Is the endogenous business cycle dead?
Goldstein, Jonathan P.
I. Introduction
A clearly defined dichotomy exists in the business cycle literature
between endogenous and exogenous cycles. Exogenous cycles are either
temporary, heavily damped random deviations from a stable long-run
growth path or permanent stochastic fluctuations in the growth path
which both require repeated stochastic impulses to generate typically
observed recurrent and irregular fluctuations. In contrast, endogenous
cycles are systematic (deterministic), self-generating recurrent cycles
that result from the inherent instability (structure) of the underlying
economy.
The most recent and most severe critiques of endogenous theory are
empirical in nature and stem from the unit root debates which contrast
trend stationary (TS) and difference stationary (DS) models. Despite
this critique, the evolution of this methodology has produced
conflicting results with respect to the most appropriate model. More
importantly this approach implicitly rejects, through the use of an
overly restrictive specification, endogenous cycles in favor of
stochastic cycles. In this light, the purpose of this paper is to
justify and apply an alternative, more general, estimation framework
that includes DS, TS and endogenous cycles as nested alternatives.
In particular, I employ a structural time series (STS) or unobserved
components methodology which allows for a direct empirical test of
endogenous cycle theory against stochastic alternatives and/or mixed
stochastic-endogenous models. The integration of secular regime shifts
into the basic STS model effectively introduces nonlinearities and thus
moves the analysis one step beyond simple linear models. This general
approach which relies on economic theory for model specification is
superior to the ARIMA-based unit root methodology which relies solely on
the data to identify the structure of macro time series.
Using this approach, I estimate STS models for seven relevant U.S.
macroeconomic time series and find that endogenous cycles play a
fundamental role in characterizing the data generation process.
The remainder of this paper is organized in the following manner.
Section II reviews the restrictive nature of the unit root-ARIMA
methodology. Section III offers an alternative approach. Section IV
presents estimation results and section V contains my conclusions.
II. The Unit Root-ARIMA Methodology
While the early work of Nelson and Plosser [6] sparked interest in
the subject of unit roots, it also severely limited the scope of inquiry
through a restrictive specification of endogenous business cycles. The
unit root debate contrasts two variants of new classical stochastic
business cycle theory - real business cycles versus equilibrium business
cycles based on incomplete information and rational expectations.
More formally, a TS process can be represented as follows
[Y.sub.t] = [[Alpha].sub.0] + [[Alpha].sub.1]t +
[Theta](L)[[Phi].sup.-1](L)[[Epsilon].sub.t] (1)
where L is the lag operator, [[Alpha].sub.0] and [[Alpha].sub.1] are
constants, t is a time trend, and
[Theta](L)[[Phi].sup.-1](L)[[Epsilon].sub.t] is a stationary ARMA (p, q)
process. While stationarity does not preclude complex conjugate roots
for the AR polynomial and thus systematic cyclical behavior, it limits
that behavior to damped fluctuations. Thus constant amplitude (self-generating) cycles are not readily considered. While this approach
subsumes endogenous cycles as a special case - complex conjugate roots
with a modulus statistically indistinguishable from one, the vast
majority of unit root tests accept DS over TS. In the DS case, the
treatment of endogenous cycles is even more restrictive.
Equation (2) represents a DS process:
[Delta][Y.sub.t] = [Beta] +
[Theta](L)[[Phi].sup.-1](L)[[Epsilon].sub.t] or [Y.sub.t] = [Y.sub.t-1]
+ [Beta] + [Theta](L)[[Phi].sup.-1](L)[[Epsilon].sub.t] (2)
where [Beta] is a constant and [Delta] is the difference operator.
Even though [Delta]Y can follow an AR(p) process and thus include
systematic cycles implying cycles in [Y.sub.t], the coefficient
restrictions implied by the I (1) structure make it extremely difficult
to find evidence of constant amplitude behavior.
In particular a DS plus AR(p) or ARIMA (p, 1, 0) results in a
potential cycle characterized by a p + 1 order difference equation for
[Y.sub.t] (in levels) with p independent coefficients.(1) In addition,
recent evidence of smooth stochastic trends - a special case of a local
linear trend where the intercept is not stochastic but the slope is
mildly stochastic - in macro time series, found by Harvey and Jaeger [4]
suggests that the DS and TS models are misspecified.(2)
On the practical side, the treatment of autocorrelation in unit root
equations neglects the importance of structural cycles by treating the
MA (q) process as an infinite AR process and thus conflating the AR and
MA components.(3) Finally, the common finding of a unit root and a
significant time trend in unit root tests casts doubt on the validity of
such tests. Technically, the acceptance of the unit root hypothesis
requires that both the coefficient on [Y.sub.t-1] and t be insignificant
in a [Delta][Y.sub.t] equation. Yet practitioners interpret this common
result as support for the DS hypothesis. In contrast, these results, as
are the smooth trend findings, may be indicative of more complex
behavior where [Delta][Y.sub.t] is nonstationary and thus suggest the
need for a more flexible modelling approach.
