Advertising and quality in the U.S. market for automobiles.
Nichols, Mark W.
1. Introduction
Each year, automobile manufacturers spend millions of dollars on
advertising. Between January and September 1995, for example, General
Motors (GM) spent $1.07 billion (Crain Communications, Inc. 1996). What
function do such large outlays serve, and what is the correlation
between these outlays and a vehicle's quality? Do high-quality
producers use advertising as a means to signal their quality to
relatively uninformed consumers or do low-quality producers take
advantage of this information asymmetry and mimic their high-quality
competitors, thereby inhibiting advertising's use as a signal? On
the other hand, does advertising merely serve an informational role,
reminding consumers that a product's recent ancestors proved to be
high quality?
These questions continue to be a perennial debate in economics. While
recent game-theory literature thoroughly analyzes advertising's
ability to signal quality (reviewed below), empirical evidence is
somewhat limited and generally mixed. For example, Caves (1986) and
Tellis and Fornell (1988), using the Profit Impact of Market Strategies
database (a broad interindustry data set), show that high quality
generally induces higher advertising expenditures. In contrast, Caves
and Greene (1996), conducting a multiple-product analysis of quality,
price, and advertising, find a positive correlation between advertising
and quality when examining goods where buyers' experience and
search are effective at guiding brand choice but a negative correlation for convenience goods.
One explanation for these mixed findings is the use of broad
cross-sectional data sets and treatment of advertising as a homogenous activity in different markets. Indeed, the findings of Caves and Greene
(1996) support the idea that the use of advertising varies across
industries depending on market structure, product characteristics, and
consumer characteristics and that "empirical studies using
individual industries as cross-sectional observations may be
economically uninterpretable" (Leffler 1981, p. 46).
In an attempt to avoid this potential pitfall, the present study
employs data from the U.S. automobile market and compares outlays on
superior products relative to inferior products for producers of
otherwise identical goods, that is, it conducts an intraindustry
analysis in order to avoid any potential bias introduced by analyzing
multiple-product, cross-sectional data. Nevertheless, even in an
intraindustry study there are several confounding factors to consider.
For example, consumers' knowledge of the product will influence
advertising. Ceteris paribus, greater knowledge about product quality
should result in lower advertising expenditures. In addition, there may
exist manufacturer-specific factors, such as the number of models
produced, that influence advertising. A detailed description of the
model and controlling factors employed in this study are provided in
Section 3.
The automobile industry is chosen to conduct the intraindustry
analysis because model-specific information on advertising outlays and
product quality is readily available. More importantly, however, the
quality ratings for automobiles employed in this study are unobservable
when a car is new and being advertised. The ratings, which first become
available a year after a vehicle's introduction, therefore reflect
information on quality that is unknown to the consumer at the time of
purchase. This feature, current advertising expenditures and unknown
quality, provides a unique opportunity to empirically examine hypotheses
offered by the recent game-theory literature on the ability of
advertising to signal product quality to relatively uninformed
consumers.
Before proceeding, it should be noted that, while quality ratings on
the current model being advertised are unavailable, ratings on a
previous model's quality do exist. To the extent that quality
ratings are highly correlated over time, past quality may be a reliable
indicator of current quality. In short, current quality may not be
completely unknown to consumers. If true, advertising's role may be
to simply inform or remind consumers of high quality in the past. To
distinguish between these two hypotheses (signalling versus
information), the current study controls for past quality, examines how
changes in the (future) quality rating from past quality ratings impact
advertising, and compares advertising and quality for introductory
models where no past data exist. The results reveal that advertising is
multidimensional and serves both as a signal of quality and a provider
of information. Nevertheless, strong support for the signalling
hypothesis is found when controlling for past quality and when examining
changes in quality. Nowhere in the analysis is it found that low-quality
automobiles are advertised more intensively.
The next section reviews theories on the strategic use and
determinants of advertising. Section 3 describes the empirical model and
the choice of variables to empirically test the advertising-as-a-signal
hypothesis. This is followed by a discussion of the methodology used to
derive the results reported in section 4. Section 5 concludes the paper.
2. Theories on the Strategic Use and Determinants of Advertising
There is a vast theoretical literature addressing the strategic use
of advertising and its correlation to quality. Much of this literature
focuses on experience goods whose quality is costly to ascertain prior
to purchase and is only learned over time with consumption (Nelson
1970). While this literature varies dramatically in its assumptions and
conclusions, a central theme is advertising's ability to signal
quality to uninformed consumers.
The origin of the signalling literature can be traced back to Nelson
(1970, 1974). In this series of seminal articles, Nelson distinguishes
between search and experience goods and the informational content of
advertising. In the case of search goods, advertising provides direct,
credible information about product characteristics and quality because
consumers can verify this information prior to purchase. With experience
goods, however, quality is not verifiable prior to purchase.
Consequently, claims of high quality lack credibility because they can
be freely made by all producers. Realizing this, consumers will
rationally ignore any direct claims about high quality. Nevertheless,
the consumer can extract indirect information. In particular, the
consumer learns that the brand is being advertised. Therefore, in the
case of experience goods, it is the level of advertising, not
necessarily the information content, that provides information to
consumers.
