Tax and spend, or spend and tax? An inquiry into the Turkish budgetary process.
Darrat, Ali F.
1. Introduction
Contemporary economies, perhaps without exception, have been plagued
with huge and escalating government budget deficits. These deficits are
expected to have adverse economic consequences including high real
interest rates, slow capital formation, and high unemployment rates.
Moreover, to the extent that the deficit is financed through the
issuance of government bonds, the recurrent large deficits have further
worsened the public debt problem, which threatens the well-being of
numerous countries, both developed and developing.
Therefore, researchers and policymakers have expended enormous
efforts attempting to analyze the deficit problem and to suggest ways to
resolve it. Some, for example, advocate cuts in government spending rather than tax increases as the optimal solution to the deficit
dilemma. They reason that governments often spend all that they receive
in taxes and perhaps much more. Under this line of reasoning, raising
taxes would simply induce more spending, leaving the deficit unchanged
(or even higher). Others, however, deny this implied tax-and-spend
nexus, and argue that it is taxes that adjust gradually to spending.
Under this latter scenario, tax increases will not lead to higher
spending, and thus, could be used as an effective deficit-cutting
measure along with spending cuts. Still, other researchers posit that
changes in spending and taxes could occur simultaneously. Therefore,
focusing on one component of the government budget while ignoring the
interdependence with the other component would have an ambiguous overall
effect on the deficit.
Clearly, then, the optimal approach to solving the problem of
government budget deficits depends to a large extent on the
intertemporal relationship between government spending and taxation.
Indeed, there have been numerous studies that empirically gauge this
relationship (e.g., Anderson, Wallace, and Warner 1986; Manage and
Marlow 1986; von Furstenberg, Green, and Jeong 1986; Ram 1988; Ahiakpor
and Amirkhalkhali 1989; Joulfain and Mookerjee 1990; Miller and Russek
1990; Hoover and Sheffrin 1992; Lee and Vedder 1992; Owoye 1995).
Interestingly, the bulk of this voluminous empirical literature has
focused almost exclusively on the U.S. experience, with few studies
examining the case of other large industrialized major OECD countries.
By contrast, there has been, thus far, no attempt to study the
interrelationship between government spending and taxation for
developing countries; yet, the problem may be more acute in these
countries with huge and escalating deficits in recent years.
Investigating the government spending/taxation nexus in these countries
can provide useful information pertaining to the optimal solution to
their deficits. Note also that developing countries have often been
required to curtail budget deficits as a precondition to receiving
financial aid and/or loans from international organizations like the
International Monetary fund (IMF) or the World Bank.
The main purpose of this paper is to fill this gap in the literature
and examine the intertemporal relationship between government spending
and taxation in the case of Turkey. Since the 1960s, Turkey has had a
large and growing government sector. Measured by the share of government
expenditures in Gross National Product (GNP), the government sector in
Turkey expanded from less than 18% in the 1960s to claim more than 25%
of the economy in the 1990s. Taxes have also risen during the last three
decades but at a slower pace, resulting in persistent budget deficits.
Many analysts and popular commentators (Bugra 1994; Adaman and Sertel
1995; Pope 1996) have warned that such deficits, if they continue, can
seriously stifle economic activities and worsen the already bleak
international credit-worthiness of the country. So far in the 1990s,
inflation in Turkey has been running at about 75% annually, interest
rate on three-month government securities is more than 80% and the
public debt rose nearly 25% in the first quarter of 1996. Such bad
economic conditions have already threatened a new IMF aid package for
Turkey and also prompted the Standard & Poor's Ratings Group to
rank Turkey's long-term government securities among the lowest of
all countries. Although many elements, including perhaps political
instability, may be behind Turkey's economic and financial woes,
the large budget deficits have undoubtedly been a major contributing
factor. Indeed, there is a near consensus among economists and
public-policy observers in the region that it is indispensable for
Turkey to aggressively resolve the budget deficit dilemma and put the
public sector in order.
Of course, the contrasting viewpoints with respect to government
spending and taxation in Turkey presume the endogeneity of the Turkish
budgetary process.(1) Budget decisions in an endogenous framework are
determined in a large political body whose agents often exhibit
conflicting objectives. Despite several military interventions in Turkey
since the 1960s, the multiparty political system has remained largely a
democratic system with fundamental rights and freedoms guaranteed to all
citizens. The 1961 Constitution created a bicameral legislature
comprised of a National Assembly and a Senate with an elaborate system
of checks and balances on government authority. Among many
constitutional responsibilities, the legislators have exclusive powers
to make law, and they freely debate and amend the government's
proposed budget. The president, who is appointed by the parliament, can
veto legislation passed by the parliament. Since 1983, the country has
been ruled by a new Constitution, which was approved by a national
referendum in 1982. This Constitution established a popularly elected,
single-chambered parliament and continued to preserve the civil and
political rights of all citizens, but made these rights subordinate to
"national security," "national unity," and
"public morality."(2) Therefore, it appears that the Turkish
budgetary process is sufficiently endogenous without substantial regime
shifts, a setting that seems appropriate for the tests I perform in this
study.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2
provides a brief account of the literature on the government
spending/taxation nexus with emphasis on four alternative hypotheses
pertaining to this relationship. Section 3 describes the data and the
empirical methodology of the paper. The methodology is based on the
recent cointegration and error correction modeling in bivariate and
multivariate contexts. Section 4 reports the empirical results. Section
5 concludes the paper.
2. Alternative Hypotheses
Researchers have advanced four alternative hypotheses regarding the
government spending/taxation nexus. First, some researchers (e.g.,
Wildavsky 1988) have argued that government's decisions to spend
are independent from its decisions to tax. Owing to the institutional
separation between spending allocation and taxation in the United
States, Hoover and Sheffrin (1992) report empirical results for the U.S.
that are consistent with an independent determination of the two sides
of the budget, especially since the 1960s.
