Purchasing power parity in high-inflation countries: a cointegration analysis of integrated variables with trend breaks.
Zhou, Su
1. Introduction
Purchasing power parity (PPP) is an important building block for
international economic modeling. The absolute version of PPP (APPP)
posits a long-run relation between the bilateral exchange rate and price
levels of two relevant countries, while relative PPP (RPPP) suggests
comovements of changes in the exchange rate with the inflation
differential of two countries. An important use of PPP is that it may
serve as a guide for monetary authorities when they intervene in the
foreign exchange market to move the exchange rate toward the level
consistent with PPP.
Recent developments in time-series analysis provide some advanced
techniques to examine the statistical behavior of economic series and to
test the existence of a long-run relationship among integrated
variables. Several recent studies have applied new econometric techniques to examine PPP. Among them, Taylor and McMahon (1988), Abuaf
and Jorion (1990), Kim (1990), Ardeni and Lubian (1991), Choudhry,
McNown, and Wallace (1991), Diebold, Husted, and Rush (1991), Glen
(1992), and Cheung and Lai (1993a) utilize the unit root tests, variance
ratio tests, and fractional differencing or fractional cointegration
analysis and find some evidence favoring PPP. Their studies are for the
1920s floating exchange rate period, for the 1950s Canadian float using
monthly or quarterly data, or for long historical periods of different
exchange-rate systems employing long low-frequency (annual) data.
However, when using monthly or quarterly data and applying univariate
unit root tests to real exchange rates or Engle-Granger (Engle and
Granger 1987) bivariate cointegration tests to exchange rates and
relative price levels, Baillie and Selover (1987), Corbae and Ouliaris
(1988), Taylor (1988), Mark (1990), Layton and Stark (1990), and Flynn
and Boucher (1993) fail to provide support for long-run PPP over the
recent floating-rate period.
In more recent studies, Cheung and Lai (1993b), Kugler and Lenz
(1993), and MacDonald (1993) utilize the multivariate cointegration
methodology proposed by Johansen (1988) and Johansen and Juselius (1990)
to test the long-run validity of PPP in a trivariate framework.(1) They
find evidence more favorable to long-run PPP during the recent
floating-rate period than the findings of other research applying the
Engle-Granger regression methodology. They demonstrate that there is a
long-run relationship between a number of bilateral exchange rates and
their corresponding relative prices, although the hypothesis of
proportionality of the exchange rate with respect to relative prices
does not receive much support from the data.
Most of the cointegration studies of PPP use the data of industrial
countries. There has been only limited effort examining the relevance of
long-run PPP for less-developed countries (LDCs). Liu (1992) employs the
cointegration analysis and long historical data (from the late 1940s to
the end of the 1980s) that encompass periods of different exchange-rate
arrangements to study PPP for some high-inflation countries of Latin
America. His findings again do not provide general support for the
proportionality hypothesis of PPP but are consistent with the hypothesis
of the existence of a long-run relationship between some bilateral
exchange rates and relevant price variables. Unfortunately, the results
from other studies for LDCs using the data of the flexible exchange-rate
period are not as favorable to PPP as those of Liu (1992). McNown and
Wallace (1989) show some evidence of cointegration between the exchange
rate and the wholesale price index (WPI) in two out of four
high-inflation countries but find no evidence of cointegration in any of
the four cases when the consumer price indices (CPIs) are employed.
Bahmani-Oskooee (1993) uses the concept of an effective exchange rate to
examine the experience of 25 LDCs, including both high-inflation and
low-inflation countries. He finds little empirical support for PPP for
most countries.
Mahdavi and Zhou (1994) notice that the time series properties of the
variables of high-inflation LDCs might be different from those of
industrial countries. After conducting the standard stationary tests for
the data of 13 countries with moderately high to very high inflation
rates over the flexible-rate period, they conclude that, for most of the
countries with very high inflation, exchange rates and price ratios,
with the U.S. as the base country, are integrated of order two, or I(2)
for short. Similar findings are also reported in Bahmani-Oskooee (1993).
Bahmani-Oskooee then considers the results that the residuals from the
cointegrating regressions of I(2) variables are integrated to a degree
less than two, even if they are still nonstationary, as the evidence
supporting PPP. Unlike Bahmani-Oskooee (1993), Mahdavi and Zhou (1994)
directly test two versions of PPP for two groups of countries using the
Johansen maximum likelihood methodology; that is, they apply the
cointegration tests to the levels of the exchange rate and price ratio
for the group of countries whose variables are found to be integrated of
order one, or I(1) for short, to test for the absolute version of PPP.
At the same time, they investigate the validity of relative PPP as a
long-term equilibrium relationship between the change in the exchange
rate and the inflation differential for another group of countries whose
exchange-rate and price-ratio series seem to be I(2). They show support
for RPPP for all countries in the second group. Yet APPP holds for only
three out of eight countries in the first group when the wholesale price
indices are used.
A question arises from the results and conclusions of Bahmani-Oskooee
(1993) and Mahdavi and Zhou (1994). If the residuals from the
cointegrating equations of I(2) variables are still nonstationary or if
the RPPP relation is stationary while the APPP relation is not, does
this imply that the APPP relation is basically nonstationary for
high-inflation countries and therefore their exchange rates and price
levels permanently wander from a stable long-run relationship? If this
is the case, the claim by Mahdavi and Zhou that PPP holds in
high-inflation countries is not well supported by their study, nor has
the hypothesis that APPP holds as a long-run equilibrium relationship in
LDCs over the flexible-rate period received much support from the
existing studies, especially when the consumer price indices are
utilized.
It has long been argued that deviations from APPP may result from a
number of factors, including transport costs and trade restrictions, the
existence of nontraded goods and services, relative price changes,
differential speeds of adjustment in the currency exchange markets and
the goods markets, as well as the problems of price-level measurement
associated with aggregation and index constructions (see Edison 1987, p.
