Scope, learning, and cross-subsidy: organ transplants in a multi-division hospital - an extension.
Kaserman, David L.
I. Introduction
In a recent paper in this Journal, Possai and Goetz [10] (P-G) offer
an explanation of why a hospital might choose to provide a service
(organ transplants) or continue to provide a service that, on its own
merits, may appear to be unprofitable. Their explanation is based upon
hypothesized (and plausible) cost and demand relationships involving
economies of scope, demand complementarities, and learning-by-doing that
render the net effects of the service profitable for the hospital's
overall operations while appearing unprofitable on its own. Thus, the
(undocumented) perception that the transplant business is unprofitable
is an illusion caused by a failure to consider the full range of effects
of a transplant program on costs and demands, both for transplants and
other hospital outputs.
There are two fundamental and interrelated issues that P-G do not
address. First, the analysis they present does not explain why hospitals
that do not currently have organ transplant programs are rapidly
entering this industry. Nor does it explain why hospitals that already
have transplant programs are actively trying to expand the number of
operations beyond that presently performed. Rather, P-G's analysis
focuses on the static optimality (first-order) conditions for the four
objective functions considered and describes the implications of those
conditions for overall, firm-wide profitability versus service
profitability. Thus, the explanation provided is one of profitability of
a service that, on a more narrow accounting, appears unprofitable.
Assuming the hospital is already at these optimal values (and there is
no reason given why they are not), however, there is no obvious
incentive for either entry or expansion, which are dynamic phenomena, to
occur. The analysis we present here will more directly address these
issues.
The second fundamental issue not addressed in P-G's approach is
the implications for observed behavior in this industry of the
persistent and severe shortage of human organs for transplantation. Both
federal and state laws proscribe the purchase or sale of human organs
for transplantation.(1) Such organs may be donated, but they may not be
sold. As a result, the legally mandated price of this crucial input is
fixed at zero, and a chronic organ shortage has plagued the industry
since transplants first became feasible in the mid-1950s. That shortage
has become increasingly severe in recent years.(2) It is difficult to
model equilibrium conditions in this market without recognizing and
incorporating the effects of this shortage on observed outcomes. Indeed,
it is our thesis here that one cannot understand the underlying
incentives to enter and expand in this business without first taking
account of the organ shortage.
II. A Simple Model of an Input-Constrained Firm
Over the years, economists have modeled the behavior of firms subject
to a variety of exogenous constraints.(3) To our knowledge, however, the
particular constraint examined here - where an input price is held fixed
below the equilibrium level - has not yet been explored systematically.
Such a constraint is clearly relevant to an analysis of firms
(hospitals) supplying human organ transplants due to the legal
prohibition on purchases and sales of the organs required for such
transplants. Accordingly, we begin by developing a simple model that, we
believe, reflects the essential effects of this institutional feature of
the transplant industry.
Assumptions
Our model makes use of the following set of notation and assumptions:
1. The price of transplantable organs, [P.sub.O], is legally fixed at
zero.
2. Transplant providers receive a fixed rate, [P.sub.T], per
transplant performed, paid by a third party. Recipients have a
willingness to pay for transplants, but cannot be individually billed
for procedures.
3. The production function for transplant operations is characterized
by a fixed-proportions technology in which each operation requires one
transplantable organ. Thus, we assume that [Q.sub.T] = [Q.sub.O], where
[Q.sub.T] is the number of transplant operations performed and [Q.sub.O]
is the number of transplantable organs acquired by the transplanting
hospital.
4. The marginal cost of performing a transplant operation is constant
at [MC.sub.T].
5. The supply curve of organs is given by [Q.sub.O]([P.sub.O]), with
d[Q.sub.O]/d[P.sub.O] [greater than or equal to] 0, and [Mathematical
Expression Omitted]. Thus, the organ supply curve is coincident with the
[Q.sub.O] axis up to [Mathematical Expression Omitted], and it increases
in [P.sub.O] thereafter.
6. Hospitals have significant monopsony power in the procurement of
organs within their respective geographic collection regions.
A brief explanation of these assumptions may be useful. The first
assumption reflects the fact that, under the National Organ Transplant
Act of 1984, it is a felony to buy or sell human organs for purpose of
transplantation. The second assumption captures the exogeneity of
reimbursement rates for transplant procedures. These rates are set
administratively either by funding agencies (e.g., the Health Care
Financing Administration fully funds all kidney transplants under the
End Stage Renal Disease Program) or by insurance companies and are,
therefore, exogenous to the individual hospital.(4) Further, in an
effort to reduce recipient bidding for transplants, guidelines prohibit
additional direct charges by hospitals to patients requesting or
receiving transplants, although some violations of these restrictions
have apparently occurred. The third and fourth assumptions provide a
reasonably accurate depiction of the transplant production process and
also serve to substantially simplify the analysis. And the fifth and
sixth assumptions appear to characterize the market conditions that
exist in the procurement of organs for transplantation.