Most of the literature, however, suggests that spending and taxes are
interrelated, giving rise to three additional possibilities. Several
economists, led by Milton Friedman (1982), contend that raising taxes
would likely fall to lower budget deficits because they would instead
invite more spending. Because of this positive causal impact of taxes on
spending, Friedman has long proposed tax cuts as a means to reducing
budget deficits. He reasons that the larger budget deficits resulting
from tax reductions should exert mounting pressures on the government to
curtail its spending. Interestingly, like Friedman, Buchanan and Wagner
(1977, 1978) have also suggested that causality runs from taxes to
spending. However, unlike him, Buchanan and Wagner hypothesize a
negative causal relationship. They argue that reducing taxes would lower
the cost of government programs as perceived by the public. Hence,
voters tend to accept or even demand further government programs,
resulting in higher government spending. The tax cut, in conjunction
with the resultant government spending increase, would lead to higher
(not lower) budget deficits. Thus, Buchanan and Wagner advocate,
instead, tax increases which would raise the cost of government spending
as perceived by voters, thus resulting in lower spending. The tax
increase, combined with spending cuts, could drastically curtail budget
deficits.
A third group of economists, most notably Barro (1979) and Peacock and Wiseman (1979), has challenged the above views and argues that
governments spend first and then tax later. They contend that temporary
increases in government spending (perhaps easily justified by natural
crises and/or severe humanitarian needs) tend to become enduring and
lead to permanent tax increases to finance the excessive spending. Under
this causal pattern from spending to taxation, the optimal solution to
controlling the budget deficit is clearly spending cuts. Proposals like
these will become particularly attractive in the absence of the severe
crises that initially justified the spending hikes.
The fourth and final causative link between government spending and
taxation suggests a mutual change. This fiscal synchronization hypothesis of Musgrave (1966) and Meltzer and Richard (1981) contends
that the public simultaneously determine the levels of government
spending and taxation by contrasting the benefits of government services
with their costs. Therefore, these economists maintain that spending and
taxes are determined concurrently.
In summary, there are four alternative hypotheses pertaining to the
causal relationship between government spending and taxation. These are
(i) taxes and spending are causally independent, (ii) taxes cause
spending, (iii) spending causes taxes, and (iv) taxes and spending are
mutually causal. Theoretical debate also exists within hypothesis (ii);
namely, that higher taxes cause higher spending (Friedman's view),
or higher taxes cause lower spending (Buchanan-Wagner view).
As I stated, numerous studies have examined the empirical validity of
the above hypotheses, primarily for the United States, with remarkably
mixed results. For example, Blackley (1986), Manage and Marlow (1986),
Ahiakpor and Amirkhalkhali (1989), and to some extent Ram (1988) have
reported results showing that taxes cause spending.(3) On the other
hand, results consistent with the opposite view that spending causes
taxes have emerged from many other studies including Anderson, Wallace,
and Warner (1986) and von Furstenberg, Green, and Jeong (1986). Still,
researchers like Joulfain and Mookerjee (1990), Miller and Russek
(1990), and Owoye (1995) have found a bidirectional causality between
government spending and taxation.
It is important to observe that these apparently contradictory
studies have used a variety of empirical procedures that are capable of
yielding different and conflicting results. Equally important is the
fact that the majority of these empirical procedures are deficient and
are known to yield biased inferences. For instance, Manage and Marlow
(1986) and Joulfain and Mookerjee (1990) employ bivariate Granger
causality models; yet, it is widely recognized that such models are
suspect due to the omission-of-variables bias discussed in Lutkepohl
(1982, 1993), among others. If a variable is found not to cause another
variable in a bivariate setting, this does not necessarily imply that
such an inference holds in the context of a larger economic system which
includes other germane variables. Lutkepohl (1982, p. 367) writes,
"this conclusion is a consequence of the well-known problem that a
low dimensional subprocess contains little information about the
structure of a higher dimensional system." In order to avoid these
potential biases, Anderson, Wallace, and Warner (1986), von Furstenberg,
Green, and Jeong (1986), and Ahiakpor and Amirkhalkhali (1989) have
incorporated other relevant variables and examined multivariate Granger
causality models.
However, another source of inadequacy in such standard Granger
causality tests is their neglect of other sources of causality stemming
from the underlying equilibrium (long-run) relationships among the
variables. Such cointegration relationships are taken into account by
Miller and Russek (1990) and Owoye (1995). Unfortunately, their error
correction causal models are bivariate in nature, ignoring other
relevant variables that may influence government spending and/or taxes.
Recent literature (Miller 1991; Darrat 1994; Darrat and Arize 1996) has
shown that the problem of omission-of-variables bias is not unique with
standard Granger causality tests, but it also distorts inferences from
cointegration and error correction models.
In summary, a better way to discriminate among the alternative causal
hypotheses linking government spending and taxation is to use
multivariate error correction models. I perform this task below for
Turkey.
3. Methodology and Data Used
I test for Granger causality between government spending (G) and
taxes (T) in the context of the Turkish economy. For examining the
direction of causality between any two variables, the Granger test has
gained a lot of popularity, partly due to its simplicity. This testing
procedure further saves degrees of freedom which, in relatively small
samples, is an important advantage. Briefly, a stationary time series {[Z.sub.t]} is said to Granger-cause(4) another stationary time series
{[V.sub.t]} if the prediction error from regressing V on Z significantly
declines by using past values of Z in addition to using past values of
V.