382; Melvin 1992, pp. 124-127). That PPP often holds better for the WPI
pairs than the CPI pairs could be explained by the fact that the CPI
does not include exported goods and thus is weighted more toward
nontraded goods than is the WPI.
The effects of most of the factors listed above will be less
important in the period during which a country experiences high
inflation. It is generally believed that PPP should hold better in
high-inflation countries where the disturbances to their economies are
mostly monetary in origin and the relative price effects are shadowed by
the general price level movements (see Melvin 1992, pp. 123-124).
However, the existing studies mentioned above for the recent
flexible-rate period have not offered strong evidence favoring APPP in
less-developed, high-inflation countries. One possible reason for their
failure to support APPP is that these studies might fail to detect the
time-series properties of the variables of high-inflation countries, and
consequently they are unable to appropriately model these variables when
they conduct the tests.
For example, the issue of whether the exchange rates and price
variables of some high-inflation countries (HICs) are I(2) is not beyond
controversy. If these variables are I(2), their first differences would
be nonstationary I(1) series. To have a visual analysis, in Figure 1, we
plot the log differences of the U.S. consumer price index and the
variables of four countries that experienced very high inflation in the
last two decades. Among these countries, the exchange rates and price
variables of Brazil, Israel, and Mexico are shown in Mahdavi and Zhou
(1994) to be I(2), while the price variable of Zaire is found to be
either I(1) or I(2). The data plotted in Figure 1 are taken from the
International Financial Statistics (various issues) of the International
Monetary Fund (IMF). The exchange rates (ERs) are the end-of-the-period
market rates in terms of units of domestic currency per U.S. dollar and
the price variables (P, domestic price, or USE the U.S. price level) are
the consumer price indices.(2) Due to the availability of the data, the
sample periods for these countries are varied. When we take a close look
at these plots of the first differences of the logged variables (dlnER,
dlnP, and dlnUSP), two interesting characteristics of the data can be
seen. One is the comovement pattern of dinER and dlnP for each country
and the other is the existence of some apparent trend breaks in the
data. This is not beyond expectation because, during the sample periods,
all these HICs experienced some dramatic changes in their economies.
Naturally, one may ask the question: Are the first differences of these
variables really nonstationary I(1) series or are they actually
stationary but with some trend breaks?
Perron (1989), Christiano (1992), Banerjee, Lumsdaine, and Stock
(1992), and Zivot and Andrews (1992) point out that the standard
augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) tests (Dickey and Fuller 1981), which are
used in Bahmani-Oskooee (1993) and Mahdavi and Zhou (1994), are not
appropriate for the variables with apparent structural breaks.
Therefore, it might be incorrect to claim that the first differences of
the variables of some HICs are nonstationary (thus theft levels are
I(2)) on the basis of the results using the standard ADF tests when
there are some notable trend breaks in these variables.
In this paper, I re-examine the time-series behavior of the exchange
rates and price indices of the four high-inflation countries: Brazil,
Israel, Mexico, and Zaire, for which Bahmani-Oskooee (1993) and Mahdavi
and Zhou (1994) fail to show the existence of a stationary APPP
relation. I use the method of Zivot and Andrews (1992), which allows us
not only to examine the stationarity for the variables with a structural
break but also to test for a possible break point rather than assuming
it exists. I then conduct the cointegration tests for the long-run
validity of APPP in these high-inflation countries, based on the
findings of the Zivot-Andrews tests, and incorporate the correction of
the finite sample bias and the adjustment for trend breaks in the tests.
As far as I know, no other studies have been conducted taking the trend
breaks into account in the cointegration analysis of PPP for
high-inflation countries.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. The next section
briefly introduces the sequential ADF tests of Zivot and Andrews (1992)
and applies them to the variables I study. In section 3, I offer some
explanations for the existence of trend breaks in these variables, on
the basis of the experiences of the relevant countries. I then use
Johansen's multivariate cointegration methodology to investigate
whether the APPP condition holds in the four high-inflation countries
and report the results in section 4. The last section presents
conclusions of this study.
2. Identifying the Order of Integration for the Variables with Trend
Breaks
A time series [x.sub.t] is said to be nonstationary and integrated of
order d, denoted by [x.sub.t] [similar] I(d), if it achieves
stationarity after being differenced d times. In testing the
nonstationarity of time series, the augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) tests
(Dickey and Fuller 1981; Said and Dickey 1984) have been widely used.(3)
However, Perron (1989, 1990) shows that the existence of a structural
change in the mean of a stationary time series biases the standard ADF
tests toward nonrejection of nonstationarity. Since the variables
plotted in Figure 1 appear to have such structural changes, it seems to
be appropriate to employ the method of Zivot and Andrews (1992), called
sequential ADF tests, to investigate the nonstationarity of the
variables.
