Efficiency wages, partial wage rigidity, and money nonneutrality.
Lai, Ching-Chong
1. Introduction
Since the 1970s, the persistently high unemployment rates in many
industrial economies have made more and more economists believe that
involuntary unemployment is one of the major stylized facts of modern
economies. Therefore, a satisfactory macroeconomic labor model should
explain well such a stylized fact. The efficiency wage theory has in
recent years generally been regarded as a powerful vehicle for
explaining why involuntary unemployment has persisted in the labor
market. In constructing a business cycle model, "a potential
problem of the efficiency-wage hypothesis is the absence of a link
between aggregate demand and economic activity" (Yellen 1984, p.
204). Hence, until Akerlof and Yellen (1985) presented the near-rational
model, efficiency wage theories still left unanswered the question of
how changes in the money supply can affect real output.(1) By utilizing
the idea of partially rigid wages, this paper interprets why changes in
money supply and other demand management policies can cause changes in
aggregate employment and output.
In macroeconomic theory, the wage is simply regarded as the amount of
money that employees receive and is assumed to be exactly equal to the
average cost of labor to employers.(2) In practice, the components of
wages are more complicated than the simple economic setting would
suggest. There exist some gaps between the amounts that trading partners
pay and receive. For example, the actual average cost of labor to
employers is equal to the wage that employees receive after the addition
of hiring and training costs, firing (severance pay) and retirement
(pension) costs, various taxes and insurance fees, sometimes traffic and
housing outlays, and so on. Some of these costs, especially taxes,
insurance, and traffic fees, are set by the process of political
negotiations. The resetting processes relating to these costs are always
time-consuming and controversial in modern democratic societies, and
these costs are not as flexible as other components of wages determined
by competitive markets or monopsonists. Since some components of wages
are always inflexible, partial rigidity of wages is thus a realistic
specification for economic modeling. When we recognize that wages have
the property of partial rigidity, it is logical to expect that money
nonneutrality will hence result.
The basic tenet of the efficiency wage theory is that the effort or
productivity of a worker is positively related to his real wage and
firms have the market power to set the wage. Therefore, in order to
maintain high productivity, it may be profitable for firms not to lower
their wages in the presence of involuntary unemployment. The main
reasons that are provided for the positive relationship between worker
productivity and wage levels include nutritional concerns (Leibenstein
1957), morale effects (Akerlof 1982), adverse selection (Weiss 1980),
and the shirking problem (Shapiro and Stiglitz 1984).(3) The shirking
viewpoint proposed by Shapiro and Stiglitz (1984) is the most popular
version of the theory.(4) Its essential feature is that firms cannot
precisely observe the efforts of workers due to incomplete information
and costly monitoring; equilibrium unemployment is therefore necessary
as a worker discipline device. We thus adopt a shirking model as the
analytical framework of this paper to examine the effects of partial
rigidity of wages.
The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 derives the
effort function of a representative worker. Section 3 examines a typical
firm's labor demand and wage-setting behavior. Section 4 studies
the labor market equilibrium. Finally, some concluding remarks are
presented in section 5.
2. The Worker's Optimization Problem
Our analysis starts by considering a simple economy where each of
many identical firms hires a number of ex ante homogeneous workers to
perform some task.(5) The worker enjoys on-the-job leisure and dislikes
working hard. Owing to team production or some unobservable
disturbances, the firm cannot determine the actual effort of an
individual worker. Thus, it is impossible to reward individual workers
according to their particular productivity, suggesting that there would
be a probabilistic penalty to induce work effort. Such a probabilistic
penalty in the shirking model is typically represented by the threat of
firing. Employers will therefore monitor the performance of employees
and lay off workers who are found not to be working hard.
The worker's probability of being fired [Rho] is assumed to be
negatively related to his work effort e. For simplicity, [Rho] is
specified as
[Rho] = 1 - e; 0 [less than or equal to] e [less than or equal to] 1.
(1)
Effort e is assumed to be the fraction of the standard paid-for hours
that the worker actually works, while the number of standard hours is
assumed to be fixed and normalized to unity.
