The return to hours and workers in U.S. manufacturing: evidence on aggregation bias.
Singell, Larry D., Jr.
1. Introduction
In the 1980s, the statutory workweek was shortened in some British
and all French manufacturing industries to discourage the use of
overtime and to hypothetically increase employment of standard-time
workers (Marchand, Rault, and Tarpin 1983; White and Ghobadian 1984).
While interest in this policy was initially limited to European countries, the increasing reliance by U.S. firms on either overtime or
part-time work over the last decade has generated a similar interest in
the U.S. (Trejo 1991; Stratton 1996). In fact, 1994 legislation backed
by organized labor was introduced in the House of Representatives to
reduce the standard workweek from 40 to 30 hours in an effort to spread
the existing work over more employees (Fitzgerald 1996). In 1997, the
United Auto Workers' strike against General Motors emphasized
excessive use of overtime work, while the Teamsters' strike against
the United Parcel Service focused primarily on the use of part-time
rather than full-time workers. Thus, the appropriate mix of hours and
workers appears to be a major point of contention between organized
labor and employers (Kahn and Lang 1995).
The effectiveness of policies that seek to exploit the worker-hour
tradeoff depend on the returns to hours and workers in the production
process. Theoretical worker-hour models predict a reduction in hours can
cause worker productivity and employment to decline if the returns to
hours are sufficiently high (Hammermesh 1996, chapter 7). Simulations of
worker-hour models using both U.S. and European data predict that firms
are more likely to convert overtime to new hires for a given reduction
in the workweek when the returns to hours are small (van Ginneken 1984;
Whitley and Wilson 1986; DeBeaumont 1993; Holm and Jaakko 1993).
Accurate return-to-hours estimates are thus important in analyzing the
productivity and employment effects of a workweek reduction.
Prior worker-hour studies estimate the rerum to hours and workers
using longitudinal manufacturing data for U.S. and European industries
and impose a Cobb-Douglas production function across industries that
requires fewer degrees of freedom than more general functional forms. A
survey of empirical analyses by Hart and McGregor (1988) indicates that
the return to hours is greater than the return to workers and may exceed
one.
Leslie and Wise (1980), however, reject the hypothesis of a common
production structure across industries using an F-test. They contend
that the imposition of a common production function confounds
productivity of hours with different technology or labor use patterns
across industries and biases the returns to hours upward. Leslie (1991)
finds, in fact, that heavy overtime users often assign an additional
shift that may be more productive than an extra hour at the end of a
shift for occasional overtime users. This suggests that work hours are
greater in industries for which hours are relatively productive and that
the production function should be estimated separately by industry.
Leslie and Wise (1980) provide the only industry-specific
return-to-hours estimates in the literature. However, their estimates
are insignificant because of limited degrees of freedom from the small
time dimension of their data.
In this paper, the aggregation-bias hypothesis is tested in two
parallel analyses that use U.S. manufacturing data disaggregated by
industry. In particular, industry-specific data by state from 1972-1978
and by four-digit-SIC code from 1958-1994 are used to estimate
worker-hour production functions for each two-digit-SIC industry. The
results are remarkably robust across the two data sets and indicate that
the returns to hours are significantly less than one for most
industries. Moreover, the findings also suggest that returns to hours
are generally less than returns to workers. The two sets of
industry-specific estimates are compared to estimates that impose a
common production function across industries and use data that aggregate
across states or subindustry. In both cases, the aggregate
return-to-hours estimates are greater than one and greater than most
individual industry-specific estimates. Jointly, these analyses provide
strong evidence of aggregation bias in prior worker-hour studies and
suggest that the returns are likely to be less than one for most U.S.
industries.
2. Empirical Model
Following the worker-hour literature, we estimate the returns to
hours and workers using a Cobb-Douglas production function that
distinguishes between the number of workers and hours in the production
process (Leslie and Wise 1980; Hart and McGregor 1988; Hammermesh 1996).
A Cobb-Douglas production function is adopted here and in the literature
because it uses fewer degrees of freedom than more general functional
forms. In fact, tests of the restriction imposed by the Cobb-Douglas
using a translog are statistically unreliable due to the relatively
small number of observations in our data. Nonetheless, by using a
Cobb-Douglas specification, we insure that any differences in our
results from prior work are not due to functional-form differences in
the estimating equation.
