Perfect Competition and the Transformation of Economics.
Heath, Will Carrington
This well-researched treatise by Frank Machovec makes the case, not
originally but thoroughly and convincingly, that the classical
understanding of market activity differed fundamentally from the
neoclassical paradigm. Machovec challenges the dominant interpretation
of neoclassical economics in general, and the model of perfect
competition in particular, as a mathematically formalized rendering of
the classical vision. "[T]he model of perfect competition should
more aptly be characterized as a mutation," the author argues,
"for its genes bear little resemblance to those of its presumed
parents."
Professor Machovec does more than challenge the continuity assumption
by which neoclassical theorists link present-day equilibrium analysis to
classical economics. He goes on to argue that the modern paradigm
misrepresents the market in ways that result in maldirected economic
policy. To the extent that neoclassical orthodoxy rests on the
assumption of perfect competition and ignores the Hayekian problem of
knowledge, it inevitably leads, Machovec insists, to interventionist
policy which is at once complicated and naive.
If the neoclassical model of perfect competition is a
"mutation," as Machovec characterizes it, when did this
mutation occur? And why did leading economists eventually embrace it so
warmly? Machovec traces the model of pure competition back to
Cournot's Researches Into the Mathematical Principles of the Theory
of Wealth, where it first appeared in 1838 and languished virtually
unnoticed for several decades. (During the first few years of its
publication, apparently not a single copy was sold.) Stanley Jevons was
an early proponent of the Cournotian approach to market structure, and
predicted that it would triumph over the process-oriented approach.
History would prove him correct, but not immediately.
By the turn of the century Walras's general equilibrium model
was rapidly gaining adherents among the more technically proficient
economists around the world, and with this model came the need for a
more formal derivation of equilibrium conditions under perfect
competition. But Machovec maintains that the decisive turning point in
the history of competition theory, the revolutionary coup d'etat,
occurred later, with the 1921 publication of Frank Knight's Risk,
Uncertainty and Profit. More than anyone else it was Knight, Machovec
argues, who transformed the substance of competition theory from an
understanding of "process" in the classical sense, which
involved thinking, acting entrepreneurs, to the derivation of
entrepreneurless static-equilibrium conditions. Economists embraced
Knight's methodology because they yearned, then as now, for a
measure of scientific legitimacy; they wanted their science to be
recognized as rigorous, formal, predictive and "objective."
Since entrepreneurship cannot be modeled precisely, the concept of
market process had to be abandoned, "banished to the economic
hinterlands," as Machovec aptly puts it.
Machovec argues that the new theory of competition elides a critical
distinction between the foreknowledge necessary to calculate the prices
and quantities of a static equilibrium, and the revealed information
which makes possible an equilibrium in the context of entrepreneurial
market behavior. The assumption of perfect foreknowledge obviates the
role of entrepreneurs, whereas the discovery of revealed information is
the essence of entrepreneurial activity. Perfect competition thus
removes entrepreneurs from the competitive process and opens the door to
a centralized guiding intelligence that can not only carry out the
functions of the market, but actually improve upon its overall
performance. Armed with more complete information than any single
economic agent could hope to possess, the central planners could arrive
at equilibrium prices more directly, with fewer trials and errors, than
the unplanned market actually does.
Machovec traces the implications of this interventionist mentality
for four key fields of economic study: industrial organization,
comparative systems, development, and international trade. In each of
these areas the author demonstrates that static-equilibrium theory
favors consideration of factors and outcomes that can be formalized
mathematically and calculated in numerical terms.
This book is one in the series, Foundations of the Market Economy,
edited by Mario Rizzo and Lawrence White, the underlying theme of which
series is that markets should be understood as causal processes driven
by the perceptions, expectations and preferences of human actors.
Clearly Machovec echoes these themes in his contribution to that series.
The central arguments of his book - that the static-equilibrium model of
market analysis is distinctively modern, not classical, and that this
model engendered a pro-planning spirit among many post-Walrasian
economists - are hardly original; however, few scholars have amassed as
much supporting material for these arguments as Machovec offers here.
And while he relies heavily on the usual sources from Classical,
Austrian and Chicago literature, Machovec also assembles a surprisingly
diverse cast of bit-part players, much to pleasure of this reviewer.
William F. Buckley, Stephen Jay Gould, Samuel Johnson, Robert Bork,
Aristotle, Thomas Sowell, Edgar Allen Poe, Fidel Castro, Dostoyevsky and
President Bill Clinton all find their way into this delightfully
readable book.
A minor flaw in Machovec's presentation is his tendency to make
points repetitively, which adds unnecessarily to the book's length.
In general, however, this treatise is artfully written and holds the
intelligent reader's attention throughout. Perfect Competition and
the Transformation of Economics is a treasure-trove of bibliographic
material for those interested in the history of economic theory,
particularly the theory of competition.
Will Carrington Heath University of Southwestern Louisiana