When a worker is fired, he will try to find another job. The
probability of finding another job is assumed to be the employment rate
(1 - u). The unemployment rate u here is defined to be the ratio of the
number of unemployed to the total number of workers.
Following the static analytical framework of Pisauro (1991), there
are three states of nature that an employed worker may face. First, he
is not fired and receives a real wage [w.sub.i] with the probability of
(1 - [Rho]). Second, he is dismissed but finds another job at a real
wage w; the associated probability is [Rho](1 - u). Third, he is fired
and cannot find another job; hence, he becomes unemployed (and enjoys
all-day leisure, e = 0) and receives unemployment benefits b from the
government. The probability in this case is [Rho]u. Moreover, firms are
assumed to be identical and to pay the same real wage (w = [w.sub.i]).
The three states are thus reduced to two.(6) Accordingly, the expected
income of an employed worker, namely [y.sup.e], is
[y.sup.e] = (1 - [Rho]u)w + [Rho]ub. (2)
The worker enjoys consumption of goods by spending income y and
dislikes putting forth any effort e. For ease of analysis, his utility
is specified as
U(y, e) = v(y) - e; v[prime] [greater than] 0, v [double prime] [less
than] 0, v(0) = 0.(7) (3)
From Equations 1, 2, and 3, the expected utility of a typical worker
E[U(y, e)] is
V [equivalent to] E[U (y, e)] = [1 - (1 - e)u][v(w) - e] + (1 -
e)uv(b). (4)
Since unemployment benefits are not the focus of this paper, in what
follows, we will set b = 0.
A utility-maximizing worker will choose his effort level at which the
expected marginal gain from effort equals the expected marginal cost of
effort. Taking the first differentials of Equation 4 with respect to e,
we have the first-order condition as
[V.sub.e] = u[v(w) - e] - [1 - (1 - e)u] = 0. (5)
The second-order condition for an interior maximum is satisfied
because [V.sub.ee] = -2u [less than] 0.
The effort function can be solved from Equation 5 as
e = e(w, u) = 1/2 [v(w) - 1/u + 1], (6)
with
[e.sub.w] = v[prime](w)/2 [greater than] 0, [e.sub.u] = 1/2[u.sup.2]
[greater than] 0, [e.sub.ww] = v[double prime](w)/2 [less than] 0, and
[e.sub.wu] = 0.
Intuitively, the result of [e.sub.w] [greater than] 0 indicates that
an increase in the employed worker's real income w raises his
expected cost of being fired. The worker will thus provide a greater
effort level to prevent his being dismissed. The positive relationship
between a worker's effort and the real wage is the basic tenet of
efficiency wage theories.
The outcome of [e.sub.u] [greater than] 0 states that, when the
unemployment rate rises, it becomes more difficult for the employed to
find an alternative job if dismissed so that the worker will exert more
effort. This result confirms the Shapiro and Stiglitz (1984)
contribution that unemployment is a worker discipline device. In
addition, the results of [e.sub.ww] [less than] 0 and [e.sub.wu] = 0 are
relevant for the discussions that follow.
When there is no unemployment (u = 0), from Equation 5 it can be seen
that [V.sub.e] = -1. This result means that full employment is
inconsistent with any positive effort level. This outcome is similar to
that of the no-shirking condition reported by Shapiro and Stiglitz
(1984). Clearly, for a lay-off to be perceived as a real penalty, it
must be the case that the probability of a fired worker finding a new
job is smaller than one, which implies that the labor market equilibrium
in this model must be characterized by unemployment.
3. The Firm's Optimization Problem
Let us assume there are many identical firms with the same production
technology f(en), which has the usual properties of a standard
production function with f[prime] [greater than] 0 amd f[double prime]
[less than] 0. In this production function, n is the number of workers
and en represents the actual working hours or the effective labor force
of the firm. The output of the firm is also affected by an unobservable
disturbance [Mathematical Expression Omitted], which is a random
variable with a probability density function q([Epsilon]) and an
expected value equal unity, E([Epsilon]) = 1. The unobservable
disturbance presumption indicates that the firm cannot determine the
actual effort level of an individual worker.