In summary, the unit root-ARIMA methodology neglects, on the
practical level, the existence of structural cycles and, on the
theoretical level, treats these cycles through a restrictive
specification. Thus, this approach is seriously flawed with respect to
cross-paradigm or mixed tests of business cycle theories.
III. Statistical Methodology
In this section, I describe an alternative statistical methodology -
structural time series (STS) or unobserved components models - which
includes a less restrictive specification of cycles and effectively
considers relevant stochastic and deterministic trend and cycle models
as nested alternatives or mixed models which can be decomposed.
In a formal specification of an STS model,(4) the trend, [Mu], is
modelled with a random level (intercept), [Alpha], and a random slope,
[Beta], as:
[[Mu].sub.t] = [[Mu].sub.t-1] + [[Beta].sub.t-1] + [[Eta].sub.t] (3a)
[[Beta].sub.t] = [[Beta].sub.t-1] + [[Zeta].sub.t] (3b)
where [Mathematical Expression Omitted], [Mathematical Expression
Omitted], [[Eta].sub.t] and [[Zeta].sub.t] are mutually uncorrelated and
[[Mu].sub.0] = [Alpha]. The equations in (3) characterize a local linear
trend. In the case where [Mathematical Expression Omitted] a special
case of an I(2) trend, a smooth stochastic trend results, when
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] and [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
a DS model results, and when [Mathematical Expression Omitted],
[[Mu].sub.t] = [Alpha] + [Beta]t is a deterministic trend or TS.
Consistent with the general solution of a difference equation that
can exhibit a constant amplitude cycle, the cyclical component is
modelled as
[[Psi].sub.t] = [Gamma]cos[[Lambda].sub.c]t + [Delta] sin
[[Lambda].sub.c]t (4)
where [Gamma] and [Delta] are unknown parameters and [[Lambda].sub.c]
is the unknown frequency of the cycle measured in radians. The cycle
period is thus 2[Pi]/[[Lambda].sub.c]. An appropriate stochastic variant
of equation (4) which includes both a damping factor, [Rho], and random
walk-type evolution of [Gamma] and [Delta] is generated from a two
equation recursion.(5) In order to form [[Psi].sub.t], the recursion
requires the use of a constructed variable, [Mathematical Expression
Omitted].
Thus the cycle can be expressed as:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (5)
where 0 [less than or equal to] [Rho] [less than or equal to] 1 is a
damping factor and [[Kappa].sub.t] and [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
are two white noise disturbances. This vector AR(1) model is
identifiable if either [Mathematical Expression Omitted] or
[[Kappa].sub.t] and [Mathematical Expression Omitted] are uncorrelated.
For parsimony both of these assumptions are imposed.
The reduced form of equation (5) allows for the decomposition of the
cycle into deterministic and stochastic components:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (6)
where [Y.sub.t] is the observed series. The LHS of equation (6)
represents the deterministic cycle, while the RHS the stochastic cycle.
The deterministic cycle in (6) will have complex conjugate roots under
the condition that 0 [less than] [[Lambda].sub.c] [less than] [Pi]. Here
two independent parameters, [[Lambda].sub.c] and [Rho], determine the
nature of the cycle, thus this representation is less restrictive than
the cycle in the unit root-ARIMA approach. The modulus associated with
the cycle is [Rho]. Thus for [Rho] [less than] 1, the structural cycle
is damped and for [Rho] = 1 the cycle is endogenous (self-sustaining) by
virtue of its constant amplitude. Finally, when [Mathematical Expression
Omitted], the cycle is deterministic (nonstochastic).
The damping factor, [Rho], is at the heart of statistical tests for
an endogenous cycle. The stationarity conditions on the AR(p) polynomial
in the TS and DS specifications require that the estimation techniques
employed restrict [Rho] such that [Rho] [less than or equal to] 1. Thus
a tradeoff exists between the specification of an all encompassing
estimation framework that includes the three key hypotheses in a nested
format and the equal statistical treatment of the competing hypotheses.
In particular the exclusion of values of [Rho] [greater than] 1 makes,
on a priori grounds, the hypothesis that [Rho] = 1 more difficult to
accept. Thus the key issue in testing for an endogenous cycle is
restricted to not whether [Rho] = 1 or [Rho] [not equal to] 1, but is
rather the degree of damping. Point estimates of [Rho] close to, but
less than, one imply that the cycle is only mildly damped with a
virtually nonexistent dependence on random shocks for propagation. As a
result, STS estimation can only effectively, rather than definitively,
treat competing hypotheses as nested alternatives. Given that the
macroeconomic theory that underlies both TS and DS specifications argues
for heavily damped AR(p) components, it is not difficult to distinguish
this behavior from a heavily undamped, but stationary, process.
Finally, the irregular component, [Epsilon], is modelled as:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. (7)
Thus the full STS model can be written as
[y.sub.t] = [[Mu].sub.1] + [[Psi].sub.t] + [[Epsilon].sub.t] (8)
where y, is the dependent variable, [[Mu].sub.t], [[Psi].sub.t] and
[[Epsilon].sub.t] are as defined in equations (3), (5), and (7) and all
distributance terms, [[Eta].sub.t], [[Zeta].sub.t], [[Kappa].sub.t],
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] and [[Epsilon].sub.t], are assumed to
be mutually uncorrelated.