Granger-causality tests require stationary variables (e.g., whose
stochastic properties are time invariant). Granger (1986) demonstrates
that a nonstationary time series (Y) can achieve stationarity if
differenced appropriately. To determine the proper order of differencing
for any variable, I use three alternative testing procedures. They are
the augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF), Phillips-Perron (PP), and weighted
symmetric (WS) tests. Although the ADF procedure is perhaps the most
common test, it requires that the errors in the testing equation be
homoscedastic and serially uncorrelated. The PP test generalizes the ADF
procedure allowing for less restrictive assumptions regarding the error
terms. Finally, Pantula, Gonzales-Farias, and Fuller (1994) report
extensive Monte Carlo evidence supporting the empirical power of the WS
test against several alternative unit root testing procedures.
To avoid the omission-of-variables bias, I incorporate two additional
variables that theory suggests as potentially relevant for the
determination of G and/or T; namely, real GNP and interest rates.(5)
Both fiscal variables are potentially sensitive to changes in the level
of economic activity as measured by real GNP. Such automatic stabilizing
effects of business cycles are usually removed by using cyclically
adjusted or full-employment data on government spending and taxes. Since
these data are usually unavailable (except for the U.S.), it is
important to include real GNP in the testing equations for Turkey to
prevent contaminating the data with nonpolicy (business cycles)
effects.(6) On the other hand, interest rates are often considered a key
controlling variable in any macroeconomic model (see Sims 1980; Fackler
1985). Moreover, government spending is particularly sensitive to
changes in interest rates, because a significant portion of government
outlays is related to interest payments on public debt.(7) In light of
the above considerations, it can be argued that important information
would be lost by excluding real GNP and interest rates from the
analysis. To provide some empirical insight into this issue, I report,
in the next section, results from bivariate models followed by the
results from multivariate extensions.
In a multivariate context, Granger causality running from, say, taxes
(T) to spending (G) can be tested by estimating:
[G.sub.t] = [[Psi].sub.0] + [summation of] [[Psi].sub.1i][G.sub.t-i]
where i = 1 to [n.sub.1] + [summation of] [[Psi].sub.2i][T.sub.t-i]
where i = 1 to [n.sub.2] + [summation of] [[Psi].sub.3i][X.sub.t-i]
where i = 1 to [n.sub.3] + [summation of] [[Psi].sub.4i][R.sub.t-i]
where i = 1 to [n.sub.4] + [[Mu].sub.t] (1)
where X is real GNP, R is the interest rate on three-month T-bills,
[Mu] is a white-noise error term, and the summations of [Psi]'s are
polynomials of appropriate orders ([n.sub.1], [n.sub.2], [n.sub.3],
[n.sub.4]) for the four explanatory variables. I use the Akaike's
final prediction error (FPE) criterion to determine the proper lags for
each variable within a maximum lag of three years for each variable.(8)
A longer lag profile could seriously deplete degrees of freedom,
particularly damaging in small samples. The null hypothesis that T does
not Granger-cause G is rejected if the summation of [[Psi].sub.2i] is
significant as a group. To test for the reverse hypothesis that G does
not Granger-cause T, I estimate as in Equation 1, except I use T as the
left-side variable.
[T.sub.t] = [[Phi].sub.0] + [summation of] [[Phi].sub.1j][T.sub.t-j]
where j = 1 to [m.sub.1] + [summation of] [[Psi].sub.2j] [G.sub.t-j]
where j = 1 to [m.sub.2] + [summation of] [[Psi].sub.3j][X.sub.t-j]
where j = 1 to [m.sub.3] + [summation of] [[Phi].sub.4j][R.sub.t-j]
where j = 1 to [m.sub.4] + [[Xi].sub.t] (2)
That is, the hypothesis that G does not Granger-cause T is rejected
if the summation [[Phi].sub.2j] is significant as a group.
Observe that the above standard Granger causality tests between G and
T are valid only if the variables are not cointegrated.(9) Otherwise, as
Hendry (1986) and Engle and Granger (1987), among others, have
demonstrated, inferences from such tests will be biased because they
overlook valuable long-run (low-frequency) information. Therefore, it is
important to examine the cointegrating properties of the variables
before testing for Granger causality. To that end, I use two alternative
testing methodologies.
Perhaps the most popular and simple procedure to test for
cointegration is the two-step approach suggested by Engle and Granger
(1987), hereafter EG. Suppose that the four variables are integrated of
order one. The first step is to estimate the underlying cointegrating
equations using the variables in their nonstationary (level) form. With
three or more variables, the choice of the left-side conditioning
variable is arbitrary (Banerjee et al. 1993). I follow Miller (1991) and
examine all possible cointegrating regressions and choose that which
yields the highest adjusted [R.sup.2]. In the second step of the EG
procedure, the estimated residuals from the optimal cointegrating
equation are recovered and checked for nonstationarity using the ADF
test. To provide further evidence, I also use the PP and the WS tests,
in addition to the Cointegration Regression Durbin-Watson (CRDW) test
recommended by EG. If the null hypothesis of residual nonstationarity
(noncointegratedness) is rejected, then the variables are said to be
cointegrated. Engle and Yoo (1987) provide the critical values for the
cointegration test for finite sample sizes, and Davidson and MacKinnon
(1993) calculate the corresponding asymptotic values.
However, recent literature (e.g., Kramers, Ericson, and Dolado 1992;
Inder 1993) has shown that the EG test suffers from poor finite sample
properties that may result in large estimation biases. In addition, even
moderate departures from the presumed Gaussian errors (especially in
regard to normality) can significantly impair the reliability of the
inferences, as pointed out by Davidson and MacKinnon (1993) and
Noriega-Muro (1993). Moreover, the EG procedure is essentially limited
to testing for a single (unique) cointegrating vector, which is proper
only in bivariate models. With three or more variables, the model could
exhibit multiple cointegrating vectors, in which case the EG test will
not be useful.