Given the effort function in Equation 6, the expected profits
[[Pi].sup.e] of a risk-neutral firm are
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], (7)
where p is the price of the good, t is the lump-sum or the specific
tax per worker, and the term W (W = pw) is the nominal wage that the
firm pays. As is typically the case in efficiency wage models, the wage
affects the labor quality. Furthermore, it is the effective labor units
en that enter the production function instead of the crude number of
employed workers n.
As mentioned in section 1, there exist some gaps between the wage
that the employer pays and the wage bill that the employees actually
receive. The imposition of the lump-sum tax is an example of inserting a
tax wedge (t) between the cost to the firm (W + t) and the wage of the
worker (W). Here we specify, for simplicity, that the nominal value of
the lump-sum tax is fixed. This indicates that the government does not
adjust its taxation even if the economy experiences a change in the
price level.(8)
The firm's goal is to maximize Equation 7 by choosing its
employment and wage. Since there are many small firms in the economy,
each firm makes its employment decision based on the belief that it
cannot influence the unemployment rate. The first-order conditions with
respect to n and W are
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], (8)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. (9)
Equation 8 states that, given the quality of labor, the quantity of
labor employed is that where the marginal revenue from labor
(pef[prime]) equals the marginal cost of labor (W + t). Equation 9
explains that, given the quantity of labor, the quality of labor hired
is that where the marginal revenue of wage ([e.sub.w]nf[prime]) equals
the marginal cost of wage (n). The unobservable disturbance has no
impact on the risk-neutral firm's optimal decisions. The
second-order conditions are fulfilled due to [e.sup.2]f[double prime]
[less than] 0 and [e.sup.2][e.sub.ww]nf[prime]f[double prime] [greater
than] 0.
Before proceeding, it should be noted that, when there is no taxation
(t = 0) as with the standard efficiency wage model of Yellen (1984),
from Equations 8 and 9, we can obtain
w [e.sub.w]/e = 1. (10)
This result indicates that a profit-maximizing firm will set its wage
at the level at which the effort-wage elasticity is unity. This result
is dubbed the Solow condition by Akerlof and Yellen (1986).
However, in their review of efficiency wage models, Akerlof and
Yellen (1986) argue that an effort-wage elasticity of unity is too high
and propose a simple model with external costs to illustrate an
effort-wage elasticity lower than unity. When the lump-sum tax is
imposed, the effort-wage elasticity is less than one; that is,
w[e.sub.w]/e = W/W + t [less than] 1. (11)
This result has been reported in Schmidt-Sorensen (1990) and Pisauro
(1991).
The firm's labor demand and wage-setting functions can be solved
from Equations 8 and 9 as(9)
n = n(u, p), (12)
W = W(u, p), (13)
with
[n.sub.u] = [e.sub.u]/[e.sup.2][e.sub.ww]f[double prime]
[[e.sub.ww](f[prime] + enf[double prime]) + [([e.sub.w]).sup.2]nf[double
prime]] [greater than] 0,(10) (12a)
[n.sub.p] = - 1 - w[e.sub.w]/e/pe[e.sub.ww]f[double prime]
[[e.sub.ww]f[prime] + [([e.sub.w]).sup.2]nf[double prime]] [greater
than] 0, (12b)
[W.sub.u] = [e.sub.u][e.sub.w]/e[e.sub.ww] [less than] 0, (13a)
[W.sub.p] = W/p + [e.sub.w](1 - w[e.sub.w]/e)/[e.sub.ww] [less than]
W/p. (13b)
Intuitively, an increase in the unemployment rate raises the quality
of workers ([e.sub.u] [greater than] 0) and motivates the firm to hire
more workers and pay lower wages ([n.sub.u] [greater than] 0, [W.sub.u]
[less than] 0), as shown in Equations 12a and 13a. It is worth noting
from the wage-setting function in Equation 13 that, given the
unemployment rate of the economy and the price level, the firm will set
a corresponding optimal wage for its employees. This outcome explains
why the wage does not continuously fall to eliminate the excess supply
of labor in the presence of involuntary unemployment.
