首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月28日 星期四
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Optimal regulation of multiply-regulated industries: the case of physician services.
  • 作者:Sindelar, Jody L.
  • 期刊名称:Southern Economic Journal
  • 印刷版ISSN:0038-4038
  • 出版年度:1996
  • 期号:April
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Southern Economic Association
  • 摘要:An important type of regulatory failure occurs when agencies neglect to coordinate their actions. A growing body of research has found that coordination failures confound government efforts to implement optimal public policies. For example, see Baron [1]; Coate [5]; Hansson and Stuart [12]; Kotlikoff [16]; and Veall [24]. These studies have typically focused on coordination failures between the public and private sectors.(1) Our analysis examines coordination failures among agencies involved in different aspects of regulation within a given industry.
  • 关键词:Health services administrators;Medical care;Medical professions;Medicare;Physicians

Optimal regulation of multiply-regulated industries: the case of physician services.


Sindelar, Jody L.


I. Introduction

An important type of regulatory failure occurs when agencies neglect to coordinate their actions. A growing body of research has found that coordination failures confound government efforts to implement optimal public policies. For example, see Baron [1]; Coate [5]; Hansson and Stuart [12]; Kotlikoff [16]; and Veall [24]. These studies have typically focused on coordination failures between the public and private sectors.(1) Our analysis examines coordination failures among agencies involved in different aspects of regulation within a given industry.

Given the varied institutional contexts in which multiple regulation occurs, formal representations may be most insightful when tailored to the specifics of each industry, as Bernheim and Whinston [2] have noted.(2) This paper models physician services as a market regulated by two governmental agencies, each concerned with a different aspect of market performance. One branch of the government, the Health Care Financing Administration (HCFA), currently sets Medicare reimbursement rates while another branch, the Agency for Health Care Policy and Research (AHCPR), sets practice or quality standards for physicians' services. While the standards set are merely guidelines, not rules, there are potentially costly implications to physicians from ignoring the guidelines.

Coordination failures arise in our model when two agencies, one charged with price regulation, the other with setting medical practice guidelines, fail to take full account of each other's actions and goals. Although the basic model may be generalized to a number of settings, the physician services industry provides a particularly vivid example, given the current policy concerns about the cost and quality of medical care.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Part II discusses the current regulatory environment under Medicare. Part III presents a model of optimal practice guidelines and physician reimbursement. Part IV solves the model for the socially optimal case. Part V compares outcomes under coordination failure to the social optimum. In particular, the implications of coordination failures for cost, quality, medical practice characteristics, and quantity of care are derived. These are the salient outcomes of concern for health care regulatory agencies and for society. Part VI summarizes the results and discusses their policy implications.

II. Institutional Background

Practice guidelines are continuing to be developed by AHCPR. These guidelines set standards and try to affect the quality and appropriateness of care. Medicare payments to physicians are now set by HCFA according to the recently implemented Resource Based Relative Value Scales (RBRVS).

Practice Guidelines

With the establishment in 1989 of the Agency for Health Care Policy and Research (AHCPR), the federal government made the development of practice guidelines an important component of health care regulation. AHCPR has initiated work on 16 practice guidelines. The Institute of Medicine and many other health care organizations are concurrently involved in guideline development.(3)

Guidelines may be developed in a variety of ways. AHCPR is funding research on outcomes assessments to aid in the development of guidelines for specific procedures. More common methods than engaging in original research to develop guidelines are use of literature reviews of available scientific evidence and/or expert panels.

Guidelines may focus on diagnosis, evaluation of individual services, or appropriate treatment regimens for specific conditions (management guidelines).(4) The first two types of guidelines identify illnesses and evaluate specific medical technologies or services, respectively. Management guidelines, however, prescribe appropriate treatments for an entire episode of care for a patient with a given medical condition. A report by the Physician Payment Review Commission [20] indicates that AHCPR is currently devoting the vast majority of its efforts to the development of diagnostic and management guidelines.