The mechanism leading to a positive correlation between advertising
levels and quality in Nelson's model is repeat purchases. There are
two ways that repeat purchases induce a positive correlation between
advertising and quality. First, when only high-quality products induce
repeat purchases, high-quality producers have a greater incentive to
advertise in order to increase demand and expected profits. Second,
because high-quality products induce repeat purchases, high-quality
producers will wish to distinguish themselves from low-quality
producers. For this to occur through advertising, low-quality producers
must be unable to recoup the costs of advertising necessary to mimic the
advertising strategies of high-quality producers.
There are subtle, but distinct, differences between these two
strategies. In the first scenario, firms are not intentionally signalling their quality. Instead, they are merely trying to increase
demand in the initial period in order to induce future sales and
increase expected profits. In the second scenario, however, the firm is
intentionally signalling its quality to consumers, thereby
distinguishing itself from its low-quality competitors. In this latter
case, it is immaterial whether advertising has any direct impact on
demand.
More recent studies on advertising as a signal of quality have
followed the second scenario, focusing on cost differences between high-
and low-quality firms. For example, Khilstrom and Riordan (1984) provide
a formal game theoretic model to Nelson's argument where higher
fixed, but not marginal, costs for high-quality firms result in
advertising signalling quality. This requires that high-quality firms be
able to recover their advertising costs (through repeat sales) while
low-quality firms cannot and that consumers know enough about cost
differences to realize that only high-quality firms can profitably
advertise.
Klein and Leffler (1981) model advertising as a signal of the
existence of a firm-specific selling cost and the existence of a price
premium. This, too, results in a positive correlation between
advertising and quality. In particular, knowing that sunk costs (advertising) are only profitable if the expected future quasi-rents
exceed the one-time gain from cheating, that is, providing low quality
at the higher price, larger advertising expenditures signal larger price
premiums and higher quality.
Finally, Milgrom and Roberts (1986) extend this literature by
providing a model where a monopolist signals quality through both price
and advertising or other dissipative expenditures, The extension is
perhaps best understood in the context of Klein and Leffler, recognizing
that the price premium enjoyed by high-quality firms can be used by
consumers to infer quality.
All of the above studies are valuable contributions to the signalling
literature. However, the ability to directly test them empirically is
limited. Very little of the signalling literature deals with an
oligopoly setting where the actions of rival firms may have an impact on
advertising decisions. In fact, Milgrom and Roberts (1986, p. 802) note
that "the assumption of monopoly seems natural in this context, at
least in comparison with the perfectly competitive alternative. Treating
the intermediate case of oligopoly would involve significant additional
problems." Nevertheless, there is no reason to rule out the
possibility that the actions of rivals are an important determinant of a
firm's advertising decision in an oligopolistic market such as
automobiles (see, e.g., Kwoka [1993], who shows that the action of
rivals influences a firm's sales).
Another factor clouding any empirical test is the fact that most of
the signalling literature assumes advertising is purely dissipative and
has no direct effect on demand.(1) This seems implausible given that
advertising for automobiles, in addition to being a potential signal of
quality, will carry information about price, warranty, style, etc. Firms
may be just as likely to advertise to increase demand as to signal
quality. Therefore, there is a need to consider other factors that
influence the firm's advertising decision and to consult the
non-game-theoretic models that address the determinants of
nondissipative advertising.
One of the first papers to examine the optimal advertising intensity
was Dorfman and Steiner (1954). Specifically, for a profit maximizing
firm, the advertising-to-sales ratio will equal the ratio of the
advertising demand elasticity to the product demand elasticity or,
similarly, the product of the price cost margin and the advertising
elasticity. Conclusions arising from these optimality conditions are
that products with lower demand elasticities and/or higher profit
margins will have higher advertising expenditures.
More recent non-game-theoretic studies have examined the determinants
of advertising using a derived demand framework (e.g., Porter 1976;
Ehrlich and Fisher 1982; Caves 1986). In these models, as with
signalling models, consumers have imperfect knowledge about product
quality. Therefore, consumers seek information from various sources such
as word of mouth, technical publications, and advertising. It is this
demand for information that leads to a derived demand for advertising.
According to Ehrlich and Fisher (1986, p. 366), "[Advertising] can
be constructed on the assumption that it affects not tastes, but the
opportunities under which advertised products can be acquired.
[Advertising] affects the demand for goods because it lowers the gap
between the market price received by the seller and the full price borne
by the buyer." While consumer knowledge about a product is clearly
an unknown, variables capturing the newness of the product are used as
proxies (Caves 1986).
The non-game-theoretic approaches to advertising are useful for
examining the determinants of advertising but unfortunately, unlike the
game-theoretic signalling literature, depicting the relationship between
advertising and quality is not their primary purpose. Moreover, they
often will not examine why consumers respond to advertising. Rather,
consumers are simply assumed to respond to advertising, many times
according to a specific or ad hoc functional form (e.g., Schmalensee
1978).
In summary, both the game- and non-game-theoretic models make varying
assumptions and offer useful conclusions about the levels of
advertising. However, neither is completely satisfactory for the purpose
of empirically testing the relationship between advertising and quality.
The signalling literature generally ignores the impact of advertising on
demand, while the non-game-theoretic literature provides little
theoretical basis for the correlation between advertising and quality.
Nevertheless, it seems plausible that advertising could be used by firms
to both signal quality and influence demand. Unfortunately, firms do not
separate their advertising expenditures according to these categories.