Moreover, when the lump-sum tax is absent, as in the specification
for the standard efficiency wage model, the Solow condition holds and
the results of [n.sub.p] and [W.sub.p] in Equations 12b and 13b become
[n.sub.p] = 0 and [W.sub.p] = W/p. These results show that the
firm's nominal wage increases proportionately with an increase in
the price level, whereas its employment remains intact. Consequently,
both real variables, namely, the real wage and employment, are invariant to changes in the nominal variable, i.e., the price, and hence money is
neutral. This result is the same as in the case of the standard
efficiency wage model in Yellen (1984). In fact, from the Solow
condition in Equation 10, we can see that the level of the real wage is
solely determined by the effort function. Since the worker's
utility and the firm's profits are dependent only on real rather
than nominal variables,(11) any variation in price is supposed to be
neutralized by the firm's nominal wage policy, resulting in no
impact on real variables. This is the fundamental reason why "[a]ny
efficiency wage model based on pure maximization must, of necessity, be
a real model" (Akerlof and Yellen 1986, pp. 18-19).
When the nonindexation lump-sum tax is imposed, the effort-wage
elasticity is less than unity, The results in Equations 12b and 13b thus
become [n.sub.p] [greater than] 0 and [W.sub.p] [less than] W/p. In
other words, nominal wages increase less than proportionally as the
price level increases and the firm's employment increases. As a
consequence, money is not neutral (a price shock has a positive effect
on the firm's employment decision). Intuitively, even though the
firm has an incentive to neutralize the impacts of price changes by
adjusting its nominal wage proportionally, a rise in the price level
still lowers the real average labor cost of the firm (W + t)/p by way of
lowering the real lump-sum tax burden tip due to the fixed nominal tax
t. The lower labor cost alters the perceived employment-wage tradeoff
faced by firms and thus motivates the firm to provide more jobs at a
lower real wage.(12) Consequently, money is not neutral because of the
rigidity of the cost of labor tax. As the lump-sum tax is a part of the
firm's total labor cost, we can thus conclude that the partial
rigidity of wages will result in money nonneutrality.
4. The Labor Market Equilibrium
Suppose that the number of identical firms is m so that the market
labor demand function is
[N.sup.d] = mn(u, p). (14)
Owing to firms having market power to determine their employment and
wages, the market labor demand is not a function of wages. In other
words, the labor market equilibrium is prominently determined by the
demand-side rather than by the Walrasian Auctioneer in this shirking
model.
Under the assumption that all workers are homogeneous, we must
exclude the situation in which the expected utility of a worker who
participates in the labor market is less than the utility of an
individual who does not.(13) This implies that every worker is willing
to look for a job. However, not all workers can be hired when there is
less than full employment. Hence, given the number of total workers, the
higher the unemployment rate is the fewer the workers who are employed.
Let N be the total number of workers and [N.sup.s] the number of workers
who can get a job. The relationship between [N.sup.s], u, and N is
[N.sup.s] = (1 - u)N. (15)
To avoid workers' exertion to a minimum (zero effort), we have
shown that the labor market equilibrium must result in unemployment.