The sequential ADF tests developed by Zivot and Andrews (1992) may
not only be used to identify the order of integration for the variables
with a structural break, but also allow us to test a possible break
point rather than assuming it exists. The null hypothesis of the tests
is that the series [x.sub.t] is integrated, with the errors to be normal
ARMA(p, q) processes, without an exogenous structural break. The
alternative hypothesis is that [x.sub.t] can be represented by a
trend-stationary process with a trend break occurring at an unknown
point in time. Basically, their tests are represented by the following
augmented regression equations:
Model A: [x.sub.t] = [Mu] + [Beta]t + [Theta]D[U.sub.t] + [Alpha]
[x.sub.t-1] + [summation of] [c.sub.j][Delta][x.sub.t-j] where j=1 to k
+ [e.sub.t],
Model B: [v.sub.t] = [Alpha][v.sub.t-1] + [summation of]
[c.sub.j][Delta][v.sub.t-j] where j=1 to k + [e.sub.t],
Model C: [x.sub.t] = [Mu] + [Beta]t + [Theta]D[U.sub.t] +
[Gamma]D[T.sub.t] + [Alpha][x.sub.t-1] + [summation of]
[c.sub.j][Delta][x.sub.t-j] where j=1 to k + [e.sub.t],
where the level dummy variable D[U.sub.t] = 1 if t [greater than]
[T.sub.B] (here [T.sub.B] denotes a possible break point) and zero
otherwise. The slope dummy variable D[T.sub.t] = t - [T.sub.B] if t
[greater than] [T.sub.B] and zero otherwise. Models A and C are
estimated by one-step regressions. The estimation of Model B has a
two-step procedure, where the series v, is the residual series from a
recession of x, on a constant, a time trend, and a slope dummy variable
D[T.sub.t].(4) Note that if D[U.sub.t] is not included, Model A turns
out to be the standard ADF test with a time trend, and if both
D[U.sub.t] and the time trend are excluded, Model A becomes the standard
ADF test without a time trend.
The sequential ADF procedure estimates a regression equation for
every possible [T.sub.B] within the sample and calculates the
t-statistics for the estimated coefficients. The null of nonstationarity
is rejected in favor of the alternative of stationarity if [Alpha] is
significantly different from one. The chosen break point for each series
is that [T.sub.B] for which the t-statistic for [H.sub.0]: [Alpha] = 1
is minimized. The asymptotic critical values for these tests, which are
greater (in absolute value) than those for the standard ADF tests, are
tabulated in Zivot and Andrews (1992). Model specification (i.e., which
of models A, B, or C is appropriate) is determined by first running each
series on Model C, with the possibility of both a slope and a level
break. Model C is chosen if both dummy variables are significant. If
only the slope dummy variable is significant, Model B is estimated. If
only the level dummy variable is significant, Model A is estimated.
For either standard ADF tests or sequential ADF tests, the choice of
lag length k may affect the test results. We follow the procedure
suggested by Campbell and Perron (1991). Start with an upper bound,
[k.sub.max], on k. If the last included lag is significant, choose k =
[k.sub.max]. If not, reduce k by one until the last lag becomes
significant. We set [k.sub.max] = 8 for the quarterly data we use.
To illustrate the differences between standard ADF tests and
sequential ADF tests, we first apply the standard ADF tests to the first
(log) differences of the exchange rates and price variables, i.e., x, =
dlnER or dlnP or dlnUSP, and report the results in Table 1. the results
are similar to the findings of Mahdavi and Zhou (1994). The test
statistics fail to reject the null hypothesis of nonstationarity. If we
draw the conclusions based on these statistics, we may conclude that
dlnER, dlnP, and dlnUSP the integrated variables, while lnER, lnP, and
lnUSP are integrated of order greater than one. Due to the presence of
trend breaks in the data, such conclusions could be false.
We then apply the tests of Zivot and Andrews to dlnER, dlnP, and
dlnUSP. The results are presented in Table 2. the first four columns of
Table 2 list the countries, the variables to be tested, the number of
observations, and the chosen lag lengths. Note that Model A is selected
for dlnUSP and for dlnER and dlnP of Brazil, Mexico, and Zaire; that is,
in these cases, the slope dummy variable is found to be insignificant
while the level dummy variable is significant. Model C is selected for
the variables of Israel, i.e., both the level and the slope dummy
variables [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 1 OMITTED] are found to be
significant. The Ljung-Box Q(12) statistics, reported in column 11, are
unable to reject the null hypothesis that there is no serial correlation remaining in the residuals from the models.
The discovered dates of break points are illustrated in column 5 of
Table 2. A trend break of dlnUSP that occurred at the third quarter of
1981 may reflect the switches of the Federal Reserve's monetary
policy in the early 1980s. The discussion regarding the break points for
the HIC variables will be given in the next section. In the 10th column
of Table 2, the test statistics for the nonstationarity of variables are
reported. The results show that, when we take the structural breaks into
account in our testing, the null hypothesis of nonstationarity (i.e.,
[H.sub.0]: [Alpha] = 1) is rejected at the 5% level (or less) of
significance for all the first differences of the exchange rates and
price indices using either the asymptotic critical values of Zivot and
Andrews or the finite sample critical values listed in the last three
columns of Table 2. These finite sample critical values are obtained
through the Monte Carlo experiments under the assumption that the errors
driving the series dlnER, dlnP, and dlnUSP are normal ARMA(p, q)
processes. Following Zivot and Andrews (1992), we determine p and q by
fitting ARMA(p, q) models to the first difference of each dlnER, dlnP,
or dlnUSP (i.e., the second differences of lnER, lnP, or lnUSP) and
using the model-selection criterion of Schwarz (1978) to choose the
optimal ARMA(p, q) with p, q [less than or equal to] 5. The selected
ARMA(p, q) models are reported in Table 3. We then perform the Monte
Carlo experiment described in Zivot and Andrews (1992, p. 262) to get
the critical values for the finite-sample distributions based on 10,000
repetitions.(5) The results in Table 2 suggest that dlnER, dlnP, or
dlnUSP are stationary with some trend breaks, and therefore the levels
of the exchange rates and price variables of the four HICs and the U.S.
are unlikely to be integrated of order two. This contrasts sharply with
the results of Mahdavi and Zhou (1994) using the standard ADF tests.
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 2 OMITTED]
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 3 OMITTED]
3. Trend Breaks and the Experiences of the Relevant Countries
During the sample period, all four high-inflation countries in our
study have experienced some dramatic changes in their economies,
especially in their inflation rates. The average annual rates of
consumer price inflation of these countries have a range of 50 to 1600%
over the sample period, and the record of their highest annual inflation
ranges from 130 to 22,000% within the sample period. The governments of
these countries made various efforts to try to stabilize their
economies.
