Xenophon Oeconomicus: A Social and Historical Commentary.
Lowry, S. Todd
Most economists are aware that the name for their discipline dates
back to a 4th century B.C. Greek text by Xenophon, but few have bothered
to read it. It has been represented as dealing with household economics,
but once when I gave it to a top quality business administration student
to read, he came back shaking his head, "you know, its all there -
personnel management and organization science - you don't need much
more!"
Pomeroy has given us an introduction that includes a biographical
sketch of Xenophon, the history of the document itself, and a discussion
of its influence in European education, particularly its support of
equal education for women. The text is presented with the Greek and
English on opposing pages, with 134 pages of commentary that ties the
material into the latest scholarship on the subject matter in the
classics and economic history. This translation is distinguished from
others, even recent ones, by the serious scholarly content of the
commentary and the insight of the introduction.
Although all 19th century economists had classical educations and
many, Sidgwick, Jowet, Wicksteed, Ingram, had a foot in both camps, by
the turn of the century, things changed. The theologically, ethically or
philosophically oriented classical scholars began to defend their
shrinking turf. One thing became quite clear; they did not want the
purity of their discipline sullied by the grubby science of economics.
The Greek heritage in ethics, politics, historiography, and mathematics
was heralded, but not economics. The epitome of this attitude was M. I.
Finley's adamant denial of any relevant economic ideas in the
writings of Aristotle or Xenophon in his classic 1970 essay,
"Aristotle and Economic Analysis," in Past & Present [no.
47, pp. 3-25]. He drew on Schumpeter's failure to find antecedents
to his perception of economic analysis and on a narrow price-theory
definition of the total discipline of economics. As the ranking economic
historian of antiquity, he stifled communication between the disciplines
with both economists and classicists trusting his judgment in the other
field.
Pomeroy challenges Finley's anachronistic obstinacy in refusing
to grasp the relation of Xenophon's concept of the division of
labor to the market [p. 43], and for failing to appreciate the
significance of the accounting practices of the day [p. 56]. We should
go further, however, and point out that Xenophon's discussion of
use value and exchange value is worth Xeroxing and circulating to
introductory economics students. After all, the Oeconomicus was an
instructional piece and presents its basic ideas quite vividly. Value is
subjectively defined and exchange value is approached as a skill that
would enable an individual to take advantage of the general social
capacity to use an item, such as a horse, that may not only not be a
value to its owner, but even a hazard. According to Xenophon,
responsibility and efficiency were enhanced more by praise, incentives,
and rewards than by penalties while good leadership could double
productivity. Historically, the concept of organization and finely tuned
interaction was the primary conceptual legacy of the Oeconomicus but it
vested in the late 19th century in the new discipline of ecology, moved
to ecosystems and returned to management science as systems analysis and
linear programming - yes, Xenophon does touch on programming in his Ways
and Means.
Economists should not forget that economic science is a system of
analysis that applies to the economic system of the culture being
studied. During the heyday of ancient Greek culture, the family
agricultural estate was the basic production/consumption structure of
the society. No more than about 15% of the population were ever
supported in commerce, handicrafts, the military or government
administration until the 18th century. The oikos by that or other names
was the real economic unit throwing off some surplus grain and textiles
for trade and taxes. We pay too little attention to the breakthrough in
agricultural productivity in 18th century England when abstracting the
character of capitalism and its applicability to less developed
countries.
Of parallel interest to historians of economic thought should be the
section on estate management in Yassine Essid's recent book, A
Critique of the Origins of Islamic Economic Thought [2]. The Muslims
followed a Greek text by a neo-Pythagorean, Bryson, who had written a
text paralleling Xenophon's Oeconomicus in many respects. Also, the
chapter on the Cistercian monasteries in Louis Baeck's The
Mediterranean Tradition in Economic Thought [1] brings home the crucial
significance of agricultural organization in earlier economies.
The interdisciplinary door is being gradually opened, but
Pomeroy's analysis would have been strengthened by a more
perceptive emphasis on an analysis of Xenophon's focus on human
capital in the form of training and organized interaction. Also, his
treatment of the importance of information and administration could have
been rounded out in terms more accessible to modern practitioners of
management science. You would have hoped to see the name of a prominent
historian of economic thought listed in her acknowledgments of those who
read her manuscript. Economists do have something to contribute in
understanding both the retrospective significance of the classics and
the technical importance of classical writings in their own time and
place. For example, not only is subjective value elaborated in great
detail in classical literature, but the hedonic calculus and ordinal
utility are clearly developed. There are also some striking bits of
formal analysis that must have been constantly surfacing over the ages.
I refer specifically to the closing lines of Xenophon's Banquet or
Symposium where Socrates is formally challenged to justify his
reputation as a thinker by some demonstration of profundity. A classical
scholar could not be expected to appreciate Socrates' reply, but to
an economist, it is a clear statement that profitability is maximized by
reducing marginal costs that do not contribute to marginal revenue!
[Xen. Banquet, VII. 1-5; 3, 75, 81]. At a minimum, this passage can be
associated with the use of cost/benefit analysis in the administrative
policies of 18th century French engineers.
S. Todd Lowry Washington and Lee University
References
1. Baeck, L. The Mediterranean Tradition in Economic Thought. New
York and London: Routledge, 1994.
2. Essid, M. Y. A Critique of the Origins of lslamic Economic
Thought. New York and Leiden: E. J. Brill, 1995.
3. Lowry, S. T. The Archaeology of Economic Ideas: The Classical
Greek Tradition. Durham: Duke University Press, 1987.