Instead, only total advertising is observed. Consequently, the empirical
model chosen for this study adopts ideas from both sets of literature
and examines how advertising varies with quality and various other
determinants of advertising.
Before proceeding with the empirical model, it should be noted that
other scholars have extended the advertising/signalling literature by
allowing for multiple signals such as advertising and price (Milgrom and
Roberts 1986) and price and warranties (Lutz 1989). In the matter of
warranties, Lutz offers a model where warranties serve as a signal of
quality when high-quality products are cheaper to warrant than
low-quality products.
A complete empirical analysis of all potential signals of quality is
a daunting task, and this paper is merely a first attempt at analyzing a
very difficult problem. Consequently, the analysis focuses primarily on
the advertising/quality link. Warranties are difficult to analyze
because there is little variation between brands. Moreover, there is
evidence that interpreting warranties is costly to consumers, limiting
their ability to signal quality (Crocker 1986). Similarly, price as a
signal of quality is difficult to analyze because producers may choose
not to simultaneously use price and advertising to signal quality when
signal loss is possible (Hertzendorf 1993). When consumers cannot
distinguish between no advertising and not seeing the advertisement (TV
not turned on), low-quality producers can successfully mimic the pricing
strategies of high-quality producers and price will not vary with
quality.
3. Empirical Model and Data
To examine the relationship between the levels of advertising and
quality and other various determinants of advertising, the following
equation is estimated:
[ADV.sub.j,t] = [[Beta].sub.0] + [[Beta].sub.1][q.sub.j,t] +
[Gamma][K.sub.j,t] + [Pi][C.sub.j,t] + [Lambda][X.sub.j,t] +
[[Epsilon].sub.j,t], (1)
where [ADV.sub.j,t] represents advertising for model j at time t,
[q.sub.j,t] represents the quality of model j at time t, [K.sub.j,t]
proxies for buyer knowledge through variables that capture the newness
of model j at time t, [C.sub.j,t] represents industry and manufacture
specific conditions that affect advertising, [X.sub.j,t] represents
other control variables that affect advertising, and [Gamma], [Pi], and
[Lambda], are vectors of coefficients.
To estimate Equation 1, this study employs a dataset consisting of
various car models (e.g., Ford Thunderbird, Toyota Corolla) produced by
U.S. and foreign manufacturers for the model years 1985-1990. Only
models where consistent trouble indices were reported by Consumer
Reports (CR) (Consumers' Union 1986-1995) are included. Over 100
models are available in each model year, yielding a sample of 630
observations. Nominal dollar values are adjusted for inflation using the
consumer price index (CPI). A description of the variables included in
the empirical analysis and their mean values are provided in Appendix A.
The choice of particular variables and their expected impact on
advertising expenditures is discussed below.
Advertising expenditures [ADV.sub.j,t] are drawn from Leading
National Advertisers Class/Brand Year to Date for 1984-1990.
Expenditures are reported for different categories, including magazines,
newspaper supplements, network television, spot television, network
radio, and outdoor. Total advertising is defined as the sum of these
categories. Television advertising is the sum of network and spot
television, while print advertising includes magazine and newspaper
supplements. Advertising in newspapers and cable television are not
included because they were not available for the entire sample
period.(2)
Quality [q.sub.j,t] is defined as the average of all available
trouble indices for model j reported by CR.(3) A value of one is given
if a car is much better than average, while a value of five is given to
vehicles that are rated much worse than average. Thus, higher values of
the trouble index reflect poorer quality.(4) Again, this information on
quality is not observed by consumers when a car is new. If advertising
is used to signal high quality, larger advertising expenditures should
be associated with smaller values of the trouble index.
The next set of variables in Equation 1, [K.sub.j,t], pertain to the
newness of the car model and proxy for consumer prior knowledge of the
product. [K.sub.j,t] includes dummy variables equal to one if the model
has been mechanically redesigned, if the model had significant styling
changes, that is, all new body panels, and if the vehicle is an
introductory model launched for the first time.
Vehicles that have been mechanically redesigned are expected to have
higher advertising, ceteris paribus, since consumers may have limited
knowledge about these changes or their effects on the car's
performance. Styling changes, in contrast, are highly visible and there
may be less demand for information from the producer. Consequently,
styling changes are expected to have little impact on advertising.
Consumers have little or no information on introductory models. For
example, consumers had limited information to judge the quality of the
Ford Taurus when it was first introduced in 1986. Moreover,
manufacturers may simply want to make consumers aware that a new model
exists. Therefore, advertising levels for introductory models are
expected to be higher, ceteris paribus.
Industry and manufacturer conditions [C.sub.j,t], also enter the
advertising equation. The number of models offered by a manufacturer,
total sales of model j at time t, price, and engineering and styling
changes of rival manufacturers are included.
The number of models offered by any particular manufacturer is
expected to affect advertising, but its directional impact is ambiguous.
If spillovers or externalities exist among advertised models, producers
offering more models may have lower advertising expenditures. On the
other hand, a larger number of models may require higher advertising
outlays given the increase in consumer choice.
