The effects of import quotas on national welfare: comment.
Tower, Edward
1. Introduction
Recently in this journal, Palivos and Yip (1997a) married real and
monetary analysis to provide an intriguing new argument for protection.
Is this an idea that international agencies like the World Trade
Organization and the World Bank should educate their member countries
about?
The authors consider an economy with differential cash-in-advance
constraints, fiat money, and no interest payments on cash. They argue
that the first-best policy in such an economy is differential
consumption taxes and, if the exportable is cash intensive, a
second-best policy is an import quota. In this Comment, we argue that
paying interest on cash (or equivalently deflating the economy) is
better than differential taxation because it is administratively simpler
and cheaper; for variants of the model, it is welfare superior, and less
susceptible to manipulation by rent seekers.
This issue is most relevant for high-inflation economies, for they
have the highest interest rates and hence the highest opportunity costs of holding money. Such economies are typically developing.
2. The Palivos-Yip Argument
Here is a simple exposition of the Palivos-Yip argument. Consider a
hypothetical small economy, which we will call Ghana. It imports wheat
and exports cocoa. It produces and consumes both goods. At time T, its
producer prices measured in local currency (cedis) are [P.sub.w] and
[P.sub.c], respectively. There are no explicit taxes, so these are also
nominal prices paid by consumers. To consume a unit of cocoa at time T,
our consumer must acquire the purchase price in non-interest-bearing
cash at time T - [Phi] and hold it for [Phi] periods. Thus, the present
value at time T of the cost of consuming a unit of cocoa at time T is
[P.sub.c][e.sup.i[Phi]], where i is the nominal interest rate on other
securities. There is no cash-in-advance requirement for consuming wheat,
so the present value at time T of the cost of consuming a unit of wheat
at time T is just the purchase price [P.sub.w]. The relative price of
cocoa to consumers is [P.sub.c][e.sup.i[Phi]]/[P.sub.w] [approximately
equal to] [1 + i[Phi]][P.sub.c]/[P.sub.w]. Since [P.sub.c]/[P.sub.w] is
the relative producer price of cocoa, consumers pay an implicit ad
valorem tax of i[Phi] on cocoa. Since there is no social opportunity
cost associated with money creation, this tax is inefficient. It could
be offset with an explicit tax on wheat consumption or subsidy on cocoa
consumption. Alternatively, it could be offset by taxes on international
trade, but this would distort production decisions so, as the authors
note elsewhere (Palivos and Yip 1997b), trade intervention is inferior
to differential consumption taxes.(1)
3. Paying Interest on Money
An alternative solution emphasized by Friedman (1959, 1969) is to pay
interest on money. If money bears the same interest rate that securities
do, then there is no implicit tax on cocoa, and consumption is
optimized. Equivalently, as Friedman points out and the authors note
elsewhere (Palivos and Yip 1997b), the economy could be deflated at the
real rate of interest, so the money interest rate falls to zero, and
there is no need to pay interest on money.
How do the various policies compare? In this model, it makes no
difference whether wheat consumption bears a tax or cedis carry
interest. However, in more general models, for several reasons, payment
of the optimum interest rate on cash will be superior:
(i) Taxes or subsidies to consumption or trade evoke attempts to
trick the authorities through tax evasion, smuggling, or falsification of invoices. These activities and official efforts to combat them
squander resources.
(ii) If our representative citizen must work to obtain goods, a
consumption tax on goods will cause him to superoptimally economize on
money and substitute leisure for goods.
(iii) Suppose I live closer to a bank than you do, so I hold cash for
a shorter period before each purchase than you do. In this case, we have
different cash-in-advance requirements and different consumption taxes
should be levied on the two of us. But if interest is paid on cash,
resource allocation is optimized with one interest rate for all.
(iv) Suppose our representative citizen can economize on money
balances by transforming leisure into transactions services, so the
cash-in-advance constraint [Phi] is endogenous. He will choose a
suboptimal quantity of money unless it pays the appropriate interest.