Compared to the EG test, Johansen (1988) provides a better and more
efficient approach to test for cointegration based on the well-accepted
likelihood ratio principle. Although most of the advantages of the
Johansen test are realized in multivariate models, Enders (1995)
presents arguments favoring the Johansen approach over the EG test even
in bivariate models. Moreover, Cheung and Lai (1993), Gonzalo (1994),
and Johansen (1995) have all demonstrated that, unlike the EG test, the
Johansen method has the additional advantage of not requiring Gaussian
errors. Although I use both the EG and the Johansen methods to test for
cointegration, I place more emphasis on the results from the Johansen
robust test.
If the variables are found to be cointegrated, then they possess a
long-run (equilibrium) relationship. Such a long-run (low-frequency)
relationship would be filtered out if the variables are expressed in
first-differences as the stationarity requirement dictates, but without
due consideration to the underlying long-run comovements among the
variables. Thus, to satisfy the stationarity requirement and, at the
same time, avoid the loss of low-frequency information, I follow
Granger's (1986) Representation Theorem and construct an error
correction model (ECM) to analyze the underlying causal relationships
among the variables. In the ECM, all variables are expressed in their
stationary form, but a once-lagged error correction term is added as
another regressor.(10) This error correction term is the stationary
residuals estimated from the associated cointegrating equation. Granger
discusses some interesting causality implications from error correction
models. An independent variable is said to Granger-cause the dependent
variable if the lagged coefficients on the independent variable are
jointly significant (the standard Granger causality test) and/or the
coefficient on the once-lagged error correction term is significant.
Moreover, the former can be interpreted as short-run Granger causality,
whereas the latter reflects long-ran Granger causality.(11)
I apply the above empirical procedure to detect the direction of
Granger causality between government spending and taxes in Turkey in the
context of bivariate as well as multivariate models that include real
GNP and interest rates. The estimation period covers the annual period
1967-1994, the maximum amount of data available from the IMF data tape,
International Financial Statistics. The unavailability of quarterly data
dictated the use of annual figures. This period of three decades appears
sufficiently long to gauge the cointegrating properties of the system.
It is also not too long to contaminate the analysis with quite different
episodes of fiscal policy regimes that might introduce structural
shifts.
For the purpose at hand, the proper budgetary measures are those
commonly discussed by the public and popular press; namely, total
government expenditures and total government revenues from taxation.
Given the extremely high rates of inflation in Turkey during most of the
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 1 OMITTED] estimation period, I express the
figures on total government expenditures and total revenues in real
terms. Many previous studies in this area have also used real values of
the budgetary measures to abstract from the inflationary effects.
Business cycles are measured by real GNP (X), and interest rates (R) are
measured by the annualized yield on three-month government securities.
4. Empirical Results
I now discuss the empirical results obtained for Turkey from applying
the methodology described in the previous section.
Unit Root and Cointegration Test Results
A key step in testing for cointegration is to determine the degree of
integration of each of the four variables using the ADF, PP, and WS
procedures. I assemble the unit root test results in Table 1. It is
clear from the table that the log-level of each variable is
nonstationary. However, according to all three tests, the variables are
stationary when expressed in first-differences (of the logs). Thus, each
variable is integrated of the first order. Following Dickey, Bell, and
Miller [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 2 OMITTED] [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 3
OMITTED] (1986), I do not include a deterministic time trend in the unit
root testing equations. Nevertheless, similar inferences emerge when the
trend is included.
Next, I check whether the variables are indeed cointegrated. Table 2
reports the results from the EG test in two separate panels. Panel A
contains the results for the simple bivariate model (G and T only), and
panel B constitutes the results for the multivariate model (G, T, X, and
R). The EG test results for both bivariate and multivariate systems
suggest the presence of significant cointegration among the variables.
However, in light of the well-known problems with the EG test
discussed earlier, I now turn attention to Table 3, where I report the
results from the Johansen test. The evidence there for the bivariate
model (panel A) clearly indicates no cointegration between government
spending and taxes on the basis of both the maximal eigenvalue and the
trace tests, even at the relatively weak 10% level of significance. In
contrast, the Johansen test results in panel B for the multivariate
(four-variable) system soundly reject the null hypothesis of no
cointegration at better than the 5% level. Moreover, both the maximal
eigenvalue and the trace tests imply that there is one nonzero cointegrating vector in the multivariate model which is reported in
panel B after being normalized on G.(12) Consequently, there exists a
stationary long-run relationship in Turkey between government spending,
taxes, real GNP, and interest rates.(13)
Further Tests of the Cointegrating Relationship
I have performed additional tests to check whether I have been misled by the above statistics. In particular, how robust are the Johansen
results to different lag specifications? Cheung and Lai (1993) and
Gonzalo (1994) demonstrate through extensive Monte Carlo experiments
that overparameterized (longer lagged) tests exhibit higher empirical
power than those that are underparameterized (with shorter lags). In
congruence with this evidence, the results in Table 3 are based on VARs
with three annual lags, a lag length that is sufficiently long given the
relative brevity of the sample. Nonetheless, to further check the
sensitivity of the Johansen results to this issue of lag lengths, I
performed the Johansen approach using shorter lags (one and two) as well
as a longer lag (four). It is encouraging that the results (available
upon request) are very similar to those reported in the table on the
basis of three lags.