This implies that [N.sup.d] = [N.sup.s] holds at a positive unemployment
rate. Therefore, the labor market equilibrium condition is
mn(u, p) = (1 - u)N. (16)
The equilibrium unemployment rate [u.sup.*] can be solved from
Equation 16 as
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. (17)
The impacts of changes in p on the firm's wage-setting will
further vary by way of changing the unemployment rate. By substituting
Equation 17 into Equation 13, the market equilibrium wage [W.sup.*]is
[W.sup.*] = [W.sup.*](p) = W[[u.sup.*](p), p], (18)
with
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. (14)
As stated in section 3, money is neutral in the standard efficiency
wage model with t = 0. This result is demonstrated by Equation 17 and 18
under the constraint of the Solow condition w[e.sub.w]/e = 1, that is,
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] and [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
When the nonindexation lump-sum tax is introduced, the results in
Equations 17 and 18 show that the market equilibrium wage level will
rise less than proportionally with the price increase, whereby the
equilibrium unemployment rate will fall in response. In other words, the
aggregate employment and thus aggregate output will rise as the price
level increases.(15)
Graphically, we name the loci of the combinations of N and u, which
respectively satisfy Equations 14 and 15, as the LD curve and the LS
curve. Their slopes are du/d[N.sup.d] = 1/m[n.sub.u] [greater than] 0
and du/d[N.sup.s] = -1/N [less than] 0. The positively sloping LD curve
reflects the fact that an increase in the unemployment rate motivates
the worker to furnish more work effort and thus increases each
firm's labor demand. The negatively sloping LS curve reveals that a
rise in the unemployment rate reduces the number of workers who can get
a job. Both curves are drawn in the right-hand panel of Figure 1, and
the intersection of both curves determines the market equilibrium
employment [N.sup.*] and the equilibrium unemployment rate [u.sup.*].
A curve WS depicting the firm's wage-setting behavior in
Equation 13 is drawn in the left-hand panel of Figure 1. The negatively
sloping WS curve states the result of [W.sub.u] [less than] 0 in
Equation 13a; that is, a higher unemployment rate raises the work effort
and thus enables the firm to lower its wage offer without hurting labor
productivity. By substituting the equilibrium unemployment rate
[u.sup.*] into the WS curve, one can obtain the market equilibrium wage
[W.sup.*]. There are N ex ante homogeneous workers who are willing to
work at the market wage [W.sup.*] and to provide the effort level
according to the effort function in Equation 6. However, the number of
total available vacancies that all firms in the economy want to afford
is only [N.sup.*]. There are (N - [N.sup.*]) workers who want to work at
the prevailing wage but cannot find a job and become unemployed
involuntarily.
When t = 0, a rise in the price level makes each firm raise its
nominal wage proportionally, and hence employment remains intact. This
change shifts the WS curve upward to [WS.sub.1] and leaves the LD curve
unchanged. As a result, the market equilibrium wage increases from
[W.sup.*] to [Mathematical Expression Omitted], whereas the market
equilibrium employment [N.sup.*] and the unemployment rate [u.sup.*]
remain unaltered. When t [greater than] 0, a rise in p motivates each
firm to raise its nominal wage less than proportionally and increase its
employment simultaneously. The WS curve thus shifts upward to
[WS.sub.2], and the LD curve shifts downward to [LD.sub.1]. The result
is that the market equilibrium nominal wage increases to [Mathematical
Expression Omitted], and the equilibrium unemployment rate falls to
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
The result of money nonneutrality is crucially based on the
assumption of the rigidity of the lump-sum tax. The tax we define is a
representative specification of a lot of costs. Since these costs are
some parts of the total wage or the average cost of labor that employers
pay, we name such channels as the partial rigidity of the wage.
Why are these costs rigid or, in a more plausible setting, not under
full indexation? It is because these costs are always determined by
tedious political processes. The outcomes of political negotiations
(laws) are public goods. These public goods, once produced, are
available for use by all citizens without cost. The free-rider problem
then naturally appears. The producers of public goods create a positive
externality so that such goods tend to be underproduced. This means that
these costs cannot be adjusted quickly or precisely enough to be under
full indexation. In sum, the notion of the externalities of public goods
is the essential reason for justifying why some parts of wages are not
fully flexible and why changes in aggregate demand policies are the
causes of fluctuations in aggregate supply.
For the same reasons, the argument can be applied to the idea of
partial rigidity of prices. As we know, the price is always defined as
the amount of money that buyers pay and is assumed to be the actual
average revenue of sellers. From a broader point of view, the actual
average revenue of sellers is equal to the price that buyers pay after
the deduction of transportation and storage costs, advertising and
wastage costs, various taxes and insurance fees, and so on. Some of
these costs are also determined by tedious political negotiations. As a
consequence, partial rigidity of prices exists and is one of the reasons
why changes in money supply and other demand management policies can
cause fluctuations in aggregate employment and output.(16)
5. Concluding Remarks
The efficiency wage theory is generally regarded as a plausible
explanation as to why wages do not fall to clear labor markets in the
presence of involuntary unemployment. In a paper, Blinder (1988, p. 290)
claims that "the simplest, and to me the most appealing, of these
[theories addressing the involuntary unemployment question] is the
efficiency wage model. It also seems to accord best with common
sense." In their popular macroeconomic textbook, Blanchard and
Fischer (1989, p. 489) claim that "in labor markets, notions of
efficiency wages have a definite ring of truth."