The three main business cycle hypotheses can be distinguished on the
basis of the [Mathematical Expression Omitted], [Mathematical Expression
Omitted], and [Rho] coefficients: (1) DS requires [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] and [Rho] [less than] 1; (2) TS requires
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] and [Rho] [less than] 1; and (3)
endogenous cycles necessitate [Rho] = 1. Thus [Rho] = 1 is a sufficient
condition to distinguish endogenous cycles from the other
specifications. A deterministic trend or a stochastic trend plus an
endogenous cycle are evidence against the TS and DS hypotheses. In
addition, a smooth stochastic trend also suggests the same result.
A non-nested alternative to the trend plus cycle specification is a
cyclical trend (level) specification. This is achieved by modifying
equation (3a) to be [[Mu].sub.t] = [[Mu].sub.t-1] + [[Psi].sub.t-1] +
[[Beta].sub.t-1] + [[Eta].sub.t] and substituting this modification
along with equations (3b), (5) and (7) into equation (8). This
alternative is considered below.
Statistical treatment of STS models requires that the parameters
([Mathematical Expression Omitted], [Mathematical Expression Omitted],
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], [Rho], [[Lambda].sub.c],
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]) governing the evolution of the
unobserved components (state variables), referred to as hyperparameters,
be estimated. The Kalman filter is used to decompose the likelihood
function into one-step ahead prediction errors, thus allowing for
maximum likelihood (ML) estimates of the hyper-parameters to be
generated. After these parameters are estimated the Kalman filter is
used again to generate optimal forecasts and to generate optimal
estimates of the entire state (trend, cycle) trajectories via a
smoothing algorithm.(6)
IV. Estimation Results
I consider the estimation of the STS trend and cycle model for seven
key quarterly macroeconomic time series. The variables cover four major
areas considered in endogenous theories of the cycle - production and
employment, aggregate demand, profitability, and financial conditions -
and are grouped into these four categories: (1) real gross domestic
product (GDP) and the civilian unemployment rate (UN); 2) real
consumption (CON) and real net nonresidential investment (INV); 3)
profit's share of national income (PS); and 4) the real BAA industrial bond rate (BAA) and the debt-equity ratio for the
manufacturing sector (DER). A full description of each variable with
sources is contained in Appendix A. All STS models are estimated over
the sample range from 1949:1 to 1995:2 - a period that includes eight
complete cycles and a portion of the ninth cycle as determined by the
NBER cycle dating system.(7)
Before estimation techniques are employed, I describe the level and
first difference of these variables. With the exception of UN, the
production and demand series show a noticeable increase in volatility in
the post-1970 period. There is also a possible upward shift in the trend
of UN and CON in this same subperiod. The profitability and financial
series reveal an increase in volatility in the DER variable and a
possible shift in the trend for BAA upward. The latter shift does not
occur until 1979 and is most likely associated with the regime shift in
the conduct of monetary policy.
These findings have important implications for the specification of
STS models. The heteroscedasticity and trend shifts can be theorized in
one of four ways as a result of: 1) the normal evolution of the
stochastic components of the STS model; 2) a structural change in the
data generation process; 3) in the case of increased volatility only, a
(significant) random shock which increases variances and levels in an
autocorrelated (damped, but persistent) manner; or 4) in the case of
increased volatility only, a simple heteroscedastic pattern (as a
continuous function of time). Each of these four perspectives
respectively supports a different statistical specification: 1) one STS
model for the entire sample; 2) two STS models, one prior to the
structural break the other after; 3) an autoregressive conditional
heteroscedasticity (ARCH) model integrated with a single period STS
model; and 4) a single period STS model for log ([Y.sub.t]) rather than
[Y.sub.t].
The heteroscedastic pattern in the data and the possible trend shifts
cast serious doubt on the appropriateness of a single uncorrected STS
model with assumed homoscedastic error variances for the entire sample
range. The only exception is the PS series which does not experience a
shift or increased volatility. The existence of a heteroscedastic
pattern which is a positive step-function, rather than a continuous
function, of time suggests that a log transformation may induce a
reverse heteroscedastic (negative function of time) pattern and thus not
improve the properties of the statistical estimates and tests.
The ARCH and structural change models are competing perspectives on
the evolution of a heteroscedastic pattern. The former is a stochastic
explanation whereas the latter is structural/deterministic. An ARCH
interpretation implies that the damping process is slow enough such that
significant supply shocks in the 1970s have resulted in increased
volatility into the 1990s without a return of [Mathematical Expression
Omitted], to its steady state. In contrast a structural break argument
focuses on a major regime shift, circa 1970, associated with a rapid
deterioration in U.S. industrial relations, a significantly lower rate
of productivity growth, increased levels of indebtedness, the
intensification of international competition, a decline in
profitability, and the breakdown of the international monetary system.
These fundamental changes in both the economic and institutional
structure created a permanently more uncertain and volatile environment.
