accounting for
differences in aggregate state productivity. Regional Science and Urban
Economics 22:597-617.
Ciccone, Antonio, and Robert E. Hall. 1996. Productivity and the
density of economic activity. American Economic Review 86:54-70.
Ellison, Glenn, and Edward L. Glaeser. 1997. Geographic
concentration in U.S. manufacturing industries: A dartboard approach,
Journal of Political Economy 105:889-927.
Evans, Paul. 1997. How fast do economies converge? Review of
Economics and Statistics 79:219-25.
Fisher, Franklin M. 1969. The existence of aggregate production
functions. Econometrica 37:553-77.
Freeman, Richard, and James Medoff. 1984. What do unions do? New
York: Basic Books.
Gerking, Shelby. 1994. Measuring productivity growth in U.S.
regions: A survey. International Regional Science Review 16:155-86.
Glaeser, Edward L., Hedi Kallal, Jose Sheinkman, and Andre
Schleifer. 1992. Growth in cities. Journal of Political Economy
100:1126-52.
Henderson, Vernon. 1997. Externalities and industrial development.
Journal of Urban Economics 42:449-70.
Henderson, Vernon, Ari Kuncoro, and Matt Turner. 1995. Industrial
development in cities. Journal of Political Economy 103:1067-90.
Hirsch, Barry T., and David A. Macpherson. 1993. Union membership
and coverage files from the current population surveys: Note. Industrial
and Labor Relations Review 46:574-8.
Holtz-Eakin, Douglas. 1994. Public sector capital and the
productivity puzzle. Review of Economics and Statistics 76: 12-21.
Hulten, Charles R., and Robert M. Schwab. 1984. Regional
productivity growth in U.S. manufacturing: 1951-78. American Economic
Review 74:152-62.
Jacobs, Jane. 1969. The economy of cities. New York: Vintage.
Krugman, Paul. 1991. Increasing returns and economic geography.
Journal of Political Economy 99:483-99.
Lilien, David. 1982. Sectoral shifts and cyclical unemployment.
Journal of Political Economy 90:777-93.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr. 1988. On the mechanics of economic
development. Journal of Monetary Economics 22:3-42.
MacKinnon, James G. 1992. Model specification tests and artificial
regressions. Journal of Economic Literature 30: 102-46.
Moomaw, Ronald L. 1983. Is population a worthless surrogate for
business agglomeration economies? Regional Science and Urban Economics
13:525-45.
Moomaw, Ronald L. 1986. Have changes in localization economies been
responsible for declining productivity advantages in large cities?
Journal of Regional Science 26:19-32.
Moomaw, Ronald L. 1998. Agglomeration economies: Are they
exaggerated by industrial aggregation? Regional Science and Urban
Economics 28:199-211.
Mullen, John K., and Martin Williams. 1990. Explaining total factor
productivity differentials in urban manufacturing. Journal of Urban
Economics 28:103-23.
Munnell, Alicia H. 1990. How does public infrastructure affect
regional economic performance? New England Economic Review 11-32.
Pack, Howard. 1994. Endogenous growth theory: Intellectual appeal
and empirical shortcomings. Journal of Economic Perspectives 8:55-72.
Partridge, Mark D., and Dan S. Rickman. 1995. Differences in state
unemployment rates: The role of labor and product market structural
shifts. Southern Economic Journal 62:89-106.
Partridge, Mark D., and Dan S. Rickman. 1996. The role of industry
structure, costs, and economic spillovers in determining state
employment growth rates. The Review of Regional Studies 26:235-64.
Porter, Michael E. 1990. The competitive advantage of nations. New
York: The Free Press.
Rauch, James E. 1993. Productivity gains from geographic
concentration of human capital: Evidence from the cities. Journal of
Urban Economics 34:380-400.
Renshaw, Vernon, Edward A. Trott, Jr., and Howard L. Friedenberg.
1988. Gross state product by industry, 1963-86. Survey of Current
Business 68:30-46.
Romer, Paul. 1986. Increasing returns and long run growth. Journal
of Political Economy 94:1002-37.
Romer, Paul. 1990. Endogenous technological change. Journal of
Political Economy 98:S71-S101.
Romer, Paul. 1994. The origins of endogenous growth. Journal of
Economic Perspectives 8:3-22.
Trott, Edward A., Ann E. Dunbar, and Howard L. Friedenberg. 1991.
Gross state product by industry, 1977-89. Survey of Current Business
71:43-59.
Mark D. Partridge, Associate Professor of Economics, Department of
Economics, Stewart Hall, St. Cloud State University, St. Cloud, MN
56301-4498, USA; E-mail mpartridge@stcloudstate.edu.
Dan S. Rickman, Professor of Economics and OG&E Chair in
Regional Economic Analysis, Department of Economics and Legal Studies,
303 College of Business Administration, Oklahoma State University,
Stillwater, OK 74078, USA; E-mail rdan@okway.okstate.edu; corresponding
author.