Moreover, it is important to recognize that assumptions five and six
imply that the organ supply curve is kinked at [Mathematical Expression
Omitted].(5) As a result, the marginal factor cost curve for organs
faced by the monopsonist hospital will exhibit a gap at this level of
organ procurement. Thus, our model is one of monopsony with kinked
supply.
Initial Equilibrium with No Procurement Effort
To develop our model of the input-constrained firm, we begin with the
simplest possible case. Specifically, we initially assume that the firm
has no control over the supply curve of organs, [Q.sub.O]([P.sub.O]).
That is, organ supply is given exogeneously and organ price is set
administratively at [P.sub.O] = 0. Given these assumptions, a hospital
may acquire (or accept) anywhere from zero up to [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] organs for use in the corresponding number of
transplant operations. If [P.sub.T] [greater than] [MC.sub.T], the
profit maximizing number of transplants will equal the maximum number of
organs that can legally be acquired at the zero price, i.e.,
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. This result follows from the fact
that the value of the marginal product of organs (the marginal net
revenue of transplant operations times the marginal product of organs)
is [P.sub.T] - [MC.sub.T],(6) while the marginal factor cost of organs
is zero up to [Mathematical Expression Omitted]. Thus, if [P.sub.T]
[greater than] [MC.sub.T], the hospital will choose to acquire
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] organs for transplantation.
Conversely, if [P.sub.T] [less than] [MC.sub.T], then [Mathematical
Expression Omitted].(7) That is, in this latter case, the hospital will
refrain from entering the transplantation industry and will accept no
organ donations.
These initial equilibria are shown in Figure 1 for two alternative
reimbursement rates, [P.sub.T] and [P[prime].sub.T], where [P.sub.T]
[greater than] [MC.sub.T] and [P[prime].sub.T] [less than]
[MC.sub.T].(8) If the hospital elects to enter the transplant industry
(i.e., if [P.sub.T] [greater than] [MC.sub.T]), its profits are given by
the area [Mathematical Expression Omitted]. These profits obviously
increase with increases in the exogenous reimbursement rate, [P.sub.T].
Consequently, any increases in this rate over time provide a potential
explanation for observed entry into the transplant industry.
Figure 1 also suggests that, where [P.sub.T] [greater than]
[MC.sub.T], hospital profits will increase with exogenous increases in
the value of [Mathematical Expression Omitted]. In other words, a shift
in the supply of organs that causes more to become available at the
regulated price of zero will raise the total profits obtained from
transplants. Thus, hospitals already performing transplants would like
to acquire more organs and perform more transplants (i.e., expand) if
they could costlessly obtain these organs at a price of zero.
Although Figure 1 represents the marginal benefit of an organ to
transplant providers as the difference [P.sub.T] - [MC.sub.T], the
patients' willingness to pay for organs may be much higher. Given a
targeted, use-restricted subsidy of [P.sub.T] dollars per patient, a
consumer with an unsubsidized willingness to pay of $W will presumably offer up to W + [P.sub.T] for a transplant, or W + [P.sub.T] -
[MC.sub.T] for an organ when procedures are sold for [MC.sub.T].
Regulations seek to limit providers' charges to [P.sub.T], yet it
would be strange if the potentially substantial additional surpluses
enjoyed by many recipients did not lead to some rent seeking activities.
In particular, some patients hoping to become recipients, and some
transplant centers, may search for creative ways to
"recontract" outside the regulations. Figure 1 represents
consumers' willingness to pay for organs (inclusive of the subsidy)
by the marginal benefit curve [D.sub.O] (assuming that transplant
procedures are obtainable at the cost [MC.sub.T]). In the absence of a
restriction on organ sales, equilibrium would occur at price [P.sub.e]
and quantity [Q.sub.e].
To this point, we have taken [Mathematical Expression Omitted] as
exogenous to the hospital's decision-making calculus. But, in fact,
hospitals have some (albeit limited) ability to shift the organ supply
curve to the right by investing in activities that increase organ
donations (e.g., educational activities, advertising programs,
procurement teams, etc.). Such acquisition activities, of course, entail
costs. By increasing organ procurement efforts, however, the hospital
can shift the organ supply curve to the right. Modifying our model to
endogenize organ acquisition efforts and costs provides additional
insight into the hospital's optimization problem and, ultimately,
the incentive to enter and expand.