As a point of departure, we propose a production function for an
industry that varies in a cross-sectional dimension by state or by
subindustry (k) and over a time period (t)
ln [Y.sub.kt] = [a.sub.0] + [a.sub.1]ln [N.sub.kt] + [a.sub.2]ln
[H.sub.kt] + [a.sub.3][K.sub.kt] + [a.sub.4]ln [U.sub.kt] +
[a.sub.5][Z.sub.kt] + [[Epsilon].sub.kt], (1)
where Y is the value added, N and H are the average number of
workers and average weekly hours per worker, respectively, K is a
measure of the capital stock, U is a measure of capital utilization, and
Z is a vector of variables that includes measures of cyclical and time
variation. This specification differs from prior empirical models only
in that the cross-sectional variation by state or subindustry permits a
relaxation of the common production structure across industries imposed
in prior work. A number of factors may cause the production function to
differ by state or subindustry. For example, state-specific variation in
the productivity of resource-based industries (e.g., precious metals or
mining) is likely to arise from natural resource endowments, and
institutional factors such as right-to-work laws may affect labor
productivity in the state. Likewise, the production function for natural
gas is likely to differ from those of other petroleum subindustries.
Nonetheless, the use of two sources of cross-sectional variation to
estimate Equation 1 is important because it provides some evidence of
whether the results are sensitive to possible unobserved and unmeasured
sources of variation in the cross-sectional dimension.
The variables controlling for U and Z are included in Equation 1
because prior work suggests that their omission may bias the results for
N, H, and K. Specifically, Feldstein (1967) argues that the productivity
of hours is positively correlated with the level and utilization of
capital: He uses two-digit British manufacturing data over several years
and finds that omitting U can cause an upward bias in the return to
hours. This finding is supported by Hart and McGregor (1988). In
addition, Z includes measures that account for cyclical factors because,
for example, industries often pay more for hours in downturns than would
appear to be cost minimizing (Fay and Medoff 1985). This type of labor
hoarding would make hours appear more productive in an empirical
analysis, as actual labor hours would increase more in an upturn than
measured hours.
Our contention is that the inappropriate aggregation across
production structures in prior work causes an upward bias in the
return-to-hours estimates. This aggregation bias is similar to the
upward bias found for the return to education when there are
insufficient controls for ability (Blackburn and Neumark 1993). A
heuristic demonstration of aggregation bias can be seen in Figure 1,
which includes two production functions for competitive firms in
different industries that differ in their return to hours. Suppose these
firms are price takers in the input market such that they face the same
real wage. Profit-maximizing firms set the real wage equal to the
marginal product of an hour, which is reflected by the tangency between
the production function and the parallel wage lines A and B. It follows
that firm 2, which has both a larger intercept and a higher marginal
return to hours, hires more hours ([H.sub.2]) than firm 1 ([H.sub.1]).
However, by imposing a common production structure on the two firms, the
return-to-hours estimates are based on the slope of the regression line that connects [H.sub.1] and [H.sub.2], which is greater than the true
return to hours in either firm 1 or firm 2. This bias in the return to
hours would be present even with fixed-effect controls for intercept
differences because of the differences in the slope of the production
functions.
Two parallel empirical analyses subsequently use cross-sectional
variation by state or by subindustry to provide a sufficient number of
observations to estimate worker-hour production functions separately for
each industry, Each set of estimates is compared to an alternative model
that uses data that have been aggregated up over the cross-sectional
units and that impose a common production function for all industries.
Thus, our analyses improve on prior work by both testing the common
production structure hypothesis and by obtaining more reliable estimates
of the returns to hours by industry. Our analyses focus on the upward
bias in the returns to hours because the potential bias from aggregation
on the returns to other inputs is not likely to be systematic. For
example, in the food industry, farms that employ relatively few workers
may be capital intensive and productive or may be simply operating at
subsistence. If some states have a high concentration of
capital-intensive farms while others contain primarily subsistence
farms, then disaggregation by state could yield an increase or decrease
in the return to farm workers depending on weights used for aggregation.
Moreover, the change in the return to workers from disaggregation is
unlikely to depend on the productivity of hours or the level of hours
across states in the industry. The subsequent empirical results suggest,
in fact, that there is no significant bias in either the returns to
workers or the returns to capital.
3. Industry Estimates Disaggregated by State
The Data
We first use cross-sectional variation by state to obtain
industry-specific estimates. In particular, the Census of Manufactures
(U.S. Bureau of Census 1972, 1977) and the Annual Survey of Manufactures
(U.S. Census Bureau 1972-1978) contain data for two-digit-SIC industries
in the U.S., disaggregated by state, for the period between 1972 and
1978. These data are drawn from a survey of firms in each industry.
Observations for some states are not included for each industry because
low industry participation yields high standard errors for some
observations. The Census excludes observations that have a sufficiently
high standard error. Our sample interval ends in 1978 primarily because
capital expenditures are not available for the years between 1978 and
1982 in the state data. While it is possible to extend the sample period
by extrapolating capital expenditures over the years of missing data,
the number of states would be reduced due to missing observations for
the other variables in the empirical model. Thus, we use the period from
1972 to 1978 because it maximizes the k by t number of observations.