Based upon a model selection strategy and my strong theoretical prior
for the structural shift argument, I report estimation results below for
an STS model estimated over two distinct periods, 1949:1-1970:4 and
1970:4-1995:2, for all series with the exceptions, discussed above, of
PS and BAA.(8) The results reported below are robust for alternative
break points between 1969-1975. In addition, selective results for
alternative specifications - models (1) and (4) above, model (4)
estimated over two time periods and a cyclical trend variant, discussed
above, of model (4) over the same periods(9) - are also reported.
Irrespective of model specification, the results concerning the
endogenous nature of the business cycle are robust.
One last pre-estimation diagnostic, the sample autocorrelation and
partial autocorrelation coefficients for the first differences of the
seven series are reported in Table I for the period 1949:1-1995:2.(10)
Examining Table I, in all series except BAA the weak condition for the
existence of a cyclical component - a positive first order
autocorrelation coefficient for the first difference along with higher
order coefficients that are not strictly zero - is clearly met. The
stronger condition for a cycle - existence of an AR(2) pattern - is met
by the GDP, INV, PS, and UN series where a clear wave-like pattern
exits, while in the CON, and DER series there is less strong, yet
observable, evidence of an AR(2) pattern. The existence of a cyclical
component is further supported in the GDP and INV time series by the
appearance of two positive spikes in the sample partial autocorrelation
function. The patterns observed for PS, DER, CON and UN are more
indicative of mixed trend and cycle models. In summary, besides the
strong theoretical support, there is strong pre-estimation evidence for
the inclusion of a cyclical component in the modelling of these time
series. Thus I now turn to the estimation of the STS model in (8).
Table I. Sample Autocorrelation and Partial Autocorrelation
Coefficients of First Differences, 1949:1-1995:2
Lag DGDP DINV DCONS DUN DPS DDER DBAA(+)
Autocorrelations
1 .36 .57 .22 .61 .14 .12 -.33
2 .21 .43 .25 24 .02 .07 -.04
3 .07 .28 .30 -.07 -.04 .13 .03
4 .05 .13 .06 -.21 -.15 .18 .07
5 -.01 -.03 .10 -.21 -.14 .11 -.18
6 .01 -.04 .09 -.10 -.02 -.06 .03
7 -.06 -.11 .02 -.10 .00 .06 .01
8 -.18 -.22 -.03 -.13 -.08 .03 .03
9 -.04 -.13 -.01 -.06 .03 .13 .02
10 .05 -.08 .05 -.04 .03 .04 .04
Partial Autocorrelations
1 .36 .57 .22 .61 .14 .12 -.33
2 .10 .16 .21 -.21 .00 .06 -.17
3 -.04 -.02 .24 -.20 .05 .11 -.05
4 .02 -.10 -.08 -.05 .14 .15 .07
Notes: Standard error of all autocorrelation coefficients is .078.
+ Sample: 1951:2 to 1995:2.
The ML estimation results for the early subperiod (1949:1-1970:4)
model and the later subperiod (1970:4-1995:2) model are respectively
reported in Tables II and III. The estimates for PS are for the entire
period (1949:1-1995:2) and only appear in Table II. The tables are
organized by the estimates of the four hyperparameters ([Mathematical
Expression Omitted], [Mathematical Expression Omitted], [Mathematical
Expression Omitted], and [Mathematical Expression Omitted]), other key
parameters - [Rho], the damping factor, [[Lambda].sub.c], the cycle
frequency, and the cycle period (2[Pi]/[[Lambda].sub.c]) - and a series
of test statistics - PEV, the prediction error variance for one
step-ahead predictions, Q (lag length), the Box-Ljung test for serial
correlation of the residuals, N, the Jarque-Bera test for normality of
the residuals, H, a standard split sample test for heteroscedasticity,
[R.sup.2] and [Mathematical Expression Omitted], the percentage
improvement in fit over a random walk plus drift model.(11)
Given that it is common either for some STS parameters to lie on the
boundary of the parameter space or to formulate hypotheses for parameter
values that lie on the boundary, a violation of one of the regularity
conditions, standard distribution theory cannot be relied upon to
specify appropriate hypothesis tests. Alternatively, I rely on a series
of nonstandard tests which are valid as long as all of the other
regularity conditions are met (see n. 6). A most powerful invariant (MPI) test is used to test for a deterministic trend [Mathematical
Expression Omitted], a likelihood ratio (LR) test is used to test
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], and a modified Lagrange multiplier (LM) test is employed to test [Rho] = 0 and [Rho] = 1.(12)
Examining the results in Tables II and III, the overwhelming majority
of the series in both periods are characterized by a smooth stochastic
trend ([Mathematical Expression Omitted] and [Mathematical Expression
Omitted]) and an additive cyclical component ([Rho] [greater than] 0).
The exceptions are UN in the early period and CON in the late period
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE III OMITTED] which exhibit a local linear trend
plus cycle, and BAA in the early period and PS over the whole period
which include cycles, but for which tests cannot distinguish between a
local linear and a smooth trend. The dominant smooth trend result does
not support either the TS or DS hypotheses, but is consistent with the
results found by Harvey and Jaeger [4] for macro time series.