Such guidelines may have significant effects on physician behavior. First, they may lead physicians to rethink the type and level of care deemed appropriate. Second, deviations from the guidelines may impose costs on the physician, such as anxiety or increased malpractice exposure.

Reimbursement

The Resource Based Relative Value Scale (RBRVS), effective as of January 1, 1992, is part of Medicare's recent effort to implement a physician fee schedule. The RBRVS computes "relative values" of physicians' services across specialties. It factors into the relative values the physician's time, the complexity of services, practice costs, and opportunity costs of medical training.

The RBRVS approach is designed to base reimbursement on the costs of providing care, rather than on actual charges, which was the previous approach. See Hsiao [13] and Hadley [11] for further details. By itself, the RBRVS is not a fee schedule. However, once relative values have been computed, a fee schedule is obtained by multiplying the RBRVS by a conversion factor. Although intended to address market imperfections in the physician services market, RBRVS has drawn considerable criticism from economists.(5)

III. A Model of Reimbursement and Practice Guidelines

The model presented below applies to the physician services market, especially with regard to the Medicare sector. Physician fees (prices) are set by HCFA, while AHCPR establishes practice guidelines. In this initial formulation of the model, government agencies engage in non-cooperative behavior. Cost control is a common objective of each agency.(6) In addition, HFCA sets prices to promote patient access to and satisfaction with care, while ACHPR sets guidelines to promote quality.

Each agency is assumed to take the physician's profit maximizing behavior into account in setting price and guidelines. The implications of this model are then compared to the social optimum. In the social optimum, both agencies cooperate to promote quality and other characteristics, while controlling cost.

We assume that there is a single payer, Medicare,(7) which sets the reimbursement rates for physician services and pays the entire bill for Medicare patients.(8) As patients incur no out-of-pocket expenses for their care, their demand for care is insensitive to price. This simplifying assumption is reasonable given that: 1) the vast majority of physicians accept Medicare reimbursement as payment in full, 2) copayments are relatively small and 3) balance-billing amounts are smaller still.(9)

We further assume that patients have difficulty judging the appropriateness of medical treatment. Thus, physicians alone determine the course of treatment in our model.

Search Model

In this model of the physicians' services market, there are many (M) physicians who compete for patients, and numerous (N) consumers who search for appropriate physicians. As the cost of care is paid for entirely by Medicare, there is no price competition. Physicians compete for patients through non-price competition, in this case, by offering practice attributes that consumers value.(10) These attributes enhance the attractiveness and accessibility of the physician.(11) This search model is based on an earlier model due to Satterthwaite [22; 23]. As in Satterthwaite [22], we assume that physicians and consumers are homogeneous. However, consumers have different preferences over the attributes offered by physicians. One consumer may prefer the attributes offered by physician j; another will prefer those of physician i. Thus, instead of Satterthwaite's price competition, our model has non-price competition in the form of medical practice attributes.

The model posits physicians as being in short run equilibrium.(12) In this steady state, however, patients may leave their current physician in favor of alternative ones. Patients may leave for demographic reasons such as individuals changing their area of residence. Some patients may also search for new physicians because they are not satisfied with the attributes of their current physicians and want to search for ones who will appeal to their particular tastes.

For an equilibrium to exist, for each physician, the expected number of patients entering the practice must equal the expected number departing. Following Satterthwaite [22; 23], define [v.sub.i] as the probability that a randomly selected consumer from physician i's current practice will come to the physician for an office visit within a week.(13) We assume that [v.sub.i] is an increasing function of the attributes physician i provides, [A.sub.i]. The physician i therefore expects to have [v.sub.i][N.sub.i] patient visits per week.

Define [s.sub.i] as the probability that a randomly chosen member of physician i's practice will decide to leave that practice in any given week, and [w.sub.i] as the probability that a randomly chosen consumer who has quit another's practice will join physician i's practice. It is assumed that [s.sub.i] is decreasing in [A.sub.i], and increasing in the attributes offered by all other physicians. Further, [w.sub.i] is increasing in [A.sub.i], and decreasing in all A save for the ith physician. This leads to the equilibrium condition:

[Mathematical Expression Omitted].