Ceteris paribus, higher sales are predicted to be associated with
higher advertising expenditures. Dorfman and Steiner (1954) have shown
that the advertising-to-sales ratio should equal the ratio of the
advertising-demand elasticity to the product-demand elasticity. Thus, if
elasticities are relatively constant, firms will maintain a constant
advertising-to-sales ratio.(5)
Yet another application of Dorfman-Steiner is that models with higher
profit margins will have higher advertising expenditures. If profit
margins and quality are positively correlated, failure to account for
this may bias the empirical results. Unfortunately, model-specific
profit margins are unavailable. Therefore, market price for model j at
time t + 1 is used as a proxy.(6) Ceteris paribus, advertising is
predicted to be greater for higher priced, that is, markup, vehicles.
The actions of rival manufacturers also enter the advertising
function shown in Equation 1. Rivals are defined as other
manufacturers' models competing in the same class. For example,
rivals to the Cadillac are all large, non-GM cars. Styling and
engineering changes by rivals are expected to increase advertising
outlays.
Finally, included as other control variables, [X.sub.j,t], are a
trend variable and manufacturer and class-size dummies. The trend
variable captures the changing expenditures on advertising over the
sample period and controls for any macroconditions that simultaneously
affect the advertising levels of all automobile manufacturers. Dummy
variables for U.S. (GM, Ford, and Chrysler) manufacturers control for
manufacturer-specific effects (foreign is the excluded category).
Finally, dummies for compact, medium, and large (small is the excluded
category) account for any class-specific effects. Berry, Levinsohn, and
Pakes (1995) have shown that crowded segments, such as small and compact
vehicles, have greater price elasticities of demand. This suggests that
these vehicles will be advertised less, ceteris paribus, a la
Dorfman-Steiner.
4. Methodology and Results
Before presenting results, a brief discussion of the specification of
the advertising equation is in order. The advertising equation is
estimated using two-stage least squares with [SALES.sub.j,t-1],
[REALPCY.sub.t], and [GASPRICE.sub.t] serving to (over) identify the
[ADV.sub.j,t] and [SALES.sub.j,t] relationship.(7) The suitability of
these instruments is confirmed by the high partial [R.sup.2] (0.85) and
F statistic (850.26) for the excluded instruments.(8) A semilog model is
estimated because it provides a better fit using a Box-Cox (Box and Cox
1964) test.(9) Applying a Koyck transformation results in the following
equation to be estimated:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], (2)
where [ADV.sub.j,t-1], i = 0, 1, are log values and [q.sub.j,t],
[K.sub.j,t], [C.sub.j,t], and [X.sub.j,t] are defined as above.(10)
Table 1. Average Trouble Index/Change in Average Trouble Index for
U.S., Leading Japanese and Foreign Manufacturers
Year U.S.(a) Leading Japanese(b) Other Foreign(c)
1985 3.75/- 0.16 1.33/0.01 2.41/0.19
(0.82)/(0.45) (0.57)/(0.44) (0.95)/(0.55)
1986 3.64/-0.20 1.29/-0.01 2.34/0.02
(0.83)/(0.48) (0.39)/(0.15) (0.72)/(0.46)
1987 3.61/-0.22 1.46/0.15 2.37/0.13
(0.88)/(0.60) (0.66)/(0.41) (0.91)/(0.67)
1988 3.50/-0.20 1.35/0.00 2.54/0.22
(0.88)/(0.78) (0.54)/(0.30) (1.02)/(0.80)
1989 3.60/-0.13 1.31/-0.04 2.55/0.18
(0.96)/(0.89) (0.45)/(0.40) (1.25)/(0.87)
1990 3.38/-0.22 1.33/0.10 2.60/0.18
(0.89)/(0.92) (0.33)/(0.46) (1.13)/(0.74)
Change in average trouble index is the current model's average
trouble index minus the average trouble index of last year's model.
Standard deviation in parentheses.
a U.S. automobiles are GM, Ford, and Chrysler.
b Leading Japanese automobiles are Honda, Nissan, and Toyota.
c Other foreign consists of BMW, Hyundai, Mazda, Mercedes Benz,
Mitsubishi, Saab, Volkswagen, and Volvo.
Table 1 reflects the pattern of quality change over the sample period
by showing the level of the average trouble index and its average annual
change, defined as the average trouble index of the current model minus
the average trouble index of last year's model, for U.S., leading
Japanese, and other foreign automobiles. Confirming general market
perceptions, Japanese automobiles have higher quality than the other
manufacturers. Moreover, there is less variation in quality among the
various Japanese models, as indicated by the smaller standard deviation of the average trouble index. Table 1 also reveals that the relative
quality of U.S. automobiles improved over the sample period. The change
in the average trouble index is negative for all years, and while the
overall reduction in the average trouble index may appear small, 3.75 in
1985 to 3.38 in 1990, it is important to keep in mind that this measure
cannot account for improvements in all automobiles over time since
CR's ratings are model-year specific. Thus, [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE
2 OMITTED] the rising value of the average trouble index for other
foreign cars does not indicate that 1990 models are of lower quality
than 1985 models since the quality of all vehicles has improved over
time. It does indicate, however, that relative improvements among
foreign cars are occurring below the average rate. The end result is a
deterioration in the relative quality of foreign automobiles, causing
their average trouble index to increase. By the same reasoning, U.S.
automobiles are improving at a faster rate, causing their trouble index
to decline.(11) This feature, differing levels of quality and changes in
quality over time, make the automobile industry, and U.S. automobiles in
particular, an interesting case study to examine advertising's role
in conveying information and signalling quality.