Turning to the important damping factor, [Rho], the results reveal
several point estimates greater than or equal to .90 implying that the
cyclical components are dramatically undamped, but still are stationary.
A 95% (99%) two-tailed confidence interval for [Rho] contains 1.0 in 11
(12) out of 13 cycles. The exceptions being CON in the late period (95%
level only) and BAA in the late period (95% and 99%). Yet the [Rho]
confidence interval for BAA contains .99 at the .01 level of
significance. If a stricter one tail interval is constructed at the .01
(.05) significance level, in 12 (10) out of 13 cycles this interval
contains a value of one.(13) The exception in the .01 case is late
period BAA. Thus the early and late period cycles in GDP, UN, INV, and
DER and the early period cycles in CON and BAA are statistically
indistinguishable from constant amplitude cycles. This finding provides
strong evidence, in spite of the effectively more stringent intervals
employed, for the existence of self-generating, endogenous cycles in
these key macroeconomic time series. For the severely restricted number
of cases for which the LM tests of [Rho] = 1 are valid (regularity
conditions hold), these results are confirmed. In particular, [Rho] = 1
for early period INV, CON and DER and full period PS are not rejected.
The combined findings of constant amplitude cycles coexisting with a
smooth, rather than erratic, stochastic trend in all periods heavily
favors the hypothesis that cycles are endogenous phenomena with little
or no dependence on random shocks in contrast to the alternative that
cycles are shock dependent stochastic/exogenous occurrences. These
findings also suggest that both the DS and TS models are inappropriate
and that the unit root (TS-DS) debate is unnecessarily limited in scope.
Other results support the appropriateness of the statistical
specification. The estimated period of the cycles range from 10.44
quarters for UN to 20.91 quarters for DER in the early period and from
10.51 quarters for UN to 34.13 quarters for CON in the late period. This
periodicity, averaging 15.11 and 21.79 quarters respectively in the
early and late subperiods, is eminently reasonable particularly in light
of readily available explanations for the more extreme values associated
with early and late period UN and GDP.(14) In addition the diagnostics
for the 13 models reported in Tables II and III suggest for the most
part that the overall STS specifications are acceptable. If tests for
normality, homoscedasticity and autocorrelation are performed at a .01
level of significance, then all models with the exception of the UN
model in both periods and BAA in the late period pass all diagnostic
tests. While the violations associated with the UN model can be
explained,(15) no explanation is readily available in the BAA case. Thus
all models with the exception of BAA in the late period can be argued to
exhibit acceptable diagnostics. In addition the results reported below
show that the trend plus cycle model with a structural break, used here,
is superior in the vast majority of cases to the alternative
specifications considered.
The [Mathematical Expression Omitted] statistics which report the
percentage improvement in fit over the random walk with drift model - a
special case of the DS formulation and the basic representation of the
dominant stochastic cycle theory - range from .03 to .37 and thus
provide further evidence of the importance of the undamped (endogenous)
cyclical component found in the majority of models.
The estimated cycle and trend components for selected series are
depicted in Figure 1. In all four cycles the underlying constant
amplitude (endogenous) nature of the cycle is quite apparent. The
depiction of trend components is in increasing order of stochastic
influences with the late INV and GDP trends being quite smooth and the
full period PS and early period UN trends being quite erratic.
I now consider selective results, reported in Table IV, from the
alternative specifications discussed above. The PEVs for the log
([Y.sub.t]) equations have been multiplied by the factor
[e.sup.[(2/T)[Sigma]Log [Y.sub.t]]] to make them comparable to PEVs from
[Y.sub.t] models. The BAA results are excluded in the log cases due to
the existence of negative real interest rates in some periods. As
expected by the structural break hypothesis, the full period [Y.sub.t]
and log ([Y.sub.t]) models exhibit severe violations of statistical
assumptions. One major problem in the log ([Y.sub.t]) models is the
overcorrection for heteroscedasticity exhibited in the H statistics.
This result is most consistent with a step-wise increase in volatility,
as a result of a structural break.
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE IV OMITTED]
While the subperiod log ([Y.sub.t]) models with an additive cycle
have similar diagnostic problems in the early period, they have somewhat
less problems in the late period. The INV and CON model have acceptable
diagnostics. In all cases with three exceptions the log ([Y.sub.t])
subperiod models fit the data less well than their untransformed
counterparts reported above.(16) The results for the subperiod log
([Y.sub.t]) models with a trend in cycle are similar to the log
([Y.sub.t]) additive cycle models. In the late period both the UN and
INV models outperform the respective models reported above.
Thus with few exceptions, the models reported above are superior to
the rival specifications. Turning to the important damping factor, the
alternative models produce qualitatively and quantitatively similar
results to those reported above. Thus, the results that endogenous
cycles are prevalent in these key seven macroeconomic variables is
robust.
Finally, I assess the relative importance of the endogenous cycles
reported in Tables II and III. To make such an assessment operational,
it is necessary to decompose the estimated cycle, [Mathematical
Expression Omitted], in each time period into three components: 1) the
pure endogenous cycle, EC; 2) the pure stochastic cycle, SC; and 3) the
mixed endogenous-stochastic cycle, MC. Equation (6) allows this
decomposition to be carried out where the independent evolution of the
LHS of the equation determines EC and the independent evolution of the
RHS generates SC. The MC which is calculated as a residual
([Mathematical Expression Omitted]) represents the effect of past
stochastic shocks after they have been incorporated into the
structural/endogenous propagation (cycle) mechanism.