Satterthwaite [22] has shown that this equilibrium condition implies that the number of patients physician i expects to receive, [N.sub.i], is a decreasing function of his or her price. A symmetric argument implies that [N.sub.i] is increasing in attributes [A.sub.i].

Physician Behavior

We model physician behavior as consisting of sequential stages. In the first stage, physicians set the level of attributes A to attract patients. In the second stage, given that the attributes level is already determined, physicians observe their patients' medical needs and decide the level of treatment T to provide.(14)

Provision of Attributes. In deciding upon the level of attributes to provide, the physician considers the cost of and expected return on various levels of attributes. Attributes are costly to provide and costs are increasing in the level of attributes. The expected return from providing more attributes is two-fold: first is the increased probability of visits ([v.sub.i]) per patient and second is the expected increase in the number of patients ([N.sub.i]). Each additional visit that the physician provides is valued by the physician at the rate of profits per visit, [Pi], that he or she expects to receive. Profits per visit will depend positively on the price P that the physician receives under Medicare. Profits will also depend upon the level of treatment that the physician expects to provide to patients, [T.sup.e]. With new patients arriving and some established patients leaving, the physician is uncertain in advance as to the level of care that will be needed. We assume that the physician bases the expected treatment level on the treatment level currently provided to established patients.(15) Thus, we may write expected profits per visit as [Pi] = [Pi](P, [T.sup.e]).

Given expected profits, the representative physician(16) chooses attributes to:

[Mathematical Expression Omitted],

N(A) = the perceived number of patients the physician can obtain as a function of attributes A, dN/dA [greater than] 0; and

g(A) = costs of providing attributes, dg/dA [greater than] 0, and other terms are as defined above.

Maximizing (2) with respect to A yields A as an increasing function of P.(17) Individually, the physician perceives that he can obtain more patients, the higher the level of attributes offered. Since physicians are identical, they all increase attributes in response to a price increase in the same way. Because the stock of patients is fixed, however, a higher price does not lead to a higher number of patients being treated per physician in equilibrium. In equilibrium, physicians treat an equal, fixed number of patients (N/M). The effect of the price increase is to raise the equilibrium level of attributes provided.

Since each physician is providing a level of attributes that maximizes his or her net income, given the attributes provided by every other competitor, this is an equilibrium solution. Also, because we assume symmetry among physicians and patients, the equilibrium will preserve such symmetry, as Satterthwaite [22] has noted.

Treatment Levels. Given the physician's patient load and level of attributes, physicians now observe patient illness severity and decide how to treat them.(18) Physicians are assumed to choose the level of care that maximizes profits per patient visit. The level of care that they choose is a function of, among other things, the price that HCFA sets and the guideline that AHCPR sets. Thus, the physician's objective may be written as:

[Mathematical Expression Omitted],

where

T = quantity of care per visit provided by the physician;

[T.sup.R] = quantity of care per visit prescribed by the practice guideline;

m[(T - [T.sup.R]).sup.2] = the costs imposed upon the physician from violating the guideline;

c = the constant marginal cost of providing a unit of service, T; and other terms are as defined above.

The first term in brackets in equation (3) is simply revenue less production cost per visit.(19) Physicians receive fee-for-service payment at a rate of P per unit of T. The second term measures the practice costs imposed upon the physician from violating the standard. The number of patients served is fixed in equilibrium (recall that only attributes increase with price).

Costs to the physician that arise from deviating from the standard can come in many forms, including psychic costs of deviating from delivering the best or most appropriate level of care,(20) increased office-related expenditures (e.g., engaging in additional recordkeeping to justify their departures from the guidelines),(21) increased involvement in medical malpractice litigation, and costs of responding to managed care inquiries (e.g., filling in extra forms and talking to managed care representatives). In addition, there may be opportunity costs incurred in the form of foregone benefits associated with compliance, such as exemption from utilization review or other regulations. The implications of practice guidelines for medical malpractice is a subject of growing concern. See for example, Physician Payment Review Commission [20].