This time interval is similar to that used in prior aggregate studies
and thus offers the advantage that differences in the estimated returns
cannot be attributed to possible changes in the production function over
time. Nonetheless, the severe recession, price and wage controls, and
the energy crisis that occurred in the 1970s suggest that this may be a
unique time period for U.S. manufacturing. Thus, these estimates are
compared to the alternative estimates provided in the next section
obtained using subindustry data over a more extended time period. This
permits us to examine whether our results can be attributed to the use
of state-specific or time-specific variation.(1)
Data on value added, the capital stock, and the number of hours and
production workers are drawn from the Annual Survey of Manufactures
(U.S. Bureau of Census 1972-1978). Value added is measured in 1972
dollars using price indices from the Survey of Current Business (U.S.
Bureau of Economic Analysis 1972-1978). The capital series is
constructed from data on the stock, which are available by industry and
state only for 1978, and on new capital expenditures that are provided
for the years 1972 to 1978. The capital stock at time t ([K.sub.t]) is
calculated as [K.sub.t] = [K.sub.t-1] + [E.sub.t-1] -
[Lambda][K.sub.t-1], where E is both new and used/rental capital
expenditures and A is an industry-specific depreciation rate. [K.sub.t]
is calculated using backwards induction from 1978 deflating by the price
index for capital goods reported by the Bureau of Labor Statistics (1978). Several measures of cyclical variation are included in the
model. Time dummies are included to capture possible business-cycle
fluctuations. The capital-utilization rate from the Industrial
Production and Capacity Utilization and Industrial Material (U.S. Bureau
of Labor Statistics 1978) is also used, which varies over time but not
by state. The capital utilization rate is thus excluded from the model
when time dummies are included. We also use the unemployment rate as a
measure of cyclical fluctuations, which is provided by the Manpower
Report of the President (U.S. President 1978). The unemployment rate,
because it varies by state and time, does not require the exclusion of
the capital utilization rate.(2)
The number of workers is measured by the total employment of both
production and nonproduction workers. However, the number of hours is
measured by the average number of hours for production workers only
because data on hours are not available for nonproduction workers in the
Annual Survey of Manufactures. This is potentially problematic given the
general shift from production to nonproduction labor that has occurred
in U.S. manufacturing. However, estimates from the food industry that
shifted toward production workers during the sample period yield the
same qualitative conclusions as those industries that have shifted away
from production workers. Moreover, the qualitative conclusions for the
returns to hours and workers do not change in subsequent sensitivity
tests that control for the proportion of production workers in total
employment.
Summary statistics for hours are provided in Table 1 and suggest
several distinct patterns. First, consistent with findings of Leslie and
Wise (1980) for British manufactures, the ranking of long-hour
industries is relatively constant over time. For example, the paper and
petroleum industries consistently employ longer hours, while printing
and apparel consistently use the least. This suggests that some
industries have high hour products and that the technology for these
industries does not change dramatically over time. Second, hours use
appears to be in decline for the sample period. For example, hour usage
is lower for 17 of 19 industries in 1978 than in 1972; this suggests
that changes in relative prices or technology have made labor usage
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 1 OMITTED] relatively less favorable over this
time period, which may be the result of the supply shocks of the
mid-1970s. Finally, the descriptive statistics also suggest greater
variation in hours usage across states than across time and industries.
Thus, previous studies that have used aggregate data over states may
hide some of the variation in the return to hours.
Industry-Specific Results
Equation 1 is estimated controlling for fixed, unobserved
state-specific heterogeneity for 19 separate industries and jointly for
all 19 industries including industry-specific dummy variables.(3) An
F-test comparing the combined residual sum of squares of the
industry-specific specifications to that of the joint model yields a
statistic of 14.96, indicating the hypothesis of equal coefficients
across industries is rejected at the 1% level. Thus, industry-specific
parameter estimates are presented in Table 2.