In order to assess the relative importance of these three components,
I simulate [Mathematical Expression Omitted] (equation 6) and its three
components and then calculate the average correlation coefficient between [Mathematical Expression Omitted] and EC, SC, (EC + MC) and (SC
+ MC) generated from 1,000 simulations.(17) The average correlation
coefficients are reported in Table V for two sets of simulations: (1)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] from Tables III and IV; and (2) [Rho]
= 1.
The treatment of the mixed cycle component, MC, is crucial for the
interpretation of the results in Table V. Endogenous and exogenous cycle
theorists disagree and consider MC respectively as an endogenous and
stochastic element. While I report results consistent with both
interpretations, here I focus on the endogenous approach. In particular,
a stochastic shock irrespective of the complexity of its dynamic
structure, such as RHS of equation (6), has no subsequent effect
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE V OMITTED] of its own unless it is absorbed into
the systematic/endogenous propagation mechanism. At that point, it
becomes part of the endogenous cycle and loses its independent
existence.
In this light the results in Table V, strongly corroborate the
earlier results on the relevance of endogenous cycles. In particular
there exists a strong, almost perfect when [Rho] = 1, linear association
between the total endogenous cyclical components and the overall cycle
([Mathematical Expression Omitted], (EC + MC)). In contrast, the
association between the pure stochastic component and the cycle ([Psi],
SC) is much weaker. In addition, the relative strength of the total
endogenous components is strengthened as [Rho] [approaches] 1.(18) If we
confine our analysis to the relative strength of the pure endogenous and
stochastic elements, the two have correlation coefficients of similar
magnitude in the [Mathematical Expression Omitted] case, but the EC
dominates in the [Rho] = 1 case. This result further establishes the
relative importance of the endogenous cycle.
V. Conclusion
The empirical debates over alternative business cycle theories and
the accompanying theoretical literatures have predominantly focused on
the relative merits of two variants of stochastic business cycles -
trend stationary versus difference stationary models. As a result
endogenous theories of the business cycle have been dismissed, either by
restrictive specifications or by exclusion, as being empirically
uninteresting. Given this situation, I suggest a statistical
methodology, structural time series modelling, which includes trend
stationary, difference stationary and endogenous cycles as nested
alternatives. This framework is applied to seven U.S. macroeconomic time
series typically considered in endogenous business cycle theories. A pre
and post-1970 regime shift is also integrated into the structural model.
Using this approach, I find strong evidence that endogenous cycles
play a fundamental role in characterizing the data generation process.
In particular, in both the early and late periods the vast majority of
the seven series are characterized by smooth stochastic trends and a
constant amplitude additive cyclical component. The combination of a
smooth trend and a constant amplitude cycle emphasizes the importance of
permanent endogenous cycles. These results are shown to be robust with
respect to alternative specifications.
Appendix A: Definition of Variables
BAA
The real interest rate series is defined as Moody's Industrial
BAA bond rate minus the general rate of inflation. The inflation rate is
the percentage change in the GDP deflator.
Mean = 3.81 Standard Deviation = 3.34
CON
Personal consumption expenditures in constant (1987) dollars. Source:
NIPA (U.S. Department of Commerce).
Mean = 2015.55 Standard Deviation = 846.85
DER
The DER series is complied from the debt-equity ratio for
manufacturing in various issues of the Quarterly Financial Report for
Manufacturing Corporations, 1947-86 U.S. Department of Commerce). The
debt component of the ratio is based on the market value of the current
stock of debt, while the equity component is based on book value.
Mean = 41.03 Standard Deviation = 18.29
GDP
Gross Domestic Product in constant (1987) dollars. Source: NIPA (U.S.
Department of Commerce).
Mean = 3135.97 Standard Deviation = 1190.02
INV
Fixed nonresidential investment in constant (1987) dollars. Source:
NIPA (U.S. Department of Commerce).
Mean = 333.25 Standard Deviation = 157.95
PS
Corporate profits with inventory valuation adjustment and capital
consumption adjustment as a percent of national income. Source: NIPA
(U.S. Department of Commerce).
Mean = 10.77 Standard Deviation = 2.22
UN
The civilian unemployment rate. Source: Department of Labor, Bureau
of Labor Statistics.
Mean = 5.79 Standard Deviation = 1.60
Means and standard deviations are for the period 1949:1 to 1995:2.
1. In the popular ARIMA (1, 1, 0) case the additive cycle is
represented by [Y.sub.t] = [Rho][Y.sub.t-1] - [Rho][Y.sub.t-2]. While a
cycle is possible if 4[Rho] [greater than] [[Rho].sup.2], a
self-perpetuating cycle only occurs when [Rho] = 1 implying that the
frequency (period) of the cycle is constrained to be exactly 1.045
radians (6.00 time periods).