Optimal Procurement Effort
Assuming that organ supply can be increased by increasing procurement
efforts, we alter assumption 5 to:
5[prime]. The supply curve of organs is given by [Q.sub.O]([P.sub.O],
E), with [Delta][Q.sub.O]/[Delta][P.sub.O] [greater than or equal to] 0
and [Delta][Q.sub.O]/[Delta]E [greater than] 0, where E represents the
level of the hospital's expenditures on organ procurement efforts.
Given this reformulation, the hospital's optimization problem is
one of selecting [E.sup.*], the profit-maximizing level of organ
procurement expenditures.
With positive organ prices proscribed by law, increases in organ
procurement expenditures have the effect of shifting [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] to the right. Thus, with [P.sub.O] = 0, the
hospital's organ supply curve, [Q.sub.O]([P.sub.O], E), effectively
becomes [Mathematical Expression Omitted]. Hospital profits, then, are
given by
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
The first-order condition for maximization of equation (1) is
([P.sub.T] - [MC.sub.T])([Delta][Q.sub.O]/[Delta]E) - 1 = 0. (2)
The solution to (2) then yields the hospital's optimal organ
procurement expenditures, [E.sup.*].(9) This equation simply says that
the hospital will invest in organ procurement efforts up to the point at
which the marginal net revenue of such efforts equals the marginal cost
of acquiring the next organ at the legal price of zero. Thus, Figure 1
still characterizes the equilibrium number of organs procured and
transplants performed if So is interpreted as the organ supply curve
that exists at [E.sup.*]. We turn now to consider how this equilibrium
condition can shed light on the incentive to enter and expand.
III. The Incentive to Enter and Expand
The basic incentive for hospitals to enter the transplant industry is
closely tied to the existing shortage of transplantable organs.
Specifically, the current policy mandating a zero price for organs
creates rents in the transplant industry by artificially restricting the
quantity of organs supplied and transplants performed.(10) Particularly
in the presence of inelastic demand (which, no doubt, is the case with
organ transplants), such an output restriction yields a demand price for
organs of [Mathematical Expression Omitted] in Figure 1.
A hospital's ability to capture the resulting rents directly in
the price charged for transplant operations is obviously constrained by
the fixed reimbursement rate set by the funding agency or insurance
company. Nonetheless, so long as [P.sub.T] [greater than] [MC.sub.T],
some of these rents can be appropriated directly by entering the
transplant industry. While it is not our purpose here to explore the
potential avenues through which rents that cannot be appropriated
through the reimbursement rate may be captured by transplant providers,
it seems likely that such rent-seeking activities could assume a variety
of forms.(11) The goodwill, prestige, and demand interdependency effects
described by P-G are possible examples. In any case, increases in organ
demand (which lead to increases in the organ shortage) create additional
rents in the transplant industry that hospitals may attempt to capture
in one form or another.
The bulk of human organs used in transplantation are obtained from
cadavers. While only a small fraction of all deaths result in
potentially transplantable organs, most hospitals experience a
sufficient number of qualifying deaths to supply at least a small
transplant center.(12) Without such a center, when a patient dies under
circumstances allowing transplantable organs to be removed, the hospital
has only two options - either allow the (valuable) organs to go
uncollected, or collect them and ship them to another hospital that has
a transplant program.(13) In either case, none of the potential rents
associated with the organs are captured by the hospital making the
decision to solicit the organs.
Therefore, the zero price policy creates potentially large economic
rents that can be appropriated only by those hospitals that have entered
the transplant industry. In terms of the model developed above, if we
ignore the indirect benefits of entry, a hospital will enter the
transplant industry if [P.sub.T] [greater than] [MC.sub.T] and
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] at [E.sup.*]. In other words, entry
will occur if profits are positive at the optimal level of procurement
effort, i.e., if
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Any indirect benefits of having a transplant center associated with
the hospital, such as those identified in P-G, will reinforce the direct
profit incentive to enter provided by equation (3).
For a given distribution of the marginal costs of transplantation
across hospitals, an increase in [P.sub.T] will obviously encourage
additional firms to enter. With regard to the incentive to expand, we
have
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
The numerator of the expression on the RHS is negative, and the
denominator is also negative (by the second-order condition for
maximization of equation (1)). Therefore,
[Delta][E.sup.*]/[Delta][P.sub.T] [greater than] 0. An increase in
reimbursement rates will cause organ procurement expenditures to
increase.