Brazil has had an inflation problem for decades, but the inflation
worsened sharply following the debt crisis between 1981 and 1985. The
Brazilian government announced its Cruzado Plan at the end of February
1986, when the inflation rate was threatening to rise above 20% a month.
The Plan centered around a general freeze of prices and the exchange
rate. However, by late 1986, the Plan became unsustainable. Price
controls were abandoned in December 1986, and inflation reached a
monthly rate of 26% in May and June of 1987. The acceleration of
inflation led the government to adopt a new stabilization plan, known as
the Bresser Plan, as an attempt to correct some of the errors of the
Cruzado Plan. This program, too, was a failure: Inflation rose rapidly
in the last quarter of 1987, and by 1988, the annual inflation rate
approached nearly hyperinflation, at about 700%, accompanied by some
sharp depreciations of the Brazilian cruzeiro. The date of the break
point that we found for Brazil, the fourth quarter of 1987, corresponds
to this period. The situation turned even worse in the late 1980s and
the 1990s.
Like Brazil, Israel had long experienced acute, chronic inflation. A
financial crisis in 1983 stimulated inflationary expectations and
sharply increased the domestic debt of the public sector, resulting in a
rapid increase in inflation and currency depreciation. On July 1, 1985,
the Israeli government enacted an ambitious heterodox stabilization
program, including a program of public expenditure cuts, mainly in
defense, and a price freeze covering mostly the prices of consumer
goods. The monetary authority also tightened the money supply and
exchange-rate control. The U.S. provided an extra $1.5 billion in aid in
1985 and 1986 on top of its regular annual handout of around $3 billion.
This took the pressure off Israel's balance of payments and made it
easier for Israel to control its exchange rate. The exchange rate played
a central role in Israel's stabilization strategy. Given the
economy's relatively small size and open character, the authorities
used the exchange rate quite deliberately to anchor the price level. The
Israeli reform appears to have been a remarkable success. The
nation's international reserve position improved and inflation has
come down since 1985. This is consistent with the break points that we
discovered for Israel at the second quarter of 1985 for the exchange
rate and the third quarter of 1985 for the price index.
From the mid-1950s to the 1970s, Mexico was a paragon of financial
stability and economic growth. The stability ended with the oil price
increase of the 1970s because of fiscal extravagance resulting from the
dramatic increase in revenue from oil exports. With added room in the
budget, policies became highly expansionary, the currency became
overvalued, and government borrowing increased. After a huge increase in
government debt followed by the collapse of the financial system and the
exchange rate, Mexico became insolvent in 1982, the first of the debtor countries to do so. Since 1987, when consumer price inflation reached
nearly 160%, the top priority for the Mexican government had been
reducing inflation. In December 1987, the Economic Solidarity Pact was
announced. The Pact combined strict fiscal and monetary policies, wage
and price controls, and an exchange-rate policy that allowed the peso to
significantly appreciate in real terms against the dollar. The Pact and
its successor, the Pact for Stability and Economic Growth, had succeeded
in reducing inflation. Consumer price inflation was brought down to 10%
in the second quarter of 1988, following a real appreciation of the
peso. Correspondingly, the dates of break points for the Mexican
exchange rate and price index are found to be the fourth quarter of 1987
and the first quarter of 1988, respectively.
The IMF and the World Bank supported Zaire with at least five
stabilization programs between 1976 and 1987, but the custom for Zaire
quickly became to make the first drawing of the loans from the IMF or
the World Bank and then to drift away from the economic reform
performance criteria. In January 1989, the government once more took
steps to establish economic stability. A structural adjustment program,
including the commitment to contain budget deficits, narrowed the gap
between the official and black-market exchange rate to 10% by April
1989. Despite the country's reform efforts, the pace of economic
activity had not accelerated sufficiently in 1989 to boost living
standards, which had fallen each year for more than a decade.
Inefficient and corruptly managed parastatals (semiautonomous,
quasi-governmental, state-owned enterprises) had contributed to
Zaire's troubled economic history and were a severe strain on the
budget. By the end of 1989, it was apparent that the latest reforms were
unsuccessful in promoting sustained economic expansion. Instead,
Zairians experienced a massive drop in per capita income as inflation
rose and the GDP growth rate fell. Economic indicators for 1990 were
even more dismal. IMF credits had expired, and large public-expenditure
deficits were expected in order to fund pay increases for government
workers. The figures for 1991, in which a break point was disclosed at
the second quarter, showed a GDP decline of 2.6%, a 2000% rate of
consumer price inflation, and further devaluation of the zaire against
Western currencies. By 1992 and continuing into 1993, poverty and
unemployment were widespread and hyperinflation was a permanent fixture.
From the above discussions, we see that the dates of the break points
in the data exposed by the sequential ADF tests of Zivot and Andrews are
generally consistent with the true experiences of these countries. This
illustrates the strong power of the tests. Hence, further effort to
detect the trend breaks in the variables seems unnecessary.
4. Testing for the Volatility of Long-Run PPP in High-Inflation
Countries
PPP between the exchange rate and relative prices, with the U.S. as
the base country, could be expressed as the following empirical
relationship:
[[Beta].sub.er]ln[ER.sub.t] + [[Beta].sub.p]ln[P.sub.t] +
[[Beta].sub.usp]ln[USP.sub.t] = [[Xi].sub.t],
where lnER, lnP, and lnUSP are the logs of the exchange rate,
domestic price level, and the U.S. price level, respectively (as defined
earlier), and [Xi] is an error term reflecting deviations from PPP. When
the exchange rate and price levels are integrated variables, for PPP to
hold in the long run, [[Xi].sub.t] should be stationary. Strictly
speaking, the PPP condition requires - [[Beta].sub.er] = [[Beta].sub.p]
= -[[Beta].sub.esp] or [[[Beta].sub.er], [[Beta].sub.p],
[[Beta].sub.usp]] = [-1, 1, -1] when [[Beta].sub.er] is normalized to be
-1, i.e., the long-run proportionality between exchange rates and price
levels. However, as argued by Edison (1987) and Taylor (1988),
transportation costs and measurement error, as well as the existence of
nontradable elements in measured price indices, may imply that
[[Beta].sub.er], [[Beta].sub.p], and [[Beta].sub.usp] are not equal to
unity. Therefore, we refer to the situation where [[Xi].sub.t] is
stationary and the condition [[[Beta].sub.er], [[Beta].sub.p],
[[Beta].sub.usp]] = [-1, 1, -1] is satisfied as strong-form PPP.