In contrast an AR(p) allows for a damped, cycle in [Delta][Y.sub.t].
Given that most endogenous cycle theories are cast in terms of levels
rather than growth rates, the DS plus cycle model fails to adequately
incorporate endogenous cycles. Even in the case of a growth cycle, the
stationarity requirement in the DS specification rules out endogenous
growth cycles.
2. It can readily be shown that treating the stochastic slope of a
time trend as exogenous results in positive autocorrelation.
As Harvey and Jaeger [4] demonstrate via Monte Carlo simulations,
these I(2) stochastic trends are not readily detected by tests for
multiple unit roots or ARIMA modelling methods. Thus the AR corrections
typically used in single unit root tests fail to completely correct for
autocorrelation and result in inappropriate test statistics for the unit
root hypothesis.
Further, simulations reveal a tendency for t statistics to be biased
upward (towards accepting a single unit root) when a smooth stochastic
trend underlies the data but is not specified. In particular, data was
generated from the local linear trend model so as to emulate GDP
behavior. In addition, data was generated from a random walk with drift
with the same innovations. Standard unit root tests were performed on
both variables for a sample size of 150 and with the inclusion of from
one to eight lagged difference terms. On the basis of 500 samples per
set of parameter values, the average t statistic associated with the
unit root coefficient was .31 to .45 larger (less likely to reject a
unit root) in the cases where the local linear trend was the true data
generating process.
3. While this problem can be resolved by the estimation of an ARIMA
model after the issue of a unit root is resolved, Harvey [2; 3, 90-93]
and Harvey and Jaeger [4, 238-39] have convincingly argued that ARIMA
models can be misleading, particularly in the case of uncovering cycles,
when such models are chosen on grounds of parsimony.
In addition to this methodological critique of unit root tests, there
is an operational critique. See Enders [1, 239-58], McCallum [5] and
Stadler [8, 1772-73]. In particular, the power of unit root tests is
notoriously weak, the tests are biased by the failure to consider
structural breaks, heteroscadastic and autocorrelated errors and the
correct specification of deterministic regressors. Most recently there
has been a turnaround in the assessment of the empirical evidence. After
years of interpreting the evidence in favor of DS models, tests that
correct for the weaknesses of the original unit roots tests now find
that the TS model is better supported. See McCallum [5, 16-17], Simkins
[7, 977-78], and Stadler [8, 1773].
4. The remainder of this section relies heavily on Harvey [3].
5. The recursion is used to avoid discontinuities in the
specification and to ensure that the associated forecasting function
retains the property of discounting. See Harvey [3, 27-9].
6. In general desirable properties of the ML estimates hold when a
set of regularity conditions are met. In the case of the model in
equation (8), this requires that all disturbances are distributed NID,
are mutually uncorrelated, [Mathematical Expression Omitted],
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], 0 [less than] [Rho] [less than] 1,
and 0 [less than] [[Lambda].sub.c] [less than] [Pi]. Under these
conditions, the estimates of [Mathematical Expression Omitted],
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], [Mathematical Expression Omitted],
[Rho], [[Lambda].sub.c], [Mathematical Expression Omitted] are
distributed asymptotically normal, and are asymptotically unbiased with
asymptotic standard errors.
7. Alternatively, estimation results were generated over the period
which includes eight complete cycles (1949:1 to 1991:1). The results for
this sample are qualitatively similar to the results reported in the
text.
8. A one period model is fit for PS, 1949:1 to 1995:2. The break in
the BAA series occurs around 1979:2. Eliminating the outlying data
points associated with the Korean conflict, the early period for BAA is
1951:2 to 1979:2 and the late period 1979:2 to 1990:2.
9. The discussion in the text justifies the inclusion of the first
three alternative specifications. The addition of the fourth is
motivated by Harvey's [2] findings that annual data on the natural
log of GNP, industrial production, and UN are best modeled by a cyclical
trend, rather than an additive cycle, for the pre-1948 period. The same
finding also holds for GNP in the 1948-1970 period. In addition, the
inclusion of all log models is justified by the reliance on log
transformed data in the variable trend and unit root literatures.
While the integration of an ARCH process with an STS model is beyond
the scope of this paper, diagnostic evidence on the relevance of an ARCH
specification - Q statistics for the autocorrelation function of the
squared residuals associated with the models in Tables II and III, not
reported - do not support a full period ARCH model in favor of a
structural break model. In particular based on Q(20) statistics, an ARCH
process is not found to exist in both subperiods for any one variable.
10. The correlograms for the pre and post-1970 period are
qualitatively similar and are thus not reported.
11. [Mathematical Expression Omitted], [Mathematical Expression
Omitted], [Mathematical Expression Omitted], and H [similar to] F(h, h)
where m is the number of nonzero estimated parameters (hyperparameters
plus [Mathematical Expression Omitted] and [[Lambda].sub.c]) minus one
and h is the nearest integer to (T - 4)/3 and T is the number of
observations.