Table 2 shows the simple correlation between the average trouble
index and total advertising expenditures and the average trouble index
and price by model year. Generally, the results show a negative
correlation, reflecting a positive relationship between quality and
advertising and quality and price because higher values of the trouble
index reflect poorer quality. While this does not hold in model years
1985 and 1988 for advertising and quality, the positive correlation
between advertising and the trouble index in those years is generally
small.
Table 3 provides evidence on real advertising expenditures per model
over the period and the allocation across television and print media.
Total expenditures on advertising have risen over the sample period,
with the largest increase coming between 1987 and 1988. Moreover, nearly
all of the increase has been due to greater outlays on television
advertising. Print advertising, in contrast, rose only slightly, and by
1990 had nearly returned to its 1985 level. On average, the U.S. has
lower advertising expenditures per model than foreign manufacturers.(12)
Two-stage least squares estimates of Equation 2 are provided in Table
4, with total, television, and print advertising equations reported. All
variables are of the expected sign, and several are significant. The
variable of most interest for our purpose is the average trouble index.
The results for total advertising suggest that an above-average model (a
value of two) would have advertising expenditures approximately 15%
higher than an average model (a value of three). Moreover, much of the
advertising is seen to occur on television, where an above-average model
has expenditures approximately 19% higher. The reliance on television
advertising is intriguing given its reputation for excessive
expenditures on fluff or noninformative material.(13) While generally
providing few hard facts, little factual information can be credibly conveyed for experience goods since much of the information is
unverifiable. Television, therefore, provides an excellent medium to
signal quality through conspicuous, flashy commercials, whose primary
information is that the firm spent a lot of money for the advertisement.
While the coefficient on the trouble index for print advertising is
insignificant, the above results generally support the hypothesis that
higher quality products are more heavily advertised.(14)
Table 3. Mean Advertising Expenditure per Model by Media Type(a)
Year Total Television(b) Print(c)
U.S. Automobiles(d)
1985 9502 6466 2885
1986 7556 5011 2432
1987 8623 5676 2793
1988 13,081 9341 3394
1989 11,848 8583 2900
1990 13,491 10,275 2896
Foreign Automobiles(e)
1985 8713 5428 3121
1986 9430 6250 3045
1987 11,520 7729 3650
1988 12,836 8969 3646
1989 15,691 11,281 3950
1990 15,512 11,935 3157
a Expressed in thousands of dollars.
b Television consists of network and spot coverage.
c Print includes magazines and newspaper supplements.
d U.S. automobiles are GM, Ford, and Chrysler.
e Foreign automobiles are all others.
As expected, sales are shown to positively influence advertising. An
increase in sales of 1000 is associated with a 0.29% increase in
advertising expenditures (approximately $32,500 using the average
advertising expenditure given in Appendix A). The existence of spillover effects in advertising, where consumers associate quality with the
manufacturer (e.g., Ford) rather than the model (e.g., Escort), is
supported by the fact that manufactures with more models have lower
expenditures per model, ceteris paribus.
While style changes have been shown by Kwoka (1993) to increase
sales, they have no effect on advertising expenditures. Style changes
are easily discernible by the consumer, and unlike quality and
engineering changes, there is less ambiguity about their effect.
Engineering changes, however, are less visible to the consumer and are
likely to be associated with improved quality due to better handling or
improved body design. While positive, the coefficient is not significant
at conventional levels. The positive and significant coefficient for
introductory models, [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 4 OMITTED] however, is
consistent with the hypothesis that little knowledge about them exists
and that information is transmitted, in part, through advertising.
Finally, the positive coefficient on price suggests that
manufacturers advertise higher priced (i.e., higher profit margin)
vehicles more intensively, ceteris paribus. Given the positive
correlation between quality and price in Table 2, this result is also
consistent with the simultaneous use of price and advertising as a
signal of quality. The result for total advertising, however, is not
significant at conventional levels. The coefficients on the manufacturer
dummies indicate that GM advertises more than foreign manufacturers,
whereas Ford and Chrysler do not. In addition, television advertising on
compact vehicles is significantly higher than expenditures on small
cars. Generally, however, compact, medium, and large cars have
advertising expenditures that are not statistically different from small
vehicles.(15)
The above results demonstrate that higher quality vehicles are more
heavily advertised, even when controlling for other influential factors
such as profit margins, elasticity of demand, technological changes,
etc. These expenditures may not be signalling new information to
consumers, however, if the quality of this year's model is highly
correlated with the quality of earlier models. In short, last
year's quality may serve as a sufficient indicator of this
year's quality. To account for this, Equation 2 was estimated
including the quality of the previous year's model.(16) The
results, provided in Appendix B, are nearly identical to those reported
in Table 4, supporting the advertising-as-a-signal hypothesis as opposed
to the hypothesis that advertising solely provides information about
past quality.(17) Nevertheless, if advertising truly signals high
quality, the largest expenditures should occur when quality changes
significantly from the previous year or on high-quality introductory
models, where little or no previous information exists.