Note that the Johansen test reported in Table 3 suggests the presence
of cointegration in multivariate but not in bivariate models. What
rationale can be provided for this finding? A possible explanation may
lie in omitting relevant variables from the bivariate model (in this
case, real GNP and/or interest rates). As I mentioned earlier, Lutkepohl
(1982, 1993) has shown that noncausality inferences drawn from bivariate
models are often misleading due to the omission of relevant variables
that affect either or both of the two included variables. Interestingly,
Granger (1988) and Perman (1991) theorize that this
omission-of-variables phenomenon is not unique with causality testing
but also extends to hamper cointegration inferences. Such a theoretical
contention finds empirical support in Marin (1991), Miller (1991),
Darrat (1994), and Choudhry (1996). The results in this paper provide
yet another piece of evidence confirming the sensitivity of
cointegration tests to the omission-of-variables phenomenon.
Observe also that across the two testing methodologies, the results
for the bivariate model are remarkably different. Whereas the EG test
finds cointegration, the Johansen test detects none. In light of the
fragility of the EG procedure, it is of course reasonable to dismiss its
conclusion. And more specifically, the residual regression in the
bivariate model is plagued with severe nonnormality, rendering the EG
results unreliable (the Jarque-Bera [[Chi].sup.2] = 13.16; the 5%
critical value = 5.99).(14)
In addition to testing for the presence of cointegration, Table 3, at
the bottom of panel B also reports the results from testing various
hypotheses regarding the cointegrating relationship among the four
variables. In particular, the first column tests and rejects the null
hypothesis that the individual series within the nonzero cointegrating
vector are stationary by themselves. The test statistics in the second
column checks whether any variable within the four-variable system does
not belong in the cointegration space and thus can be excluded. The
results from this exclusion test suggest that only real GNP appears
redundant and can be safely omitted from the cointegration relationship.
However, interest rates cannot be excluded because the test displays a
highly significant long-run statistic. Accordingly, a more parsimonious system, which I examine below, would be to estimate a trivariate model
that contains government spending, taxes, and interest rates. Finally,
panel B also provides results of testing whether any variable in the
four-variable system can be considered weakly exogenous. Except for
government spending, each of the remaining three variables appears
weakly exogenous. This implies that, among the four variables, only
government spending should be considered endogenous.(15) Moreover, as
Hams (1995) noted, these results also suggest that omitting the error
correction term from the ECM of government spending equation would
entail significant loss of pertinent information. The same, however,
cannot be said regarding the error correction term in the tax equation
because its role in the corresponding ECM equation appears trivial.
Considering the exclusion test results discussed above, I report in
Panel C of Table 3 the cointegration results from the parsimonious
trivariate system (G, T, R) after excluding real GNP. Both the maximal
eigenvalue and the trace tests of the Johansen approach continue to
indicate the presence of one nonzero cointegration vector in the
parsimonious system. Consistent with the findings from the four-variable
model, the results in the trivariate system strongly suggest the need to
keep all three variables in the cointegrating space (exclusion tests)
and that only government spending can be considered an endogenous
variable within the system.
Granger Causality Test Results
I turn now to discussing Granger causality tests in light of the
above cointegration findings. In Table 4, panels A and B, I report the
Granger causality results from the bivariate and multivariate systems,
alternatively using taxes and government spending as dependent
variables.(16) For the multivariate system with a significant
cointegrating vector, I specify an error correction [TABULAR DATA FOR
TABLE 4 OMITTED] representation to analyze Granger causality.(17)
However, in the context of the bivariate model, no cointegration was
found and the standard Granger causality tests should be sufficient for
that purpose.
As was the case for cointegration, the causality results from the
bivariate and multivariate models are also strikingly different. Within
the bivariate model, I could not reject the null hypothesis of no
Granger causality running from government spending to taxes or vice
versa (i.e., the two variables are deemed causally independent). This
inference of no causality refers both to the short-run (as represented
by the insignificant coefficients on lagged differences of the
independent variable), as well as to the long-run (since no
cointegration was revealed). However, as I discussed earlier,
noncausality and noncointegration inferences drawn in a bivariate
setting are suspect due to the omission-of-variables bias.
Therefore, attention should be focused instead on the Granger
causality results from the multivariate system, which I report in panel
B of Table 4. The results there quite decisively suggest that Granger
causality does exist between government spending and taxes in Turkey.
Moreover, the pattern of causality is consistent with the tax-and-spend
hypothesis rather than with the spend-and-tax thesis. More specifically,
based on the statistical significance of the error correction terms, the
null hypothesis of no Granger causality running from taxes to government
spending is soundly rejected at better than the 1% level of significance
([[Chi].sup.2] = 7.49, the 1% critical value = 6.63). However, the
reverse hypothesis of no Granger causality from spending to taxes
through the error term channel could not be rejected at any conventional
level as indicated by the statistical insignificance of the associated
error correction term ([[Chi].sup.2] = 2.03).
Besides these long-run unidirectional Granger-causal impacts, the
multivariate results in panel B also suggest the presence of significant
short-run unidirectional causal effects from taxes to government
spending. Specifically, according to the likelihood ratio tests of the
joint significance of lagged dynamic terms, the null hypothesis that
taxes do not Granger-cause government spending is easily rejected
([[Chi].sup.2] = 9.20, the 5% critical value [[Chi].sup.2] = 7.81),
while the reverse hypothesis is not rejected ([[Chi].sup.2] = 3.65).
These results, taken together, suggest that taxes exert significant
unidirectional causal effects upon government spending in Turkey in both
the short-run as well as in the long-run.(18) The inferences from the
multivariate ECMs of Table 4 are consistent with the earlier finding
from the weak-exogeneity tests of the cointegration relationship
reported in Table 3.