Three empirical points are worth emphasizing. First, an empirical
disadvantage of using disaggregate data is that smaller economic units
such as states are more likely to have inputs and outputs that are
simultaneously determined. Hausman tests indicate possible simultaneity
bias in 2 of the 19 industry-specifics estimates, nonelectrical
machinery and furniture/fixtures. The production equations for these
industries are estimated using lagged values of the explanatory variables as instruments, which does not significantly alter the
coefficient estimates. Second, the models presented exclude the capital
utilization rate both because its coefficient is [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE
2 OMITTED] insignificant and its inclusion requires the exclusion of the
time dummies that are generally significant. Prior studies, however,
find that excluding the capital utilization rate biases the returns to
hours upward (Hart and McGregor 1988). Thus, the inclusion of a capital
utilization rate that varies by state and industry, if available, would
likely further reduce our return-to-hours estimates. Finally, while the
presence of first-order autocorrelation is rejected at the 5% level in
all specifications, the Durbin-Watson statistic is within the
inconclusive range for most industries. We use the Cochorane-Orcutt
procedure to correct for a first-order autoregressive error for those
industries in the inconclusive range. Comparisons of the uncorrected and
autoregressive models indicate that the point estimates and their
standard errors are robust to assumptions regarding the error structure.
The coefficients reported in Table 2 generally have the predicted
sign, with return-to-hours and return-to-workers estimates that are
significant at standard levels. The 13 significant return-to-hours
estimates have an average value of 0.63, and most of the individual
estimates are significantly less than one. This differs from prior
worker-hour studies that typically find returns to hours that are
greater than one. The results also cast doubt on the empirical
regularity in prior work that returns to hours are greater than returns
to workers. The return-to-hours estimates are less than those for the
returns to workers in 9 of the 13 industries for which the hours
coefficient is significant. The average of the rerum-to-workers estimate
is 0.73, which is comparable to prior aggregate industry estimates for
U.S. data (Feldstein 1967; Craine 1973). Thus, the smaller returns to
hours than workers appears to be largely due to the bias in returns to
hours. The analysis also indicates considerable differences in worker
productivity across industries, which explains the rejection of the
common production structure.
The other explanatory variables included in the model do not appear
to explain industry output. For example, the coefficient on the capital
stock is significant at the 10% level in only 4 of 19 regressions. The
relatively poor performance of the capital measure may be due to its
sampling error. Unfortunately, adopting a decision rule that yields more
reliable capital expenditure estimates critically reduces the number of
observations in the data. In any case, measurement error with regard to
capital is likely to inappropriately assign output increases to workers
and hours, which would tend to bias upward their estimates.(4)
The results for the cyclical measures are mixed. The coefficients
on the unemployment rate are generally insignificant and, when
significant, do not have a consistent sign. While many of the
coefficients on the time dummies (not reported)are significant at
traditional levels, their sign and magnitude do not indicate a
consistent pattern across industries. If industries respond differently
to cyclical factors, this would provide a rationale for why prior
cross-industry studies have found these factors to be insignificant. The
results may also suggest that, although cyclical factors are important
to production in an industry, economy-wide measures of cyclical
variation are too broad to capture the industry-specific effects on the
inputs of production.
Aggregate Results
The results of the industry-specific models support the proposition
that return-to-hours estimates are biased upward in cross-industry
studies. To confirm that this result is due to aggregation bias, we
replicate these cross-industry regressions using two comparable
aggregate data sets and a production function that imposes a common
production structure across industries. Our first aggregate analysis is
conducted by aggregating our data across states.(5) To make reliable
comparisons between the individual and aggregate estimates, we restrict
the industries to those 13 for which returns to hours are significant.
Thus, the sample includes 91 observations for the 13 industries over the
seven time periods. The estimates using industry-specific fixed-effects
are provided in column 1 of Table 3. Because the Durbin-Watson statistic
is in the inconclusive range, the estimates reported in Table 3 use the
Cochorane-Orcutt procedure to correct for first-order
autocorrelation.(6) A common autocorrelation coefficient is used in each
of the analyses because a F-test cannot reject the hypothesis of a
common autocorrelation coefficient across industries or across states.
Table 3. Aggregate Fixed-Effect Estimates for Two-Digit State
Data(ab)
All Industries Nineteen Industries
Coefficient Coefficient
Variable (SE) (SE)
Hours 1.02(**) 1.06(*)
(0.55) (0.47)
Workers 1.28(*) 0.75(*)
(0.25) (0.15)
Capital 0.07 0.37(*)
(0.08) (0.08)
Unemployment 0.05 -0.01
(0.05) (0.05)
Durbin-Watson 1.85 1.85
Degrees of Freedom 66 66
[R.sup.2] 0.34 0.34
a Both models are estimated correcting for first-order
autocorrelation.
b *, Significant at the 5% level; **, significant at the 10% level.