To test the hypothesis that advertising is higher when quality is
most improved, the change in the current model year's average
trouble index from the previous year is included in the advertising
equation.(18) The previous model year's average trouble index is
also included to control for the absolute level of quality. The results,
presented in column 1 of Table 5, show that advertising expenditures
significantly rise when quality improves from the previous year. The
coefficient on the change in the average trouble index is negative and
statistically significant. This suggests that manufacturers are
signalling their quality improvements to consumers through higher
advertising expenditures. Coefficient estimates on the remaining
variables mirror those described above.
Column 2 of Table 5 introduces the average trouble index interacted
with the introductory model dummy variable. While the coefficient on the
interaction term is negative, it is not statistically significant at
conventional levels. While earlier results revealed that producers are
advertising both introductory models and higher-quality models more
intensively, higher-quality introductory models are not advertised
significantly more than older models with similar quality. A potential
explanation for this result is that advertising's role of providing
information dominates its use as a signal of quality in the case of
introductory models.
As a final investigation into the advertising behavior of the auto
manufacturers, column 3 of Table 5 provides results when the average
trouble index is replaced with dummy variables representing each level
of quality. To be included in a category, a model must have received a
majority (at least three out of five) of those rankings. For example, a
vehicle that was rated [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 5 OMITTED] much better
than average (trouble index equal to one) for three out of five years
and better than average (trouble index equal to two) for two of the five
years would be considered much better than average. On the other hand, a
vehicle rated much better than average for two of the five years and
better than average for three would be classified as better than
average. The results indicate that manufacturers do indeed advertise
above-average quality cars more heavily. In contrast, advertising levels
for average and worse than average cars are indistinguishable for models
whose quality is much worse than average (the omitted category). This is
consistent with a separating equilibrium where only the highest quality
firms incur large advertising expenditures.
Finally, column 4 of Table 5 replaces [SALES.sub.j,t] with the market
share of model j at time t, defined as model j's sales at time t
over total retail passenger car sales at time t. Bagwell and Ramey
(1993) suggest that firms incur greater advertising expenditures because
they have larger market shares rather than higher quality. The results
support this argument, in part. Manufacturers do incur higher
advertising expenditures on models with larger market shares. However,
higher quality vehicles are still found to be more heavily advertised,
ceteris paribus.
5. Concluding Remarks
This paper provides an empirical investigation into
advertising's role as a source of information and signal of quality
in the U.S. market for automobiles. The results reveal that advertising
serves both roles by providing information and signalling quality to
imperfectly informed consumers. Advertising expenditures are 15% higher
for an above average quality car relative to an average quality vehicle.
Moreover, a majority of advertising occurs through television, a medium
often criticized for its lack of informational content and intent to
persuade the consumer. This supports hypotheses offered by the
signalling literature that it is the amount as opposed to the content of
advertising that is important in providing information, especially for
experience goods. Television provides an efficient medium to reveal that
large advertising outlays are being made and consequently that quality
is high.(19)
The above study is by no means a definitive test of the signalling
hypothesis. While it is advantageous to examine a single industry, other
industries should be examined to determine the generality of the
conclusions offered here. Moreover, the present study only focuses on
advertising's ability to signal quality. Examining the role of
price and/or warranties would also be beneficial.
I have benefited from discussions with Kathleen Carroll, Gary
Fournier, Jill Hendrickson, Brad Kamp, Leola Ross, and Tim Sass. I would
also like to thank two anonymous referees and Editor Jonathan Hamilton
for their helpful suggestions. Any remaining errors are solely my
responsibility.
1 See, however, Hertzendorf (1990) and Overgaard (1991), who allow
for advertising that signals quality and has a direct impact on demand.
2 Data on cable television advertising were reported starting in
1985, while figures for newspapers were not available until 1987.
3 CR rates vehicles for five years beginning in the year following
its introduction. [q.sub.j,t] is the average of these five trouble
indices. For example. for the 1985 Ford Thunderbird, trouble indices
were available beginning in 1986 and reported through 1990. Other
measures were tested but had no appreciable impact on the results
reported below. These included using the first available trouble index,
the most favorable rating, and the least favorable rating.
4 The 1985 Ford Thunderbird is rated average (a value of three) in
all five years between 1986 and 1990. In contrast, the 1985 Buick Regal
has ratings of 5, 5, 3, 4, 4 between 1986 and 1990. respectively. The
average trouble index, the average of these five ratings, for the Ford
Thunderbird is 3, whereas for the Buick Regal it is 4.2. The higher
value of the average trouble index for the 1985 Regal classifies it as a
lower quality vehicle than the 1985 Thunderbird.
5 Of course, advertising also influences sales, so the use of sales
as an explanatory variable introduces the potential for simultaneity
bias. This is addressed using two-stage least squares to estimate the
results reported in section 4.
6 Average transaction price for model j at time t is not available.
The price at time t + 1, that is, the price of the model when it is one
year old. rather than the manufacturer's suggested retail price
(MSRP), is used for two reasons: First, it is likely to be highly
correlated with the new car price but avoids the potential simultaneity
bias resulting from using the price at time t. Second. it will reflect
the market's perceptions about reliability, popularity, etc., that
the time t transaction price captures but that the MSRP may not. Using
the MSRP did not, however, significantly affect the estimated results
reported below.