Weak-form PPP requires a stationary [[Xi].sub.t], but the
proportionality condition does not necessarily hold.
Cointegration analysis offers a natural way to test the existence of
a long-run relationship among integrated variables. A set of I(d)
variables, [X.sub.t], is said to be cointegrated if a linear combination
of them, [Z.sub.t] = [Beta][prime][X.sub.t], is integrated of any order
less than d. The vector [Beta] is referred to as the cointegrating
vector. If [Z.sub.t] is found to be integrated of order zero (i.e.,
stationary), we may say that the variables in [X.sub.t] do not drift too
far apart and there exists a long-run equilibrium relationship among
these variables.
Johansen's multivariate cointegration tests (Johansen 1988,
1992; Johansen and Juselius 1990) are utilized in this paper to test the
long-run PPP relation between four high-inflation countries and the U.S.
Since in section 2 the first differences of ln[ER.sub.t] ln[P.sub.t],
and ln[USP.sub.t] are shown to be stationary with some trend breaks, we
may directly apply the cointegration tests to the levels of the
variables rather than to their first differences. The tests are
conducted through a vector error-correction mechanism with the null
hypothesis of no cointegration. Defining a vector [X.sub.t] containing
three variables, [X[prime].sub.t] = [ln[ER.sub.t], ln[P.sub.t],
ln[USP.sub.t]], a vector error-correction model can be written as
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], (4.1)
where [[Epsilon].sub.t] is a vector of independent Gaussian variables
with mean zero and variance matrix [Sigma]. [Mathematical Expression
Omitted] is a constant term that implies that the process [X.sub.t] has
a linear trend. The model including [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
allows for the possibility of quadratic trends in [X.sub.t] (see
Osterwald-Lenum, 1992, p. 471). The vector [D.sub.t] usually contains
deterministic variables such as some dummies or other variables outside
the cointegration space. They are included in the model to ensure that
the disturbances [[Sigma].sub.t] "are as close to being Gaussian as
possible" (Pesaran and Pesaran, 1991, p. 85). The hypotheses of
interest involve II; if the rank of II is r, where r [less than or equal
to] 2, then II can be decomposed into two 3 X r matrices [Alpha] and
[Beta] such that II = [Alpha][Beta][prime]. The matrix [Beta] consists
of r linear, cointegrating vectors, while [Alpha] can be interpreted as
a matrix of vector error-correction parameters. The Johansen method
offers the test for the number of cointegrating vectors and gives
consistent maximum likelihood estimates of the entire cointegrating
matrix. For each country pair, the number of cointegrating vectors is
determined using the maximum eigenvalue test statistic or
[[Lambda].sub.max].(6) If the results are consistent with the hypothesis
of at least one cointegrating vector, the hypotheses regarding the
relationship of the cointegrating coefficients [Beta][prime] could be
tested using the maximum likelihood methodology.
Asymptotic critical values for the maximum eigenvalue test are
tabulated in Osterwald-Lenum (1992). However, when the sample length is
not long, the tests based on asymptotic critical values may be biased
toward finding cointegration too often. Cheung and Lai (1993c) examine
the finite sample properties of the Johansen tests and provide finite
sample critical values for the case assuming there is no linear trend
nor quadratic trend in the data generating processes (DGPs) but allowing
the constant term [Mathematical Expression Omitted] in the models of
estimation.
Since in Table 2 we found a significant time trend in the first
differences of the logged exchange rates and price indices of Brazil,
Israel, and Mexico, we assume that the DGPs of lnER and lnP of these
three countries have a quadratic trend, i.e.,
[X.sub.t] = [X.sub.t-1] + [[Mu].sub.0] + [[Mu].sub.1]t +
[[Epsilon].sub.t], (4.2)
which is equivalent to [Delta][X.sub.t] = [[Mu].sub.0] +
[[Mu].sub.1]t + [[Epsilon].sub.t], with [[Epsilon].sub.t] being defined
earlier for Equation 4.1, and include both a constant term and a time
trend in the models for testing PPP. For Zaire, the coefficients of the
time trend are found to be insignificant in its dlnER and dlnP;
therefore, the DGPs of lnER and lnP of Zaire are assumed to have a
linear trend, i.e.,
[X.sub.t] = [X.sub.t-1] + [[Mu].sub.0] + [[Epsilon].sub.t], (4.3)
which is equivalent to [Delta][X.sub.t] = [[Mu].sub.0] +
[[Epsilon].sub.t], and only a constant term is included in the models
for testing the PPP relation between Zaire and the U.S. Based on the
above assumptions, we use the methods suggested by Cheung and Lai
(1993c) to perform the Monte Carlo experiment and produce the finite
sample critical values, reported in Table 4, for the Johansen tests.
Testing for Cointegration
The results of the cointegration tests without accounting for the
effects of trend breaks (i.e, including no [D.sub.t] in Eqn. 4.1) are
presented in Table 4. The reported lag lengths k are chosen on the basis
of the Bayesian information criterion (BIC) (Schwarz 1978) as well as
the criterion that the residuals from the model are not serially
correlated; that is, among the models where the Ljung-Box Q(12)
statistics are found to be smaller than their 5% critical values, k is
chosen corresponding to the one with the lowest BIC statistic. We set
[k.sub.max] = 8.