The results support the hypothesis that aggregation bias is present
in cross-industry regressions. Specifically, the estimate of the returns
to hours of 1.02 is larger than all but one of the individual industry
estimates. The aggregate specification, unlike its industry-specific
counterparts, includes the capital utilization rate that is available
across time for major industry groups. The inclusion of the capital
utilization rate is expected to lower the returns to hours. In fact, the
return-to-hours estimate increases to 1.4 when the capital utilization
rate is omitted from the aggregate regression.
While useful for demonstrating aggregation bias within the data
set, the aggregate data are not identical to those used in prior
cross-industry studies because some states and industries are excluded.
To insure the apparent aggregation bias in our cross-industry analysis
does not result from the exclusion of these observations, we perform a
second aggregate analysis that uses the standard methodology and
aggregate data sources for our U.S. manufacturing industries from 1972
to 1978. These data are from the Annual Survey of Manufactures and the
Census of Manufactures (U.S. Bureau of Census 1972, 1972-1978, 1977).
The tobacco products industry is again excluded from the analysis
because data are not reported for the capital stock for each year. The
estimates using these aggregate data are provided in the second column
of Table 3. For consistency, a first-order autoregressive process is
used, but the estimates are not significantly impacted by this
specification choice. The results from this analysis are qualitatively
equivalent to those from the cross-industry analysis using the
aggregated state data. In particular, the return-to-hours estimate of
1.06 is very similar to the estimate from the aggregated state data, and
the estimate is even greater when capital utilization is excluded. The
returns to capital are now significant as well, while the coefficient on
the unemployment rate remains insignificant.
4. Industry Estimates Disaggregated by Subindustry Group
The Data
The industry-specific estimates using the state data for the 1970s
suggest that the returns to hours are overstated in prior studies that
use aggregate data over a similar time period. On the other hand, the
use of data from a narrow time period that was plagued by a general
reduction in manufacturing hours may also yield unrealistic production
parameters estimates. In addition, state differences in factors such as
labor laws or average firm size could also affect the variation in hours
and workers across states. Thus, it is useful to compare the state
results with those that use alternative data to examine whether the
results are sensitive to the source of the cross-sectional variation
and/or the time period.
In this case, we use subindustry data that are again drawn from the
Annual Survey of Manufactures (U.S. Bureau of Census 1958-1994). In
particular, production data for 431 four-digit-SIC subindustries over
the period from 1958 to 1994 are made available by Eric J. Bartelsman,
Randy A. Becker, and Wayne B. Gray on the National Bureau of Economic
Research (NBER) web page (www.nber.org). Again, the number of
observations varies for each industry and depends on the number of
subindustry classifications. Thus, for example, the food industry
includes 47 four-digit subindustries, while the tobacco industry
contains only 3 subindustries. The NBER data include the value added
denominated in 1987 dollars in each four-digit subindustry, which is
used as a measure of output. In addition, the explanatory variables for
the real value of the capital stock in 1987 dollars, the total number of
workers, and the average hours of production workers are included in the
data. These data are supplemented by the national annual unemployment
rate and the capital utilization rate for major industry groups. In
addition, time dummies are included to measure year-specific effects.
Thus, we have each of the variables necessary to replicate the previous
production specification, where subindustry variation is used rather
than state variation to provide the required degrees of freedom to
estimate industry-specific production functions.
The summary statistics for the three industries with the highest
and lowest hour usage are presented in Table 4. The means confirm the
earlier finding from the state data that industries differ
systematically in their hour usage. In particular, high-hour industries
in 1958 continued to be the high-hour industries in 1994, while the
low-hour industries remain so over the entire time interval. The data
also indicate the pattern of declining hours observed in the 1970s has
since reversed, with hours per worker reaching a maximum for many
industries toward the end of the sample period. These data provide an
interesting test of the results from the previous section, both because
of the different method of disaggregation and because the data cover
periods where different economic conditions are present.
Industry-Specific Results
Table 5 reports the results for each of the 20 major industry
groups. The specification of the production function using the
subindustry data is identical to that estimated using the state [TABULAR
DATA FOR TABLE 4 OMITTED] data; thus, the capital utilization rate is
excluded in favor of time dummies. Again, the inclusion or exclusion of
the capital utilization rate does not affect the qualitative conclusions
drawn from the model. In addition, the same estimation technique is
employed to estimate the industry-specific production functions with the
subindustry data. In particular, the industry-specific production
functions are estimated including subindustry fixed-effects and
correcting for first-order autocorrelation. In this case, the
Durbin-Watson statistic indicates significant autocorrelation in each of
the industry-specific specifications, which is likely the result of the
longer time interval.