(v) Suppose that producers are subject to differential
cash-in-advance requirements on their intermediate inputs. Then if their
proportions are variable, they too should be subject to differential
rates of taxation on their intermediate inputs and, even if they use
intermediate inputs in fixed proportions, they should be subject to
differential rates of taxation on output. If exporters are subject to
differential cash-in-advance requirements on their exports, differential
rates of taxation on exports are required. However, one interest rate on
cash would fix the problem.
These arguments convince us that any combination of taxes or
subsidies on consumption, production, and trade is less than first best
and is likely in practice to waste resources on the calculation and
recalculation of second-best (or conceivably first best) optima as
technology, endowments, and tastes change. Paying interest on money
means the first best is achievable and that economists who specialize in
calculating second-best optima can be reemployed elsewhere.
Finally, since the calculation of any optimum tax/subsidy scheme will
be complex, in practice such schemes invite rent seeking in the
legislative process.
4. Currency Boards and the Gold Standard
Suppose our analysis is of a country with a currency that is backed
100% by foreign securities that pay interest rate f.(2) In this case,
holding each unit of domestic currency creates currency board revenue at
a rate of f. For optimality, this interest rate f should be paid on
currency. If the currency board holds only gold and the currency is
pegged to gold, since gold pays no interest, the currency should pay no
interest either.
5. Shadow Prices and Immiserizing Growth
Once the proper interest rate is paid on money so there are no
distortions, shadow prices become market prices. This means that project
evaluation can be carried out by just looking at market prices. This
simplifies the process of project evaluation. Moreover, the paradoxes of
immiserizing growth disappear.(3)
6. Financial Repression and the Argument for Protection
Developing economies frequently exhibit high rates of inflation so
their governments can collect the inflation tax. McKinnon (1973) notes
that, to the extent that cash holdings and deposits serve as a vehicle
for turning savings into investment, reduced real interest payments on
money and deposits implicitly tax investment.(4) To keep the demand for
domestic currency high, these same countries typically restrict
permissible holdings of foreign securities, discourage the development
of domestic securities markets, impose high reserve requirements on the
banking system (with no interest payments on reserves), and require
advance deposits of domestic currency prior to importing (with no
interest rate paid on these deposits). These are all elements of
financial repression, which shrinks welfare and economic growth. Our
prototype is, in effect, an economy where the cash-in-advance
requirement for imports is high and cash held prior to importing bears a
zero nominal interest rate, the cash held (as deposits) prior to
domestic market purchases bears a positive nominal but negative real
interest rate, and the cash held as currency prior to domestic market
purchases bears a zero nominal interest rate. In such an economy,
reducing the repression of financial and international markets through
lower inflation, freer trade, and sensible consumption and/or factor
taxes is especially desirable.(5)
Appendix: Technical Notes on the Palivos-Yip Models
The expression for the tariff equivalent of the optimum quota in
Palivos and Yip (1997a) does not depend on the interest rate. Thus, it
appears that the distortion that drives the need for a trade or tax
intervention in Palivos and Yip (1997a) is something other than the gap
between the interest rates on money and alternative assets.
In fact, there is no conflict between the logic of this comment and
Palivos and Yip (1997a). The mathematics in Palivos and Yip (1997a)
implicitly assumes an interest rate of 100%.(6) For clarity, we
reproduce the mathematics of Palivos and Yip (1997a) with the interest
rate explicit.
There is non-interest-bearing fiat money. The money stock is
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. The monetary authority lends money
out, earning an interest rate i. It distributes this seignorage as a
lump sum to each agent at the end of his single period of life. At the
same time, the agent earns income [p.sub.1][X.sub.1] +
[p.sub.2][X.sub.2] and receives the lump sum distribution of tariff
revenue earned S. This is balanced by the individual's expenditure
at the end of his life: [p.sub.1][D.sub.1] + [p.sub.2][D.sub.2] plus the
interest the individual must pay at the end of his life in order to
acquire money balances M at the beginning of the period in order to
satisfy his cash-in-advance constraint. Thus, our agent's budget
constraint is
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
which is identical to Equation 2 in Palivos and Yip (1997a) except
that the coefficients of 1 on M and [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
have been replaced by i. The rest of the analysis in Palivos and Yip
(1997a) stays intact. However, the [Gamma] in Palivos and Yip's
Equation 8 is now defined as i[[[Phi].sub.2] - [[Phi].sub.1]]/[1 +
[[Phi].sub.1]i]. In the limit as i (the excess of the interest rate on
assets alternative to money) above that on money approaches zero, the
need for a quota or commodity tax disappears.