12. These tests are developed in Harvey [3, 236-39, 242-46, 248-54].
The MPI test statistic is (T - 2)[1 - S([[Psi]*.sub.1])/S
([[Psi]*.sub.0])]/375.1 where S is the sum of squares of the
standardized innovations, [[Psi]*.sub.1] is the parameter set with
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] set equal to 375.1/[(T - 2).sup.2],
[[Psi]*.sub.0] is the parameter set with [Mathematical Expression
Omitted] (a deterministic trend), T is the number of observations. The
ratio of [Mathematical Expression Omitted] to [Mathematical Expression
Omitted] is chosen on the basis of Pitman efficiency. Critical values
for the test ([Alpha] = .05) are given in Harvey [3, 254].
The LR test of [Mathematical Expression Omitted] is standard with the
exception that its asymptotic distribution is equivalent to a
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] with 2[Alpha] level of significance.
The LM tests for p take the form of a weighted regression of V(j) on
elements of the vector Z where V(j) is a function of the sample spectrum
and spectral generating function (s.g.f.) for the STS model in equation
(8) with [Mathematical Expression Omitted] eliminated and Z is a vector
of partial derivatives (evaluated at the restricted parameter values) of
the s.g.f. with respect to the parameters of the model (with the
exception of [[Lambda].sub.c] - the LM test is not sensitive to
different values of [[Lambda].sub.c]). The weights are the s.g.f. The
test statistic is 1/2[TR.sup.2] where [R.sup.2] is the coefficient of
determination from the regression. [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
under [H.sub.0]. When [Rho] = 0, [Mathematical Expression Omitted] and
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] cannot be identified from one another
and [[Lambda].sub.c] is not identified. Dropping [[Epsilon].sub.t] from
the model allows [Mathematical Expression Omitted] to be identified and
using a test which is insensitive to [[Lambda].sub.c] overcomes its
under identification. Technically [Rho] = 1 violates one of the
regularity conditions and invalidates the test and results in perfect
multicollinearity in the weighted regression. To avoid this problem I
test [H.sub.0]: [Rho] = .9999. While this avoids the unit root problem
and ensures desirable large sample properties of the test, the small
sample properties may be compromised.
13. A one-tailed interval is not necessarily the appropriate
construction. Values of [Rho] [greater than] 1 are typically dismissed
as being unrealistic and thus lead to a one tail interval.
Alternatively, [Rho] [greater than] 1 could be interpreted as a sign of
misspecification implying that more complex (nonlinear) behavior may
exist. In such a situation, [Rho] = 1 - cyclical behavior from a linear
structure - should be rejected, but lacking a nested nonlinear
alternative this result can be considered to support the null
hypothesis.
14. UN exhibits minor setbacks and recoveries within the course of a
normal business cycle. This leads to an underestimation of the period of
the UN cycle. Fitting an STS model to a slightly smoothed variant of UN
m a 4 or 6 period moving average - leads to more respectable estimates
of the period (13.93 and 17.43 in the early and late periods).
The estimated cycle periods for GDP are explained by a fitted model
that breaks the long 1961-70 cycle into two shorter cycles and includes
the short 1980-82 cycle in the 1975-80 cycle (See Figure 1).
15. See previous note. The STS model for smoothed UN leads to N and H
statistics that are accepted at the .01 level of significance. The
[R.sup.2] statistics suggest that the BAA model in both periods is
problematic. The very erratic nature of the series suggests that these
models should be interpreted with caution.
16. In the late DER and early UN cases the rejection of the normality
and homoscedasticity hypotheses with only a marginal improvement in fit
imply that the untransformed models are superior.
17. In each trial, the initial conditions for the recursion in
equation (5) are taken from the first two values of [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] generated by the smoothing algorithm when applied to
the estimated models in Tables II and III. The initial values for
[Kappa] and [[Kappa].sup.*] are assumed to be zero. [[Kappa].sub.t] and
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] are generated as NID (0, [Mathematical
Expression Omitted]). [Mathematical Expression Omitted] and
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] are used for [[Lambda].sub.c] and
[Rho], except for the case where [Rho] is set to one.
18. Correlations for [Psi], MC are not reported because the
coefficients are all less than .01.
References
1. Enders, Walter. Applied Econometric Time Series. New York: John
Wiley, 1995.
2. Harvey, Andrew C., "Trends and Cycles in Macroeconomic Time
Series." Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, July 1985,
216-27.
3. -----. Forecasting, Structural Time Series Models and the Kalman
Filter. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1989.
4. Harvey, A. C. and A. Jaeger, "Detrending, Stylized Facts and
the Business Cycle." Journal of Applied Econometrics, May 1993,
231-47.
5. McCallum, Bennett T. "Unit Roots in Macroeconomic Time
Series: Some Critical Issues." NBER Working Paper No. 4368, 1993.
6. Nelson, Charles R. and Charles I. Plosser, "Trends and Random
Walks in Macroeconomic Time Series: Some Evidence and
Implications." Journal of Monetary Economics, September 1982,
139-62.
7. Simkins, Scott P., "Business Cycles, Trends, and Random Walks
in Macroeconomic Time Series." Southern Economic Journal, April
1994, 977-88.
8. Stadler, G. W., "Real Business Cycles." Journal of
Economic Literature, December 1994, 1750-83.