The results using the subindustry data are remarkably similar to
those found using the state [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 5 OMITTED] data.
Specifically, 19 of the 20 return-to-hours estimates are significant at
the 10% level or higher with an average estimate of 0.56, as compared to
the average estimate of 0.63 for the state data. In addition, 16 of the
estimates are significantly less than one at the 5% level, and two
estimates are not significantly different from one. Jointly, the results
from these two data sets provide strong evidence that returns to hours
do not exceed one and that they may be less than one for most
industries.
It is also interesting to compare the returns to hours and workers.
The point estimates of returns to hours are less than returns to workers
for most industries using the state data, but their differences are not
statistically different. Here, all 20 of the industry-specific,
return-to-workers estimates are significant at the 5% level, with an
average estimate of 0.84. For these data, returns to workers exceed
returns to hours for 17 of the 19 industries where both are significant.
In the two industries where returns to hours exceed returns to workers,
the 5% confidence intervals of the two estimates overlap. However, for
12 of the industries where returns to workers exceed returns to hours,
the 5% confidence intervals do not overlap. Thus, contrary to prior
work, returns to hours generally do not exceed the returns to workers
and are significantly smaller in most industries.
Prior work indicates a steady shift away from production workers
toward nonproduction workers in U.S. manufacturing, which may reflect
that many industries have experienced laborsaving technical change
(Berman, Bound, and Griliches 1994). It follows that the returns to
hours and workers could be biased due to the fact that the worker
measure does not distinguish between production and nonproduction
workers. This bias would be expected to be particularly large in the
subindustry data that covers a long time interval. Thus, the standard
model is re-estimated including a variable measuring the percent of
production workers in total employment. A comparison of the
return-to-hours and workers estimates from the standard specification
(columns 1 and 2, Appendix) with those that control for the mix of
production and nonproduction workers (columns 3 and 4, Appendix)
continue to show returns to hours that are generally less than one and
less than the returns to workers. The results using the state data,
while not reported for brevity, are similarly robust. Thus, aggregation
bias does not appear to depend on the mix of employment.
The return-to-capital estimates, unlike those from the state data,
are generally significant. The greater significance of the capital
variable in the subindustry versus the state data could be due to
smaller sampling error from measuring each subindustry over all states
and/or the greater degrees of freedom. Of the 14 significant
return-to-capital estimates, 12 fall in the range 0.100.31. The
unemployment rate is also significant in each industry, although its
exclusion has little effect on returns to hours and workers. Overall,
the results derived using the disaggregate subindustry data yield the
same qualitative conclusions to those drawn from the disaggregate state
data, although the subindustry results are generally more precise due to
their greater degrees of freedom.
Aggregate Results
The effects of aggregation are re-examined using the subindustry
data. In particular, Table 6 includes production-function estimates that
use data aggregated over the subindustry groups and impose common
production parameters across each of the industries for the period from
1958 to 1994. The specification of the production function in Table 6 is
identical to both the industry-specific estimates using the subindustry
data and the aggregate estimates using the state data.
The effects of aggregation in the subindustry data are directly
comparable to those found for the state data. Specifically, the
aggregate return-to-hours estimate of 1.12 is numerically greater than
all but one of the industry-specific estimates and is significantly
greater than most. The results confirm that aggregation yields
significant upward bias in the returns to hours. Moreover, aggregation
bias seems mostly limited to hours, as the returns to workers and
capital are close to the individual industry averages. Thus, the results
support the contention that high-hour industries are more efficient than
low-hour industries, which does not appear to coincide with high-worker
industries being more or less efficient.
Table 6. Aggregate Fixed-Effect Estimates Using Four-Digit SIC Data
for 1958-1994(ab)
Industry Coefficient (SE)
Return to Hours 1.12(*)
(0.16)
Return to Workers 0.77(*)
(0.05)
Return to Capital 0.22(*)
(0.05)
Unemployment Rate 2.30(*)
(0.08)
a Models are estimated including 36 time dummies. Each model
corrects for first-order autocorrelation based on the Durbin-Watson
statistic.
b *, Significant at the 5% level.
Our disaggregate analyses still involve some degree of aggregation
that could bias the results. Specifically, in the subindustry data, each
observation is given equal weight even though the subindustries employ a
different number of workers and produce a different level of output.