For the models expressed by Equation 4.1 and the DGPs assumed to be
Equation 4.2, the [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 4 OMITTED] finite-sample
distribution of the [[Lambda].sub.max] test statistic is invariant with
respect to the value of the drift [[Mu].sub.0], but is variant with the
value of [[Mu].sub.1] in Equation 4.2. If there is no time trend in the
model (i.e., [Mathematical Expression Omitted] in Eqn. 4.1) and the
assumed DGPs are expressed by Equation 4.3, the distribution of the
[[Lambda].sub.max] test statistic would be variant with the value of
[[Mu].sub.0] in Equation 4.3. Therefore, there are two sets of finite
sample critical values listed in Table 4 for each country pair. For
Brazil/U.S., Israel/U.S., and Mexico/U.S., the first set of critical
values is obtained assuming [[Mu].sub.1] = 1, and the second set of
critical values is produced by setting [[Mu].sub.1] in the DGPs equal to
the coefficients of the time trend for dinER, dlnP, and dlnUSP,
displayed in Table 2. In the case of Zaire/U.S., the first and second
set of critical values are corresponding to [[Mu].sub.0] = 1 and
[[Mu].sub.0] equal to the coefficients of the constant term for dinER,
dlnP, and dlnUSP in Table 2, respectively. Although the assumed
[[Mu].sub.0] and [[Mu].sub.1] might not be good proxies for the true
[[Mu].sub.0] and [[Mu].sub.1], the two sets of the critical values
indicate that, when [[Mu].sub.0] or [[Mu].sub.1] vary from one to the
values close to zero, the critical values are not much affected.
Comparing the [[Lambda].sub.max] test statistics for the null of no
cointegration ([H.sub.0]: r = 0) with the finite sample critical values,
the null hypothesis could be rejected only for Israel/U.S. There is no
supportive evidence for PPP for the other three country pairs. For the
Israel/U.S. pair, where one cointegrating vector is found, we conduct
some tests for the hypotheses on the cointegrating vector applying the
procedures of Johansen and Juselius (1990, 1992). The tests are
basically the likelihood ratio tests constructed from the estimated
eigenvalues corresponding to the restricted and unrestricted models.
For the hypothesis of proportionality, discussed earlier in section
4, the likelihood ratio test statistics reject the null of
[[[Beta].sub.er], [[Beta].sub.p], [[Beta].sub.usp]] = [-1, 1, -1] but
fail to reject the null of -[[Beta].sub.er] = [[Beta].sub.p], (i.e.,
[[Beta].sub.er] + [[Beta].sub.p] = 0). The results suggest the existence
of a proportional relationship in the long run between the exchange rate
and the price level of Israel.
Testing for Cointegration with Adjustment for Trend Breaks
Without taking the effects of trend breaks into consideration, the
cointegration tests described in the above subsection provide little
support for PPP in high-inflation countries. Cheung et al. (1995) argue
that the existence of trend breaks in the stochastic processes may bias
the cointegration test toward finding no cointegration too often if one
fails to model the breaks when performing the test. When one includes
some dummy variables in the model to capture the effects of trend
breaks, the distributions of the test statistics would be different from
those for the variables with no trend breaks.
Following Cheung et al. (1995), we set the null hypothesis of the
tests to be no cointegration, while the alternative is that the
variables are cointegrated with some trend breaks in the data. Hence, we
allow [D.sub.t] in Equation 4.1 to include the dummy variables, the
slope and/or the level dummies, representing the structural breaks
revealed in section 2.(7) They are: (i) [DU.sub.t](81: 3) and
[DU.sub.t](87:4) for the Brazil/U.S. pair; (ii) [DU.sub.t](81:3),
[DU.sub.t](85:2), [DT.sub.t](85:2), and [DU.sub.t](85:3) for
Israel/U.S.; (iii) [DU.sub.t](81:3), [DU.sub.t](87:4), and
[DU.sub.t](88:1) for Mexico/U.S.; and (iv) [DU.sub.t](81:3) and
[DU.sub.t](91:2) for Zaire/U.S.(8) Correspondingly, the finite sample
critical values for the Johansen cointegration tests in the presence of
trend breaks are simulated through the Monte Carlo experiment.(9) Again,
there are two sets of finite-sample critical values displayed in Table 5
for the reasons stated in the above subsection.
The results of cointegration tests with adjustment for trend breaks
are summarized in Table 5. They provide more positive evidence for
cointegration than those presented in Table 4. In all four cases, the
hypothesis of no cointegration can be rejected at the 5% level of
significance, indicating that weak-form PPP holds in these
high-inflation countries.
When testing the hypothesis of proportionality, i.e., [H.sub.0]:
[[[Beta].sub.er], [[Beta].sub.p], [[Beta].sub.usp]] = [-1, 1, -1], the
likelihood ratio test statistics fail to reject this hypothesis for
Israel/U.S. and Mexico/U.S. but reject it for Brazil/U.S. and Zaire/U.S.
Furthermore, the test results fail to reject the null of
-[[Beta].sub.er] = [[Beta].sub.p] (i.e., [[Beta].sub.er] +
[[Beta].sub.p] = 0) for three out of four cases. The above findings
generally support weak-form PPP in high-inflation countries for all the
countries in the study. There is also some evidence in favor of
strong-form PPP for two out of four cases.(10)
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 5 OMITTED]
5. Summary and Conclusions
With the development of cointegration techniques, the long-run
validity of purchasing power parity has received more favorable evidence
for industrial countries. However, although the PPP theory suggests that
PPP is likely to hold well in high-inflation countries, the absolute
version of PPP has not obtained much support from the existing studies
of the less-developed high-inflation countries for the recent flexible
exchange-rate period. The results are particularly unfavorable to PPP
for these countries when the consumer price indices are utilized. One
possibility is that the existing studies have not modeled the variables
of HICs appropriately, as some of them claim that the first differences
of the exchange rates and price variables of HICs are nonstationary and
thus their levels are integrated of order two.