Before proceeding any further, it seems advisable to check the
sensitivity of these causality results to alternative model
specifications. For example, to what extent are the results sensitive to
using different lag specifications? The results in Table 4 are based on
three lags that were deemed appropriate by the FPE criterion (and were
also confirmed by the asymptotically equivalent procedure, Akaike
Information Criterion). However, imposing shorter or longer lags yielded
very similar results (available upon request). It may also be important
to check whether the results are sample specific. This, of course,
requires evidence on the structural stability of the estimated models.
Given the brevity of my sample, I was unable to extensively experiment
with different sample periods, especially in the context of multivariate
models with many parameters. This notwithstanding, I inspected the
sensitivity of my conclusions to sample selection by omitting the period
before the oil price hike of 1973, by using the periods before and after
the 1980 coup, and alternatively, by omitting the years after the
approval of the new Turkish Constitution of 1982. The results (available
upon request) continued to reveal inferences very similar to those
reported in Table 4. As a further check, I applied the Chow and the
custom-of squares tests of structural stability. The results (available
upon request) corroborated parameter constancy in the estimated models.
Note also that, as Fischer (1989) and Lutkepohl (1989) point out,
reliable policy inferences from causality tests hinge crucially on their
invariance to policy regime changes. Recently, Engle and Hendry (1993)
demonstrate that this invariance proposition is closely associated with
the concept of superexogeneity. I use the methodology proposed by them
and test for superexogeneity of the relevant variables. In so doing, the
auxiliary equations include a dummy variable for the purpose of testing
the superexogeneity hypotheses for spending and taxes in the bivariate
and multivariate models. This dummy variable takes the value of one for
the post-1980 period, and zero otherwise. Compared to all other
political turbulence in modern Turkey, the 1980 coup is perhaps the
worst in terms of its relative lack of tolerance of civil liberties and
partisan politics (Hooglund 1996). Indeed, if the estimated models prove
invariant to the structural change introduced by the 1980 coup, a case
can be easily made for their stability throughout the sample period. In
the bivariate equations and the multivariate ECMs of Table 4, the
coefficient vectors of the appropriate variables are proven invariant to
the policy regime shift of the 1980s. (The F-values are 0.28 and 0.44
for the two bivariate equations and 0.41 and 0.29 for the two
multivariate ECMs. None of these values is significant at any
conventional level.)(19)
In summary, the empirical results lend strong support to the
contention that taxes have unidirectionally Granger-caused government
spending in Turkey. Moreover, this Granger causality is potent,
occurring both in the short-run and in the long-run. These results,
taken together, are consistent with the tax-and-spend hypothesis of
Friedman and Buchanan-Wagner. What implications for the deficit solution
debate emerge from such results? In other words, should Turkish
authorities cut taxes in order to control budget deficits a la Friedman,
or should they instead raise taxes to accomplish that same goal a la
Buchanan and Wagner? The empirical evidence from the multivariate ECMs
are more in line with the Buchanan and Wagner policy recommendation.
This is because the (short-run) impact of tax changes on government
spending proves negative (-1.86) and statistically significant at better
than the 5% level.
Therefore, consistent with the Buchanan and Wagner view, raising
taxes in Turkey should raise the perceived price of government goods and
services, which in turn exert pressures on the government to reduce its
spending, leading to significant reductions in budget deficits.
5. Concluding Remarks
This paper investigates the causal (lead/lag) relationship between
government spending and taxes for Turkey. In contrast to many previous
studies for the U.S. and other large industrialized countries, my
empirical analysis incorporates the cointegrating properties of the
variables and, moreover, expands the common restrictive bivariate model
to include other theoretically relevant variables. In particular, the
multivariate model includes real GNP and interest rates as macroeconomic
control variables. The bivariate and the multivariate models come to
dramatically different conclusions regarding cointegration and causality
between the two fiscal variables. This finding underscores the need to
continue with efforts to specify and test more complete (broader) models
of the budgetary process. Owing perhaps to the familiar
omission-of-variables bias, I place more emphasis on inferences drawn
from multivariate models.
The results that consistently emerge from the multivariate
cointegration analysis for Turkey support the existence of one nonzero
cointegrating vector representing a long-run equilibrium relationship
between the two fiscal variables. Moreover, evidence from the
multivariate error correction models suggests that taxes
unidirectionally and significantly Granger-cause government spending,
both in the short-run and in the long-run. These results imply rejection
of the spend-and-tax hypothesis in favor of the tax-and-spend
proposition in the case of Turkey. The results further reveal that the
unidirectional causal impact of taxes on spending is significantly
negative, as hypothesized by Buchanan and Wagner. Therefore, from the
perspective of policy making and the deficit solution debate, it appears
that raising taxes in Turkey should prove an optimal solution to the
current budget deficit predicament.
I thank, without implicating, D.C. Anderson, O. W. Gilley, and an
anonymous reviewer for several useful comments and suggestions.
1 I am indebted to an anonymous reviewer for pointing out this and
many other important aspects of the paper.
2 For more on these and other relevant political issues in the
Turkish context, see Hooglund (1996).
3 Observe, however, that none of these studies investigates whether
higher taxes cause higher spending a la Friedman or cause lower spending
a la Buchanan-Wagner.
4 Throughout the paper, I attach "Granger" to
"cause" because controversy still surrounds the Granger
concept of causality, which somewhat differs from the definition of
causality in the strict philosophical sense. Indeed, tests of Granger
causality are essentially tests of the incremental predictive content of
economic time series. See Bishop (1979) and Zellner (1979) for a
fruitful discussion.