Thus, for example, the largest food subindustry (i.e., SIC 2011)
employees an average of 120,000 production workers over the period,
which is over twice the size of any other subindustry and 30 times as
large as the smallest (i.e., SIC 2021). Thus, it may be inappropriate to
give equal weight to each of the subindustries because they vary
markedly in their share of total production for the industry. To examine
the sensitivity of the results to this type of aggregation, the
individual and aggregate production specifications are re-estimated
using weighted least squares, where the number of production workers
serves as the weight. The estimates for the returns to hours and workers
are provided in columns 5 and 6 of the Appendix. The weighted least
squares estimates yield an average return to hours of 0.77, with 14 of
the 16 significant estimates less than one. The application of weighted
least squares to account for size differences among states yields
comparable results for the state data (not reported). Thus, the
qualitative conclusions are unaffected by using generalized least
squares.
5. Concluding Remarks
Some policy analysts in the U.S. and Europe have suggested that
employment can be increased by restricting the standard workweek and
inducing firms to substitute workers for hours. A crucial criticism of
this policy is that firms will be forced to substitute highly productive
hours for less productive new hires, thus offsetting any possible
positive employment response. Prior empirical studies have been
supportive of this criticism, generally finding returns to hours to be
greater than one. We argue that prior estimates are biased upward due to
previously unmeasured differences in production technology between
industries. In particular, our analysis uses similar techniques and data
to those in prior studies but relaxes the common production structure
across industries imposed in earlier work. Our industry-specific
production function results indicate that the returns to hours are less
than one for most U.S. industries, while the imposition of a common
production structure on the data yields returns to hours that are
greater than one. Furthermore, our results suggest that returns to
workers are greater than returns to hours for most U.S. industries,
which casts some doubt on the proposition that a marginal substitution from hours to workers will result in a decrease in labor productivity.
The importance of return to hours estimates is noted in studies
that simulate the employment response of a shorter workweek. For
example, a simulation by Brunstad and Holm (1990) using Norwegian data
indicates that a 2.5-hour reduction in the workweek generates 53,000
jobs when the return to hours is 0.6 and only 4000 jobs when the return
to hours is 1.4. Our results, nonetheless, indicate significant
variation in the returns to hours across industries, suggesting that the
effectiveness of a workweek reduction may vary greatly across
industries. Moreover, unions are also likely to push for wage
adjustments to reduce the loss in income from a workweek reduction
and/or market forces could also hypothetically cause a shift in wages;
such wage adjustments may partially or fully offset any positive
employment effects (Hart 1987; Trejo 1993). Thus, while our
return-to-hour estimates provide a more optimistic assessment of the
likely employment effects from a workweek reduction, the effects could
vary across industry and be limited by worker demands for higher wages.
The results also have little to say about returns to labor inputs
outside of manufacturing and thus are only relevant for a fraction of
the U.S. labor force. It is within U.S. manufacturing, however, that
hours reduction is most likely to become an issue. While employment in
U.S. manufacturing has been stagnant during recent decades, average
worker hours has actually increased, a trend not apparent in the
manufacturing sectors of other high-income countries (Fitzgerald 1996).
The empirical results are also useful in analyzing the effects of
another work-sharing policy, raising the overtime premium. Legislation
in 1994 that proposed reducing the workweek also mandated an increase in
the overtime premium from 1.5 to 2. While there is generally more
agreement that this would cause an increase in employment rather than a
workweek reduction (Hart 1987), the size of the increase depends on the
return to hours. Again, high returns to hours limit the substitution to
more workers and also adversely affect the competitiveness of U.S.
manufacturing firms. In comparison to previous studies, our
return-to-hours estimates suggest a larger employment increase and a
smaller increase in production costs.
In summary, recent labor negotiations indicate that workers are
concerned with hours of work as well as wages, suggesting the
worksharing policies may increasingly become an issue in labor
negotiations. Theoretical worker-hour models suggest reliable estimates
of the returns to hours are important in understanding the opportunity
costs of possible tradeoffs between hours and workers. Our results
provide preliminary evidence that prior estimates of the returns to
hours are biased upward by aggregating across industries and that hours
reductions are not likely to significantly increase labor costs or
decrease productivity. Nonetheless, our analysis does not explicitly
account for the use of part-time work or overtime hours but relies on
mean hours of work that may cover up significant variation in the
worker-hour mix by industry. Thus, further work must be done to examine
the extent to which the mix of workers and hours varies with their
returns.
The authors would like to thank the two anonymous referees, whose
comments greatly improved the paper. Any remaining mistakes are our own.
1 The tobacco industry is excluded because of missing data for
capital expenditures.
2 The unemployment rate, while also available by industry over
time, is measured by state over time because the firm's labor
supply depends largely on the state labor market and because the
relatively larger state versus time dimension allows for greater
variation in the unemployment measure.