What is the relationship between the results in Palivos and Yip
(1997a) and Palivos and Yip (1997b)? In Palivos and Yip (1997a, Equation
15), the authors (after removal of an extraneous [p.sup.*] from the
right-hand side) provide an expression for the tariff equivalent of the
optimum import quota. In Palivos and Yip (1997b, Equation 29), they
provide an expression for the optimum import tariff in a "dynamic
generalized cash-in-advance model." Using the modified definition
of [Gamma] and recognizing that [Gamma] [equivalent to] [Delta],
[Epsilon] [equivalent to] [Alpha][e.sup.d], and [Sigma] [equivalent to]
([Alpha] - 1)[e.sup.s], the expression for the tariff equivalent of the
optimum quota in Palivos and Yip (1997a) is identical to the expression
for the optimum import tariff in Palivos and Yip (1997b). This equality
is to be expected in a competitive environment for certain classes of
model.
1 Of course, if wheat is the cash-intensive commodity and trade
intervention is the policymaker's only option, a subsidy to trade
is the appropriate policy.
2 For an argument for 100% reserve requirements, see Friedman (1959).
3 For an intuitive discussion of shadow pricing and project
evaluation, see Tower (1991). Incidently, like Alam (1981) and Palivos
and Yip, Bhagwati and Srinivasan (1981) recognize that, in the presence
of a quota, growth does not immiserize.
4 For discussion of financial repression, also see World Bank (1989).
5 None of these conclusions are altered when we consider an optimal
tax framework. Dixit (1985) points out that, in an optimal tax
framework, only those items that enter the utility function directly
should be taxed. Thus, in such a framework, money, production, and trade
should all be kept free of tax. Also see Kimbrough (1986).
6 T. Palivos suggested this interpretation to us.
References
Alam, Shahid. 1981. Welfare implications of growth under quotas.
Economics Letters 8:177-80.
Bhagwati, Jagdish N., and T. N. Srinivasan. 1981. The evaluation of
projects at world prices under trade distortions: Quantitative
restrictions, monopoly power in trade and nontraded goods. International
Economic Review 22: 385-99.
Dixit, Avanish. 1985. Tax policy in open economies. In Handbook of
public economics, volume 1, edited by Alan Auerbach and Martin
Feldstein. Amsterdam: North Holland, pp. 313-74.
Friedman, Milton. 1959. A program for monetary stability. New York:
Columbia University Press.
Friedman, Milton. 1969. The optimum quantity of money and other
essays. Chicago: Aldine.
Kimbrough, Kent. 1986. The optimum quantity of money role in the
theory of public finance. Journal of Monetary Economics 18:277-84.
McKinnon, Ronald I. 1973. Money and capital in economic development.
Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution.
Palivos, Theodore, and Chong K. Yip. 1997a. The effects of import
quotas on national welfare: Does money matter? Southern Economic Journal
63:751-60.
Palivos, Theodore, and Chong K. Yip. 1997b. The gains from trade for
a monetary economy once again. Canadian Journal of Economics 30:208-23.
Tower, Edward. 1991. On shadow prices, effective protection, and
domestic resource cost. In Companion to economic thought, edited by
David Greenaway, Michael Bleaney, and Ian Steward (eds.), Companion to
Economic Thought, London: Routledge, 1991, 614-33. Reprinted in A guide
to modern economics, London: Routledge, 1996.
World Bank. 1989. World development report 1989: Financial systems
and development. New York: Oxford University Press.
Professor Gokcekus is also a scholar-in-residence at Duke University
and Professor Tower is a regular visitor at the University of Auckland.
Thanks go to Kent Kimbrough and Theodore Palivos for helpful comments.