5 Of course, the addition of the two variables may not be fully
adequate, and any expanded model runs the risk of omitting other
important variables. Yet, it was felt that these two additional
variables are reasonably grounded in theory and seem sufficient for the
purpose of illustrating the susceptibility of bivariate models to the
omission-of-variables bias.
6 Ahiakpor and Amirkhalkali (1989) have also included GNP in their
models for Canada.
7 McCallum's (1984) work further implies the need to adjust
fiscal variables for interest payments.
8 The FPE is based on the minimization of the one-step-ahead
prediction error. It is a compromise between the predictive power of a
model and its complexity as measured by its lagged order. For further
details on the FPE criterion and its application, see Darrat (1988).
Thornton and Batten (1985) report results showing the superiority of the
FPE criterion over other alternative lag length selection procedures.
9 Cointegrated variables, if disturbed, will not drift away from each
other and thus possess a long-run equilibrium relationship.
10 Additional lags of the error correction term are unnecessary since
they are already reflected in the distributed lags of the
first-differences of the variables. See Miller (1991).
11 Jones and Joulfaian (1991) suggest a similar interpretation.
12 As Dickey, Jansen, and Thornton (1991) and Alogoskonfis and Smith
(1991) pointed out, cointegrating vectors are difficult to interpret
because they do not reflect structural equations. Nonetheless, the
estimated cointegrating vector implies, as it should, that there is a
positive long-run relationship between spending and taxes. I do not
report the remaining three eigenvectors since they are statistically
insignificant (nonstationary).
13 Other studies have also found a long-run relation between
government spending and taxes in the U.S. See, for example, Miller and
Russek (1990), Bohn (1991), and Jones and Joulfaian (1991).
14 Interestingly, the residual regression based on the multivariate
system does not reveal any evidence of nonnormality (the Jarque-Bera
[[Chi].sup.2] = 3.24).
15 In itself, this finding may be taken to imply support for the
tax-and-spend hypothesis. More on this below.
16 Since real GNP and interest rates are likely related to factors
other than the fiscal variables (e.g., monetary policy and international
developments), separate equations for X and R are not reported here.
17 The quadrivariate ECMs (DG, DT, DX, DR) are based on residuals
obtained from the Johansen efficient maximum likelihood estimations
within the parsimonious trivariate system (G, T, R).
18 The results in panel B of Table 4 further indicate that interest
rates (and not real GNP) exert important causal impacts on both fiscal
variables and particularly on tax revenues.
19 I performed the superexogeneity test using alternative dummy
variables. The results, available upon request, do not suggest different
conclusions.
References
Adaman, E, and M. R. Sertel. 1995. The changing economic role of the
state from a Turkish perspective. Economic Research Forum Working Paper
No. 9510.
Ahiakpor, J. W., and S. Amirkhalkhali. 1989. On the difficulty of
eliminating deficits with higher taxes: Some Canadian evidence. Southern
Economic Journal 56:24-31.
Alogoskoufis, G., and R. Smith. 1991. On error-correction models:
specification, interpretation, and estimation. Journal of Economic
Survey 5:97-128.
Anderson, W., M. S. Wallace, and J. T. Warner. 1986. Government
spending and taxation: What causes what? Southern Economic Journal
52:630-39.
Banerjee, A., J. J. Dolado, J. W. Galbraith, and D. F. Hendry. 1993.
Cointegration, error-correction and the econometric analysis of
non-stationary data. London: Oxford University Press.
Barro, R. J. 1979. On the determination of the public debt. Journal
of Political Economy 81:940-71.
Bishop, R. V. 1979. The construction and use of causality tests.
Agricultural Economics Research 31:1-6.
Blackley, P. R. 1986. Causality between revenues and expenditures and
the size of the federal budget. Public Finance Quarterly 14:139-56.
Bohn, H. 1991. Budget balance through revenue or spending
adjustments? Some historical evidence for the United States. Journal of
Monetary Economics 27:333-59.
Buchanan, J. M., and R. W. Wagner. 1977. Democracy in deficit. New
York: Academic Press.
Buchanan, J. M, and R. W. Wagner. 1978. Dialogues concerning fiscal
religion. Journal of Monetary Economics 4:627-36.
Bugra, A. 1994. State and business in modern Turkey. New York: Suny
Publications.
Cheung, Y. W., and K. S. Lai. 1993. Finite sample sizes of
Johansen's likelihood ratio tests for cointegration. Oxford
Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 55:313-28.
Choudhry, T. 1996. Real stock prices and the long-run money demand
function: Evidence from Canada and the USA. Journal of International
Money and Finance 15:1-17.
Darrat, A. E 1988. Have large budget deficits caused raising trade
deficits? Southern Economic Journal 54:879-87.
Darrat, A. E 1994. Wage growth and the inflationary process: A
reexamination. Southern Economic Journal 61:181-90.
Darrat, A. E. and A. Arize. 1996. Budget deficits and the value of
the dollar: Further results from cointegration and error-correction
modeling. Louisiana Tech University, Working Paper.
Davidson, R., and J. G. MacKinnon. 1993. Estimation and inference in
econometrics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Dickey, D. A., W. R. Bell, and R. B. Miller. 1986. Unit roots in time
series models: Tests and implications. The American Statistician
40:12-26.
Dickey, D. A., D. W. Jansen, and D. L. Thornton. 1991. A primer on
cointegration with an application to money and income. Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis Review 73:58-78.
Enders, W. 1995. Applied econometric time series. New York: John
Wiley & Sons.
Engle, R., and D. F. Hendry. 1993. Testing super-exogeneity and
covariance in regression models. Journal of Econometrics 57:119-39.
Engle, R. F. and C. W. J. Granger. 1987. Co-integration and
error-correction representation, estimation, and testing. Econometrica
55:251-76.