3 Our fixed-effects specifications follow prior analyses, which are
supported by Hausman tests that cannot reject the hypothesis that
fixed-effects are appropriate. However, the industry-specific
regressions are re-estimated using random effects to test the
sensitivity of the results to assumptions regarding unobserved
heterogeneity. The random-effects estimates yield 11 significant
return-to-hour estimates, of which 10 are significantly less than one.
4 Random-effects specifications yield much more precise and
plausible parameter estimates for the capital stock. In particular, 16
of the 19 coefficient estimates are significantly positive in these
specifications, with magnitudes ranging from 0.7 to 0.04. This may
suggest that random effects are better able to account for the
measurement error in capital.
5 The capital stock is determined by first aggregating the data by
state and then employing the earlier procedure of backwards induction
from the 1978 capital stock using new capital expenditures from 1972 to
1977.
6 Estimates that use the full aggregate data for all 19 industries
yield estimates of returns to hours and workers that are of a similar
magnitude to those presented; these estimates are insignificant,
however, at traditional levels.
References
Berman, Eli, John Bound, and Zvi Griliches. 1994. Changes in the
demand for skilled labor within U.S. manufacturing: Evidence from the
annual survey of manufactures. Quarterly Journal of Economics,
109:367-97.
Blackburn, McKinley L., and David Neumark. 1993. Omitted-ability
bias and the increase in the return to schooling. Journal of Labor
Economics 11:521-44.
Brunstad, Rolf J., and Thomas Holm. 1990. Can shorter hours solve
the problem of unemployment? Unpublished Paper, Institute of Economics,
University of Bergen.
Craine, Roger. 1973. On the service flow from labour. Review of
Economic Studies 40:39-46.
DeBeaumont, Ronald. 1993. Worker/hour labor demand models and
policies to increase employment through worksharing. Ph.D. dissertation,
University of Oregon, Eugene, OR.
Fay, Jon A., and James L. Medoff. 1985. Labor and output over the
business cycle: Some direct evidence. American Economic Review
75:638-55.
Feldstein, Martin. 1967. Specification of the labour input in the
aggregate production function. Review of Economic Studies 34:375-86.
Fitzgerald, Terry J. 1996. Reducing working hours. Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland Economic Review 32:13-22.
Hamermesh, Daniel S. 1996. Labor demand. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
Hart, Robert A. 1987. Working time and employment. Boston: Allen and Unwin.
Hart, Robert A., and Peter G. McGregor. 1988. The returns to labour
services in West German manufacturing industry. European Economic Review
32:947-63.
Holm, Pasi, and Kiander Jaakko. 1993. The effects of work sharing
on employment and overtime in finnish manufacturing 1960-87: Comparison
of three alternative models. Applied Economics 25:801-10.
Kahn, Sulamit B., and Kevin Lang. 1995. Causes of hours
constraints: Evidence from Canada. Canadian Journal of Economics
28:914-28.
Leslie, Derek G. 1991. Modeling hours of work in a labour services
function. Scottish Journal of Political Economy 38:19-31.
Leslie, Derek, and John Wise. 1980. The productivity of working
hours in UK manufacturing and production industries. Economic Journal
90:74-84.
Marchand, O., D. Rault, and E. Turpin. 1983. Des 40 heures aux 39
heures: Processus et reactions des enterprises. Economie et Statistique
3-15.
Stratton, Leslie S. 1996. Are 'involuntary' part-time
workers indeed involuntary? Industrial and Labor Relations Review 49:522-36.
Trejo, Stephen J. 1991. Overtime pay regulation on worker
compensation. American Economic Review 81:719-40.
Trejo, Stephen J. 1993. Overtime pay, overtime hours, and labor
unions. Journal of Labor Economics 11:253-78.
U.S. Bureau of Census. 1958-1994. Annual survey of manufactures.
U.S. Bureau of Census. 1972, 1977. Census of manufactures.
U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis. 1972-1978. Survey of current
business.
U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. 1978. Employment and earnings.
U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. 1978. Industrial production and
capacity utilization and industrial material.
U.S. President. 1978. Manpower report of the President.
van Ginneken, Wouter. 1984. Employment and the reduction of the
workweek: A comparison of seven European macro-economic models.
International Labour Review 123:35-52.
White, Michael, and Abby Ghobadian. 1984. Shorter hours in
practice. London: Policy Institute Studies.
Whitley, J. D., and R. A. Wilson. 1986. The impact on employment of
a reduction in the length of the working week. Cambridge Journal of
Economics 10:43-59.