It would seem reasonable to assume that increases over time in the
demand for organ transplants (which lead directly to increases in the
derived demand for organs, the associated demand price, [Mathematical
Expression Omitted], and the organ shortage, shown in Figure 1 as
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]) will ultimately cause the
reimbursement rate, [P.sub.T], to increase as well. The empirical
evidence appears to support this assumption. Table I shows the marked
increases in the shortage of organs for transplantation that have
occurred since 1987. Although the organ shortage has existed for
decades, it became substantially worse during the latter part of the
1980s and the early 1990s.(14) As a result, the (unobserved) demand
price for organs has undoubtedly increased significantly as well.
Moreover, this increase in the market value of transplantable organs has
translated, at least in part, to an increase in transplant reimbursement
rates, particularly in the charges for organ acquisition reimbursed by
funding agencies. Table II provides the relevant data. Moreover, even in
the absence of direct profit incentives provided by increases in
[P.sub.T], less direct avenues for appropriation of increased rents
provide incentives to enter and expand as organ demand grows.
Table I. Number of Patient Registrations on the National Transplant
Waiting List(*)
Kidney All Organs
12/31/87 11,822 13,115
12/31/88 13,943 16,026
2/31/89 16,294 19,095
12/31/90 17,883 21,914
12/31/91 19,352 24,719
12/31/92 22,376 29,415
12/31/93 24,973 33,394
7/31/94 26,077 35,476
* The number of patients awaiting organ transplants may be fewer
than the numbers listed in this table because some patients may be
listed with more than one transplant center.
Source: UNOS Update [11].
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE II OMITTED]
Thus, the organ shortage, which has worsened considerably in recent
years, creates economic rents that, under the existing prohibition on
organ sales, can only be captured by hospitals entering the transplant
industry. Consequently, a major force driving observed entry and
expansion efforts in this industry is the existing policy that has
created that shortage - the legal proscription of organ sales.
IV. Conclusion
In their paper, P-G attempt to explain recently observed entry and
expansion efforts in the organ transplant industry that have occurred
despite an alleged perception that transplantation is unprofitable.
Simply put, these authors argue that this apparent anomaly is the result
of inadequate accounting. According to P-G, economies of scope, demand
complementarities, and learning curve effects render transplantation
profitable to the hospital's overall operations, while a more
narrow accounting gives the illusion that these activities are
unprofitable. We have no real quarrel with that basic argument.
Rather, our work seeks to expand the P-G analysis by explicitly
modeling the effects of the organ shortage on the transplant firm's
(hospital's) optimization problem. This shortage is created by the
existing law which sets the legal price for cadaveric organs at zero.
The resulting organ shortage and the corresponding shortage of
transplant operations gives rise to substantial economic rents. Because
payment for organs is proscribed by law, the only avenue through which
hospitals harvesting organs can capture these rents is by entering the
transplant industry. It is this incentive to capture increasing rents,
rather than some accounting anomaly, that appears to explain the recent
entry and expansion efforts in the transplant industry. One simply
cannot fully understand observed behavior in this market without first
accounting for the microeconomic ramifications of this shortage.
A. H. Barnett T. Randolph Beard David L. Kaserman Auburn University Auburn, Alabama
The authors wish to thank the anonymous referee for useful comments
on a prior draft of this paper. The usual caveat applies.
1. The National Organ Transplant Act of 1984 prohibits any form of
tangible compensation in interstate exchanges involving transplantable
organs. More specifically, the Act states: "It shall be unlawful
for any person to knowingly acquire, receive or otherwise transfer any
human organ for valuable consideration for use in human transplantation
if the transfer affects interstate commerce." Participation in such
exchanges is designated a felony by the act. See the National Organ
transplant Act, Supp. IV 1986, 274(e) [12]. Every state has passed
similar legislation prohibiting intrastate commerce in organs.
2. The number of patients who died waiting for a transplant nearly
doubled between the mid 1980s to early 1990s, as noted by Peters [9].
3. The seminal work in this area is that of Averch and Johnson [1].
Since that article appeared, a flood of literature has developed
exploring firms' behavior under a variety of regulatory
constraints. For a survey of much of this work, see Baumol and Klevorick
[2].
4. The bulk of all transplants performed are covered either by
Medicare or by private insurance companies. Nonetheless, some
transplants are paid for directly by the patient, and, for these, the
hospital may have some control over [P.sub.T]. Our analysis, however, is
not sensitive to the assumption that [P.sub.T] is fixed exogenously.
5. It is perhaps worth note that the organ supply curve described by
assumption 5 has nothing to do with organ procurement costs. Rather, it
simply depicts the number of organs suppliers (donors) would be willing
to supply (donate) at each price. Obviously, some organs (e.g.,
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]) are supplied (donated) at a zero
price. Our positively sloped supply curve at quantities greater than
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] simply reflects our assumption that
positive prices paid to organ suppliers (donors) would induce some, who
would not provide organs at a zero price, to allow their (family
member's) organs to be harvested for transplantation.