7 The structural equations for [SALES.sub.j,t] and [ADV.sub.j,t]
forming the basis for the two-stage least squares estimation are as
follows:
[SALES.sub.j,t] = [[Beta].sub.0] + [[Beta].sub.1][ADV.sub.j,t] +
[[Beta].sub.2][SALES.sub.j,t-1] + [[Beta].sub.3][AVERAGE TROUBLE
INDEX.sub.j,t] + [[Beta].sub.4][STYLE CHANGE.sub.j,t] +
[[Beta].sub.5][NEW ENGINEERING.sub.j,t] + [[Beta].sub.6][INTRODUCTORY
MODEL.sub.j,t] + [[Beta].sub.7][RIVAL STYLE CHANGE.sub.j,t] +
[[Beta].sub.8][RIVAL ENGINEERING CHANGE.sub.j,t] + [[Beta].sub.9]TREND +
[[Beta].sub.10]GM + [[Beta].sub.11]FORD + [[Beta].sub.12]CHRYSLER +
[[Beta].sub.13]COMPACT + [[Beta].sub.14]MEDIUM + [[Beta].sub.15]LARGE +
[[Beta].sub.16][GAS PRICE.sub.t] + [[Beta].sub.17][REAL PER CAPITA
INCOME.sub.t] + [[Epsilon].sub.j,t]
[ADV.sub.j,t] = [[Alpha].sub.0] + [[Alpha].sub.1][SALES.sub.j,t] +
[[Alpha].sub.2][ADV.sub.j,t-1] + [[Alpha].sub.3][AVERAGE TROUBLE
INDEX.sub.j,t] + [[Alpha].sub.4][STYLE CHANGE.sub.j,t] +
[[Alpha].sub.5][NEW ENGINEERING.sub.j,t] + [[Alpha].sub.6][INTRODUCTORY
MODEL.sub.j,t] + [[Alpha].sub.7][RIVAL STYLE CHANGE.sub.j,t] +
[[Alpha].sub.8][RIVAL ENGINEERING CHANGE.sub.j,t] + [[Alpha].sub.9]TREND
+ [[Alpha].sub.10]GM + [[Alpha].sub.11]FORD + [[Alpha].sub.12]CHRYSLER +
[[Alpha].sub.13]COMPACT + [[Alpha].sub.14]MEDIUM + [[Alpha].sub.15]LARGE
+ [[Alpha].sub.16] [NUMBER OF MODELS.sub.j,t] +
[[Alpha].sub.17][PRICE.sub.j,t] + [[Upsilon].sub.j,t]
8 The high partial [R.sup.2] and F-statistic on the excluded
instruments ([SALES.sub.j,t-1], [GASPRICE.sub.t], and [REALPCY.sub.t])
suggest a strong correlation between the instruments and endogenous explanatory variable ([SALES.sub.j,t],) and negligible finite-sample
bias. The partial [R.sup.2] is that from regressing [SALES.sub.j,t], on
the excluded instruments, while the F is found by restricting the
coefficients on the excluded instruments to zero in the first-stage
regression (see Bound, Jaeger, and Baker [1995]). Furthermore, a Hausman
test on the validity of the excluded instruments (comparing the OLS estimate of the coefficient on [SALES.sub.j,t] with its IV estimate,
that is. testing if plim([[Beta].sup.IV] - [[Beta].sup.OLS]) = 0) yields
a test statistic of [Mathematical Expression Omitted], failing to reject
the null of no regressor-error correlation.
9 The Box-Cox transformation may be applied to some or all of the
variables in the equation and allows the functional form to be
determined by the data. Applying the transformation to all variables
involves maximum likelihood estimation of the following: [Mathematical
Expression Omitted], where [Y.sup.[Lambda]] = ([Y.sup.[Lambda]] - 1) and
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] for all i. [Lambda] = 1 results in the
linear model, whereas [Lambda] = 0 results in the log-linear model. By
allowing [Lambda] to vary for each variable, more flexible
specifications arise.
10 The specification in Equation 2 (the lagged effects model) was
tested and favored over a model where lagged advertising is excluded but
the errors are serially correlated (the current effects model).
Distinguishing between these two involves running the following
regression:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
where Z includes [q.sub.j,t], [K.sub.j,t], [C.sub.j,t], and
[X.sub.j,t], [Rho] is the autocorrelation coefficient, and
[[Mu].sub.j,t] = [Rho][[Mu].sub.j,t-1] + [[Epsilon].sub.j,t]. The lagged
effects model is supported by a statistically insignificant coefficient
on lagged sales (t-statistic was 1.10). See Griliches (1967) for more
detail.
11 For an excellent summary of improving quality between 1980 and
1990, see "Is Detroit Closing the Reliability Gap?" Consumer
Reports, April 1991, pp. 248-249.
12 Measuring expenditures as advertising/sales or total advertising
by class of car yields a similar pattern, with the exception that U.S.
producers have greater expenditures than foreign producers in the large
and medium class.
13 Resnick and Stern (1977) show that only 49% of television
advertisements were informative, defined as communicating 1 of 14
informational cues (e.g., price, performance, availability). When
required to communicate 2 and 3 of the 14 information cues, the percent
of television advertisements deemed informative fell to 16% and 1%,
respectively.
14 While the coefficient on quality is statistically significant,
most of the model's explanatory power is captured by lagged
advertising. Dropping quality from the estimated equation lowers the
[R.sup.2] from 0.66 to 0.65. Estimating the model without lagged
advertising, however, yielded similar results, with the [R.sup.2]
dropping from 0.30 to 0.29 when quality is excluded.