In this study, I use the method of Zivot and Andrews (1992) to
re-examine the time series behavior of the exchange rates and consumer
price indices of four high-inflation countries. I uncover that the first
differences of these variables are stationary with some trend breaks.
With the aid of the Zivot-Andrews tests, I figure out the dates of break
points and find that they are consistent with the substantial changes
that occurred in these economies. I then employ these data to conduct
the cointegration analysis for the long-run validity of APPP in
high-inflation countries and include the revealed structural breaks in
our analysis.
The results from the Johansen cointegration tests with adjustment for
trend breaks show the existence of a cointegrating relationship among
the bilateral exchange rate, the U.S. price level, and the
high-inflation country price variable for all four country pairs in this
study. In addition, there is some evidence in favor of the hypothesis of
proportionality (i.e., strong-form PPP) for a couple of cases. This
study provides support for the argument that PPP holds well, at least in
a weak form, in high-inflation countries where the general price level
movement overshadows the factors causing deviations from PPP.
The author would like to thank Dennis Hoffman, Michael Melvin, and
Yin-Wong Cheung for helpful comments and suggestions on this study.
Financial support provided by a summer research grant from the College
of Business of the University of Texas at San Antonio is gratefully
acknowledged. The usual caveat applies.
1 Johansen and Juselius (1992) test the PPP relation and the
uncovered interest parity (UIP) relation for the United Kingdom in a
five-dimensional system of equations (two prices, exchange rate, and two
interest rates). Their results reject the hypothesis that the PPP
relation is stationary by itself, but they are consistent with the
hypothesis of a stationary PPP relation with a combination of the two
interest rates.
2 I employ the CPI data rather than the WPIs for the following
reasons: (i) In so doing, we may offer a valid comparison of our results
to those of Mark (1990), Kugler and Lenz (1993), and others who use the
CPIs in their studies of PPP for industrial countries. (ii) It would be
interesting to see if my results are more favorable to APPP than the
findings of other studies on high-inflation countries, which often fail
to support APPP when the CPI data are utilized. (iii) The WPI data are
not available for Zaire.
3 Because the ADF tests are well known, the descriptions of the tests
are omitted here.
4 Perron and Vogelsang (1991) give an explanation of why Model B is
estimated differently from Models A and C.
5 The results of the Monte Carlo experiments here for the sequential
ADF tests and later for the cointegration tests are obtained through
10,000 replications using the GAUSS programming language.
6 Johansen (1988) also proposes another likelihood ratio test known
as the trace test for determining the number of cointegrating
relationships. Of these two tests, however, the maximum eigenvalue test
is expected to provide more clear cut results than the trace test
(Johansen and Juselius 1990).
7 It is worthwhile to point out that we do not add additional dummies
like (0 0 ... 0 1 0 ... 0) into the model to capture some one-period
jumps in the data of the exchange rates. As can be seen in Figure 1,
these jumps often reflect the catch-ups of the exchange rates under the
pressure of persistent inflation. They should be considered to be
consistent with PPP. If we use some one-period dummies to capture these
jumps in the exchange rates, it may distort the true PPP relation.
Readers may argue that the trend breaks in the data may also reflect the
PPP relation. Note that the trend breaks we discovered appear in both
exchange rates and price variables. If we appropriately model these
breaks, it would not cause distortion of the PPP relation. On the other
hand, if we neglect these trend breaks as McNown and Wallace (1989),
Bahmani-Oskooee (1993), and Mahdavi and Zhou (1994) did, the standard
ADF tests would falsely evidence that the variables of high-inflation
countries are I(2), and the cointegration tests would be unable to
support the absolute version of PPP when it may actually hold.
8 Note that we are unable to add both [DT.sub.t](85:2) and
[DT.sub.t](85:3) dummies into the model for the Israel/U.S. pair. If we
do so, we would receive an error message for the problem of serious
multicollinearity. For this reason, only one of the two slope dummies is
included.
9 The author is grateful to Yin-Wong Cheung for his valuable
suggestions and guidance in conducting these Monte Carlo experiments.
10 The results obtained using break dummies have to be interpreted
with caution. As mentioned in Cheung et al. (1995, p. 185), while the
existence of trend breaks may bias empirical tests, "using dummy
variables to capture them creates another problem." These breaks
may not be fully exogenous, and the dummy variables for these breaks may
capture nonstationarity in the data. In addition, the presence of trend
breaks may affect the distributions of the test statistics for the
hypothesis of proportionality. This second problem would not affect the
conclusions regarding weak-form PPP, but may have effects on the tests
for strong-form PPP. We will address this problem in a succeeding study.
References
Abuaf, Niso, and Philippe Jorion. 1990. Purchasing power parity in
the long run. Journal of Finance 45:157-74.
Ardeni, Pier G., and Diego Lubian. 1991. Is there trend reversion in
purchasing power parity? European Economic Review 35:1035-55.
Bahmani-Oskooee, Mohsen. 1993. Purchasing power parity based on
effective exchange rate and cointegration: 25 LDCs' experience with
its absolute formulation. World Development 21:1023-31.
Baillie, Richard T, and David Selover. 1987. Cointegration and model
of exchange rate determination. International Journal of Forecasting
3:43-51.
Banerjee, Anindya, Robin L. Lumsdaine, and James H. Stock. 1992.
Recursive and sequential tests of the unit-root and trend-break
hypotheses: Theory and international evidence. Journal of Business &
Economic Statistics 10:271-87.