6. With [Q.sub.T] = [Q.sub.O], the marginal product of organs equals
one. The marginal net revenue of organs is [P.sub.T] - [MC.sub.T].
7. Because we have assumed that both [P.sub.T] and [MC.sub.T] are
constants, either [P.sub.T] [greater than] [MC.sub.T] or [P.sub.T] [less
than] [MC.sub.T] will hold throughout. As a result [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] will be either [Mathematical Expression Omitted] or
zero. An interior solution, [Mathematical Expression Omitted], could be
obtained if [P.sub.T] were declining and/or [MC.sub.T] were increasing.
Modifying our model to allow for either possibility would complicate but
not materially affect our analysis.
8. The zero price constraint requires that output occur somewhere on
the 0, [Mathematical Expression Omitted] closed interval. Excess demand
(an organ shortage) exists anywhere along this interval, however,
because the derived demand for organs, [D.sub.O], equals [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] at [P.sub.O] = 0.
9. The second-order condition for maximization of (1) requires that
([P.sub.T] - [MC.sub.T])([[Delta].sup.2][Q.sub.O]/[Delta][E.sup.2])
[less than] 0.
10. A policy requiring a zero price for organs is analytically
similar to the formation of a cartel agreement in the transplant
industry. Either approach restricts output below the competitive level.
See Barney and Reynolds [3], Kaserman and Barnett [7], Barnett and
Kaserman [5], and Blair and Kaserman [6].
11. For example, in a recent article McCartney [8] reports that
". . . hospitals were offering million-dollar signing bonuses to
lure coveted transplant surgeons."
12. Typically, cadaveric organs are suitable for transplantation when
they are acquired from a brain-dead, infection-free, heart-beating
cadaver, where the individual was relatively young and in good health at
the time of the event which caused death. Such individuals are often
victims of a terminal head injury.
13. In the event the organs are collected and sent elsewhere for
transplantation, the hospital where the organs are harvested is
compensated only for use of its operating room and other direct expenses
associated with organ removal. Legally, it can receive no payment for
the organs themselves.
14. see Barnett, Beard and Kaserman [4] for a discussion of
opposition in the medical community to policy changes which could
ameliorate this shortage.
References
1. Averch, Harvey and Leland L. Johnson, "Behavior of the Firm
under Regulatory Constraint." American Economic Review, December
1963, 1052-69.
2. Baumol, William and Alvin Klevorick, "Input Choices and
Rate-of-Return Regulation: An Overview of the Discussion." Bell
Journal of Economics, Autumn 1970, 162-90.
3. Barney, L. Dwayne, Jr. and R. Larry Reynolds, "An Economic
Analysis of Transplant Organs." Atlantic Economic Journal,
September, 1989, 12-20.
4. Barnett, Andy H., T. Randolph Beard and David L. Kaserman,
"The Medical Community's Opposition to Organ Markets: Ethics
or Economics." The Review of Industrial Organization, December
1993, 669-78.
5. Barnett, Andy H. and David L. Kaserman, "The 'Rush to
Transplant' and Organ Shortages." Economic Inquiry, July 1995.
6. Blair, Roger D. and David L. Kaserman, "The Economics and
Ethics of Alternative Cadaveric organ Procurement Policies," Yale
Journal of Regulation, Summer 1991, 403-52.
7. Kaserman, David L. and Andy H. Barnett, "An Economic Analysis
of Transplant Organs: A Comment and Extension." Atlantic Economic
Journal, June, 1991, 57-63.
8. McCartney, Scott, "Agonizing Choices: People Most Needing
Transplantable Organs Now Often Miss Out." Wall Street Journal,
April 1993, 1.
9. Peters, Thomas G., "Life or Death: The Issue of Payment in
Cadaveric Organ Donation." Journal of the American Medical
Association, March 13, 1991, 1302-305.
10. Possai, Kathleen W. and Michael Goetz, "Scope, Learning, and
Cross Subsidy: Organ Transplants in a Multi-Division Hospital."
Southern Economic Journal, January 1994, 715-26.
11. United Network for Organ Sharing (UNOS Update), Vol. 10, Issue 8,
August 1994, p. 48, and Vol. 10, Issue 7, July 1994, p. 37.
12. U.S. Congress, National Organ Transplant Act, Pub. L. No. 98-507,
98 Stat. 2339 (codified as amended at 42 U.S.C. & 273-274 (e))
(Supp. IV 1986).