15 An F-test that all manufacturer and class-size dummies are jointly
equal to zero resulted in an F-statistic of 2.97, rejecting the null
that all are jointly equal to zero. Excluding GM, however, resulted in
an F of 1.40, failing to reject the null.
16 For introductory models where no previous models exist, the
manufacturer's average trouble index was used.
17 Equation 2 was also estimated with the average trouble index from
the previous model replacing the (future) average trouble index. The
coefficient was negative but insignificant, reaffirming that producers
are not simply advertising to tout high quality in previous years and
lending further credence to the signalling hypothesis.
18 Again, since no earlier data exist for introductory models, their
improvement in quality is calculated as the change from the
manufacturer's average trouble index in the previous year.
19 While advertising prices vary by time of day, show, network, etc.,
on average, a 30-second commercial on network television in 1996 cost
$169,000 (Advertising Age, September 16, 1996). Expressing this in real
dollars, assuming that the average expenditures given in Table 3 were on
an average quality vehicle, and using the 19% difference between quality
classes given in Table 4 implies 40.37, 35.23, 41.79, 60.34, 63.34, and
71.09 more commercials per year for a vehicle of much better than
average quality (CR rank = 1) and a much worse than average quality
vehicle (CR rank = 5) for the years 1985-1990, respectively.
References
Advertising Age. 1996. September 16.
Bagwell, Kyle, and Garey Ramey. 1993. Advertising as information:
Matching products to buyers. Journal of Economics and Management
Strategy 2:199-243.
Berry, Steven, James Levinsohn, and Ariel Pakes. 1995. Automobile
prices in market equilibrium. Econometrica 63: 841-90.
Bound, John, David A. Jaeger, and Regina M. Baker. 1995. Problems
with instrumental variables estimation when the correlation between the
instruments and the endogenous explanatory variable is weak. Journal of
the American Statistical Association 90:443-50.
Box, G. E. P., and D. R. Cox. 1964. An analysis of transformations.
Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, (Series B) 26:211-43.
Caves, Richard E. 1986. Information structures of product markets.
Economic Inquiry 24:195-212.
Caves, Richard E., and David P. Greene. 1996. Brands' quality
levels, prices, and advertising outlays: Empirical evidence on signals
and information costs. International Journal of Industrial Organization
14:29-52.
Consumer's Union. 1986-1995. Consumer Reports. New York:
Consumer's Union.
Crain Communications, Inc. 1996. Advertising Age, 12 February.
Chicago: Crain Communications.
Crocker, Keith J. 1986. A reexamination of the 'lemons'
market when warranties are not prepurchase quality signals. Information
Economics and Policy 2:147-61.
Dorfman, Robert, and Peter O. Steiner. 1954. Optimal advertising and
optimal quality. American Economic Review 44: 826-36.
Ehrlich, Isaac, and Lawrence Fisher. 1982. The derived demand for
advertising: A theoretical and empirical investigation. American
Economic Review 72:366-88.
Griliches, Zvi. 1967. Distributed lags: A survey. Econometrica
35:16-49.
Hertzendorf, Mark N, 1990. I'm not a high-quality firm - But I
play one on TV: A model of signaling product quality. Unpublished paper,
University of Rochester.
Hertzendorf, Mark N. 1993. I'm not a high-quality firm - But I
play one on TV. Rand Journal of Economics 24:236-47.
Khilstrom, Richard E., and Michael H. Riordan. 1984. Advertising as a
signal. Journal of Political Economy 92:427-50.
Klein, Benjamin, and Keith B. Leffler. 1981. The role of market
forces in assuring contractual performance. Journal of Political Economy
89:615-41.
Kwoka, John E. Jr. 1993. The sales and competitive effects of styling
and advertising practices in the U.S. auto industry. The Review of
Economics and Statistics 75:649-56.
Leading National Advertisers, Inc. 1984-1990. Class/brand tear to
date. New York: Leading National Advertisers, Inc.
Leffler, Keith B. 1981. Persuasion or information? The economics of
prescription drug advertising. Journal of Law and Economics 24:45-74.
Lutz, Nancy A. 1989. Warranties as signals under consumer moral
hazard. Rand Journal of Economics 20:239-55.
Milgrom, Paul, and John Roberts. 1986. Price and advertising signals
of product quality. Journal of Political Economy 94:796-821.
Nelson, Phillip. 1970. Information and consumer behavior, Journal of
Political Economy 78:311-29.
Nelson, Phillip. 1974. Advertising as information. Journal of
Political Economy 82:729-54.
Overgaard, Per Baltzer. 1991. On the nature of advertising and its
role as a signal of quality. Unpublished paper, University of Aarhus.
Porter, Michael E. 1976. Interbrand choice, media mix, and market
performance. American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings
66:398-406.
Resnick, Alan, and Bruce L. Stern. 1977. An analysis of information
content in television advertising. Journal of Marketing 41:50-3.
Schmalensee, Richard. 1978. A model of advertising and product
quality. Journal of Political Economy 86:485-503.
Tellis, Gerard J., and Claes Fornell. 1988. The relationship between
advertising and product quality over the product life cycle: A
contingency theory. Journal of Marketing Research 25:64-71.