Engle, R. F., and S. Yoo. 1987. Forecasting and testing in
cointegrated systems. Journal of Econometrics 35:143-59.
Fackler, J. 1985. An empirical analysis of the markets for goods,
money and credit. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 17:28-42.
Fischer, A.M. 1989. Policy regime changes and monetary expectations:
Testing for superexogeneity. Journal of Monetary Economics 6:423-36.
Friedman, M. 1982. Supply-side policies: Where do we go from here in
supply-side economics in the 1980s: Conference proceedings. Westport,
CT: Quorum Books.
Furstenbert, G. M. von, R. J. Green, and J. Jeong. 1986. Tax and
spend, or spend and tax? Review of Economics and Statistics 68:179-88.
Gonzalo, J. 1994. Five alternative methods of estimating long-run
equilibrium relationships. Journal of Econometrics 60:203-33.
Granger, C. W. J. 1986. Developments in the study of cointegrated
economic variables. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics
48:213-28.
Granger, C. W. J. 1988. Some recent developments in the concept of
causality. Journal of Econometrics 16:199-211.
Harris, R. I. D. 1995. Using cointegration analysis in econometric
modelling. London: Prentice Hall.
Hendry, D. F. 1986. Econometric modelling with cointegrated
variables: An overview. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics
48:201-12.
Hooglund, E. 1996. Government and politics. In Turkey: A country
study. 5th Edition. Washington, DC: Federal Research Division of Library
of Congress, pp. 233-301.
Hoover, K. D., and S. M. Sheffrin. 1992. Causation, spending, and
taxes: Sand in the sandbox or tax collector for the welfare state?
American Economic Review 82: 225-48.
Inder, B. 1983. Estimating long-run relationships in economics: A
comparison of different approaches. Journal of Econometrics 57:53-68.
Johansen, D. 1988. Statistical analysis of cointegration vectors.
Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 12:231-54.
Johansen, D. 1995. Likelihood-based inference in cointegrated vector
autoregressive models. New York: Oxford University Press.
Jones, J. D., and D. Joulfaian. 1991. Federal government expenditures
and revenues in the early years of the American republic: Evidence from
1792 to 1860. Journal of Macroeconomics 14:133-55.
Joulfaian, D., and R. Mookerjee. 1990. The intertemporal relationship
between state and local government revenues and expenditures: Evidence
from OECD countries. Public Finance 45:109-17.
Kramers, J. J. M., N. R. Ericsson, and J. Dolado. 1992. The power of
cointegration tests. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics
54:325-48.
Lee, D. R., and R. K. Vedder. 1992. Friedman tax cuts vs. Buchanan
deficit reduction as the best way of constraining government. Economic
Inquiry 30:722-32.
Lutkepohl, H. 1982. Non-causality due to omitted variables. Journal
of Econometrics 19:367-78.
Lutkepohl, H. 1989. The stability assumption. In Tests of causality
between money and income, edited by W. Kramer. Heidelberg, Germany:
Physica-Verlag, pp. 75-86.
Lutkepohl, H. 1993. Introduction to multiple time series analysis.
2nd edition. Berlin: Springer-Verlag.
McCallum, B. T. 1984. Are bond-financed deficits inflationary? A
Ricardian analysis. Journal of Political Economy 92: 123-35.
Manage, N., and M. L. Marlow. 1986. The causal relation between
federal expenditures and receipts. Southern Economic Journal 52:617-29.
Marin, D. 1992. Is the export-led growth hypothesis valid for
industrialized countries? Review of Economics and Statistics 74:678-88.
Meltzer, A. H., and S. E Richard. 1981. A rational theory of the size
of government. Journal of Political Economy 89: 914-27.
Miller, S. M. 1991. Monetary dynamics: An application of
cointegration and error-correction modelling. Journal of Money, Credit
and Banking 23:139-54.
Miller, S. M., and F. S. Russek. 1990. Co-integration and
error-correction models: The temporal causality between government taxes
and spending. Southern Economic Journal 57:221-29.
Musgrave, R. 1966. Principles of budget determination. In Public
Finance: Selected readings, edited by H. Cameron and W. Henderson. New
York: Random House, pp. 15-27.
Noriega-Muro, A. E. 1993. Nonstationarity and structural breaks in
economic time series. New York: Avebury Publishers.
Owoye, O. 1995. The causal relationship between taxes and
expenditures in the g-7 countries: Cointegration and error-correction
models. Applied Economics Letters 2:19-22.
Pantula, S. G., G. Gonzales-Farias, and W. A. Fuller. 1994. A
comparison of unit-root test criteria. Journal of Business and Economic
Statistics 12:449-59.
Peacock, A. T, and J. Wiseman. 1979. Approaches to the analysis of
government expenditure growth. Public Finance Quarterly 7:3-23.
Perman, R. 1991. Cointegration: An introduction to the literature.
Journal of Economic Studies 18:3-30.
Pope, K. 1996. Turkey's in turmoil - And the bulls cheer. Wall
Street Journal June 26:11.
Ram, R. 1988. Additional evidence on causality between government
revenue and government expenditure. Southern Economic Journal 54:763-69.
Sims, C. A. 1980. Macroeconomics and reality. Econometrica 48:1-48.
Thornton, D. L., and D. S. Batten. 1985. Lag-length selection and
tests of granger-causality between money and income. Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking 17:164-78.
Wildavsky, A. 1988. The new politics of the budgetary process.
Glenview, IL: Scott Foresman.
Zellner, A. 1979. Causality and econometrics. In Three aspects of
policy and policy-making: Knowledge, data and institutions, edited by K.
Brunner and A. H. Meltzer. Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Company,
pp. 9-54.