However, any efficiency wage model based on pure maximization must,
of necessity, be a real model. "They have nothing to say about
nominal magnitudes, and hence allow no role for nominal money, until
they are altered to include fixed costs of changing nominal wages or
prices. Nor, in their current state of development, do they have much to
say about fluctuations in employment" (Blinder 1988, p. 290). In
this paper, we use the idea of partial rigidity of wages to point out a
linkage between aggregate demand policies and aggregate supply in a pure
maximization shirking-type model of efficiency wages. We believe that
the partial rigidity of wages is a very common phenomenon in our modern
democratic societies, and surely such a linkage is also suitable in
other macroeconomic models.
We would like to thank one anonymous referee for helpful comments and
suggestions. Any remaining errors are entirely our responsibility.
1 Mankiw (1985) proposed a similar idea of the menu cost at more or
less the same time.
2 Hence, the only possibility for establishing a link between
aggregate demand and economic activities is by means of the (full)
rigidities of wages (or prices) at least in the short run.
3 Another famous version of efficiency wages without an effort
function is the labor turnover model of Salop (1979).
4 Excellent surveys of the efficiency wage literature have been
provided by Yellen (1984), Akerlof and Yellen (1986), and Katz (1986).
5 The analytical framework we use is a static framework, which
closely follows Pisauro (1991). A dynamic framework originating from
Shapiro and Stiglitz (1984) can be found in Chatterji and Sparks (1991).
6 For details, see Pisauro (1991).
7 This is a simple utility function form that keeps the following
analysis as simple as possible. A more general form of the utility
function U(y, e) with [U.sub.y] [greater than] 0, [U.sub.yy] [less than]
0, [U.sub.e] [less than] 0, [U.sub.ee] [less than] 0, U(0, 0) = 0 does
not change the basic results regarding money nonneutrality in this
paper. A detailed mathematical appendix concerning the results reported
in this paper can be obtained from the authors upon request.
8 Even if this taxation could be discretely reset or automatically
adjusted according to some degree of indexation of the price level, it
is very hard to believe that full indexation can exist in the real
world. It is accordingly very reasonable to specify that the labor tax
cannot be adjusted to full indexation due to incomplete information and
the complicated process of political negotiations. Without loss of
generality, we thus assume that the lump-sum tax is complete
nonindexation. However, it is easy to understand that the qualitative
comparative statics of the partial-indexation setting are the same as
those of the nonindexation setting.
9 Since the effects of changes in the lump-sum tax are not the focus
of this paper, we do not report the comparative static results in
relation to this tax in the discussion that follows. An analysis of the
lump-sum tax can be found in Pisauro (1991).
10 It is assumed that (f[prime] + enf[double prime]) [greater than]
0. This assumption holds under the usual production function form f(en)
= [(en).sup.[Alpha]] with 0 [less than] [Alpha] [less than] 1. Akerlof
and Yellen (1985) and Pisauro (1991) made the same assumption in their
efficiency wage models.
11 Since the price level is exogenous to the firm, the firm is
indifferent when it comes to maximizing nominal or real profits.
12 The money wage increase is less proportional than the price
increase, and thus the real wage decreases.
13 The assumption of utility differences between employment and
unemployment underlies models of trade unions (see, e.g., Oswald 1985)
and models of job search (e.g., Devine and Kiefer 1991). The literature
on the relationship between employment, unemployment, and subjective
well-being has been reviewed by Warr (1987), Banks and Ullah (1988), and
Feather (1990). These reviews show that unemployment is generally found
to be negatively correlated with well-being. Recently, Korpi (1997) has
provided some empirical evidence showing that, relative to employment,
unemployment has an ambiguously negative effect on well-being.