Campbell, John Y., and Pierre Perron. 1991. Pitfalls and
opportunities: What macroeconomists should know about unit roots. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 6:141-201.
Cheung, Yin-Wong, and Kon S. Lai. 1993a. A fractional cointegration
analysis of purchasing power parity. Journal of Business & Economic
Statistics 11:103-12.
Cheung, Yin-Wong, and Kon S. Lai. 1993b. Long-run purchasing power
parity during the recent float. Journal of International Economics
34:181-92.
Cheung, Yin-Wong, and Kon S. Lai. 1993c. Finite-sample sizes of
Johansen's likelihood ratio tests for cointegration. Oxford
Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 55:313-28.
Cheung, Yin-Wong, Hung-Gay Fung, Kon S. Lai, and Wai-Chung Lo. 1995.
Purchasing power parity under the European monetary system. Journal of
International Money and Finance 14:179-89.
Choudhry, Taufig, Robert McNown, and Myles Wallace. 1991. Purchasing
power parity and Canadian float in the 1950s. Review of Economics and
Statistics 70:558-63.
Christiano, Lawrence J. 1992. Searching for a break in GNP. Journal
of Business & Economic Statistics 10:237-50.
Corbae, Dean, and Sam Ouliaris. 1988. Cointegration and tests of
purchasing power parity. Review of Economics and Statistics 70:508-11.
Dickey, David A., and Wayne A. Fuller. 1981. The likelihood ratio
statistics for autoregressive time series with a unit root. Econometrica
49:1057-72.
Diebold, Francis X., Steven Husted, and Mark Rush. 1991. Real
exchange rates under the gold standard. Journal of Political Economy
99:1252-71.
Edison, Hali J. 1987. Purchasing power parity in the long run: A test
of the dollar/pound exchange rate (1890-1978). Journal of Money, Credit,
and Banking 19:376-87.
Engle, Robert E, and Clive W. J. Granger. 1987. Co-integration and
error correction: Representation, estimation and testing. Econometrica
55:251-76.
Flynn, N. Alston, and Janice L. Boucher. 1993. Testing of long-run
purchasing power parity using alternative methodologies. Journal of
Macroeconomics 15:109-22.
Fuller, Wayne A. 1976. Introduction to statistical time series. New
York: John Wiley.
Glen, Jack D. 1992. Real exchange rates in the short, medium and long
run: New evidence from variance ratio tests. Journal of International
Economics 33:147-66.
Johansen, Soren. 1988. Statistical analysis of cointegration vectors.
Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 12: 231-54.
Johansen, Soren. 1992. Determination of cointegration rank in the
presence of a linear trend. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics
54:383-97.
Johansen, Soren, and Katarina Juselius. 1990. Maximum likelihood
estimation and inference on cointegration - With applications to the
demand for money. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics
52:169-210.
Johansen, Soren, and Katarina Juselius. 1992. Testing structural
hypotheses in a multivariate cointegration analysis of PPP and the UIP
for UK. Journal of Econometrics 53:211-44.
Kim, Yoonbai. 1990. Purchasing power parity in the long run: A
cointegration approach. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking
22:491-503.
Kugler, Peter, and Carlos Lenz. 1993. Multivariate cointegration
analysis and the long-run validity of PPP. Review of Economics and
Statistics 75:180-4.
Layton, Allen P., and Jonathan P. Stark. 1990. Co-integration as an
empirical test of purchasing power parity. Journal of Macroeconomics
12:125-36.
Liu, Peter C. 1992. Purchasing power parity in Latin America: A
co-integration analysis. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 128:662-80.
MacDonald, Ronald. 1993. Long-run purchasing power parity: Is it for
real? Review of Economics and Statistics 75: 690-5.
Mahdavi, Saeid, and Su Zhou. 1994. Purchasing power parity in
high-inflation countries: Further evidence. Journal of Macroeconomics
16:403-22.
Mark, Nelson C. 1990. Real and nominal exchange rates in the long
run: An empirical investigation. Journal of International Economics
28:115-36.
McNown, Robert, and Myles S. Wallace. 1989. National price levels,
purchasing power parity, and cointegration: A test of four high
inflation economies. Journal of International Money and Finance
8:533-45.
Melvin, Michael. 1992. International money and finance. 3rd edition.
New York: Harper Collins.
Osterwald-Lenum, Michael. 1992. A note with quantiles of the
asymptotic distribution of the maximum likelihood cointegration rank
test. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 54:461-71.
Perron, Pierre. 1989. The Great Crash, the oil shock and the unit
root hypothesis. Econometrica 57:1361-401.
Perron, Pierre. 1990. Testing for a unit root in a time series with a
changing mean. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 8:153-62.
Perron, Pierre, and Timothy J. Vogelsang. 1991. The Great Crash, the
oil shock and the unit root hypothesis: Corrections and extensions of
some asymptotic results. Unpublished paper, Princeton University.
Pesaran, M. Hashem, and Bahram Pesaran. 1991. Microfit 3.0: An
interactive econometric software package user manual. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Said, Said E., and David A. Dickey. 1984. Testing for unit roots in
autoregressive moving average models of unknown order. Biometrika
71:599-607.
Schwarz, William G. 1978. Estimating the dimension of a model. Annals of Statistics 6:451-4.
Taylor, Mark P. 1988. An empirical examination of long run purchasing
power parity using cointegration techniques. Applied Economics
20:1369-81.
Taylor, Mark P., and Patrick C. McMahon. 1988. Long-run purchasing
power parity in the 1920s. European Economic Review 32:179-97.
Zivot, Eric, and Donald W. K. Andrews. 1992. Further evidence on the
Great Crash, the oil-price shock, and the unit-root hypothesis. Journal
of Business & Economic Statistics 10:251-70.