14 Here, we suppose that d[e(1 - u)N]/du = [e.sub.u](1 - u)N - eN
[less than] 0. This assumption excludes the situation in which a rise in
the economy's unemployment rate raises the effective labor force of
the total employed workers of the economy. A similar assumption is made
in Pisauro (1991, p. 337).
15 This indicates that the aggregate supply curve for the economy
will be positive in the output-price quadrant. As a result, changes in
money supply and other demand management policies can cause fluctuations
in aggregate employment and output.
16 The idea of externality has been successfully used to construct
such business cycle models as the menu costs model of Mankiw (1985) and
the profit sharing model of Weitzman (1985). The sources of externality
they propose arise from the market structures of imperfect competition and fixed-share contract. In welfare economics, we learn that imperfect
competition and public goods may explain why resource allocation in free
markets cannot be Pareto efficient. Here, it is interesting and
important to emphasize that imperfect competition and public goods are
the causes of business cycles.
References
Akerlof, George A. 1982. Labor contract as partial gift exchange.
Quarterly Journal of Economics 97:543-69.
Akerlof, George A., and Janet L. Yellen. 1985. A near-rational model
of business cycle with wage and price inertia. Quarterly Journal of
Economics 99:823-38.
Akerlof, George A., and Janet L. Yellen. 1986. Introduction. In
Efficiency wage models of the labor market, edited by George A. Akerlof
and Janet L. Yellen. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 1-20.
Banks, Michael H., and Philip Ullah. 1988. Youth unemployment in the
1980s: Its psychological effects. London: Croom Helm.
Blanchard, Olivier J., and Stanley Fischer. 1989. Lectures on
macroeconomics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Blinder, Alan S. 1988. The fall and rise in Keynesian economics.
Economic Record 65:278-94.
Chatterji, Monojit, and Roger Sparks. 1991. Real wages, productivity,
and the cycle: An efficiency wage model. Journal of Macroeconomics
13:495-510.
Devine, Theresa J., and Nicholas M. Kiefer. 1991. Empirical labor
economics: The search approach. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Feather, Notman T. 1990. The psychological impact of unemployment.
New York: Springer-Verlag.
Katz, Lawrence F. 1986. Efficiency wage theories: A partial
evaluation. In NBER macroeconomics annual, edited by Stanley Fischer.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, pp. 235-76.
Korpi, Tomas. 1997. Is utility related to employment status?
Employment, unemployment, labor market policies and subjective
well-being among Swedish youth. Labour Economics 4:125-47.
Leibenstein, Harvey. 1957. Economic backwardness and economic growth.
New York: Wiley, pp. 58-67.
Mankiw, Gregory. 1985. Small menu costs and large business cycles: A
macroeconomic model of monopoly. Quarterly Journal of Economics
100:529-37.
Oswald, Andrew J. 1985. The economic theory of trade unions: An
introductory survey. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 87:160-93.
Pisauro, Giuseppe. 1991. The effect of taxes on labour in efficiency
wage models. Journal of Public Economics 46: 329-45.
Salop, Steven. 1979. A model of the natural rate of unemployment.
American Economic Review 69:117-25.
Schmidt-Sorensen, Jan Beyer. 1990. The equilibrium-wage elasticity in
efficiency-wage models. Economics Letters 32: 365-9.
Shapiro, Carl, and Joseph E. Stiglitz. 1984. Equilibrium unemployment
as a worker discipline device. American Economic Review 74:433-44.
Warr, Peter B. 1987. Work, unemployment and mental health. Oxford:
Clarendon Press.
Weiss, Andrew. 1980. Job queues and layoffs in labor markets with
flexible wages. Journal of Political Economy 88: 526-38.
Weitzman, Martin L. 1985. The simple macroeconomics of
profit-sharing. American Economic Review 75:937-53.
Yellen, Janet L. 1984. Efficiency wage models of unemployment.
American Economic Review Proceedings 74:200-5.