The solution to (3) gives the physician's profit maximizing level of services as a function of price, practice guidelines, and other parameters:

T = (P - c)/b + [T.sup.R], (4)

where for notational convenience we define b = 2m.

Regulators' Objectives

AHCPR's Objectives. AHCPR is charged with setting practice guidelines ([T.sup.R]) to promote quality of care; it does so by establishing guidelines on quantity of care per visit. Increasingly, however, the Agency is being urged to take cost considerations into account when setting the guidelines. See for example Garber and Wagner [9]; Physician Payment Review Commission [20].(22) Hence, we assume that AHCPR seeks to minimize costs from providing less than the maximum quality of care and treatment costs per patient served. This goal may be written as:

[Mathematical Expression Omitted],

where

[T.sup.0] = the quantity of care that gives the maximum quality:

T(P, [T.sup.R]) = the physician's profit maximizing T obtained from equation (4) above;

[(T(P, [T.sup.R]) - [T.sup.0]).sup.2] = the social cost from providing less than the maximum quality; and

PT(P, [T.sup.R]) = program costs per patient visit.

AHCPR recognizes that quality of care does not increase with quantity of T over the entire distribution of treatment intensities. While increasing in quantity at first, beyond some point [T.sup.0], quality declines as problems such as iatrogenic infections, unnecessary surgical procedures or overly invasive diagnostic tests occur. As Brook and McGlynn [3] note, a variety of such problems have been found to be associated with increases in delivery of care beyond a certain point.

Thus, [T.sup.0] is that level of services which maximizes quality of care. This is the gold-standard for quality of care - the quality of care that consumers would desire if services were costless to them. Losses to society from less than the maximum quality of care relate to deviations of T from the quality maximizing level of care ([T.sup.0]). To capture these features while retaining analytical tractability, we specify a quadratic loss function.

As noted earlier, T represents the quantity of services per medical visit (i.e., the number of tests, treatments, or medications). As each service is reimbursed at the rate P, PT equals cost of the care and the charge to Medicare per visit.

Equation (5) says that AHCPR seeks to minimize the sum of program expenditures(23) and the social costs from providing less than the maximum quality. These social costs are higher the further away T is from [T.sup.0].

HCFA's Objectives. We assume that HCFA desires to control costs while maximizing physician accessibility and patient satisfaction. HCFA sets the reimbursement rate, P, knowing that attributes that patients value increase in P, but that costs rise as well. These objectives may be expressed as:

[Mathematical Expression Omitted],

where

[P.sup.0] = the price that elicits the utility maximizing level of attributes; and

[(P - [P.sup.0]).sup.2] = the one-sided social cost function from providing less than the utility maximizing level of care.(24)

We refer to the expression [(P - [P.sup.0]).sup.2] as a one-sided loss function because only the range 0 [less than] P [less than] [P.sup.0] is relevant; given that HCFA is concerned about cost control in addition to service quantity, P will always be less than [P.sup.0].

This specification, while simple, captures the essence of the tradeoff faced by HCFA.(25) In the case of Medicare, cost containment is undeniably an important consideration. Equation (6) says that HCFA seeks to minimize the sum of losses to patients from receiving less than the utility maximizing level of attributes, and treatment costs. As stated above, cost consciousness guarantees that HCFA will always select a price below [P.sup.0].(26)

When price is below [P.sup.0], however, social costs arise because attributes fall below the utility maximizing level, which occurs when P = [P.sup.0]. Moreover, the further P is below [P.sup.0], the greater the shortfall between actual and desired attributes, and the higher the social costs.

IV. Solving the Model

The Social Optimum

Society is concerned about the provision of attributes, quality, and the cost of care. In the non-cooperative game, each agency is concerned about costs yet otherwise their goals diverge. In the cooperative game, agencies coordinate their behavior to minimize the sum of program costs, and social costs from providing less than the quality maximizing quantity of care and less than the utility maximizing level of attributes per patient served.

In the cooperative case, given physician behavior described by (4), P and [T.sup.R] are chosen to:

[Mathematical Expression Omitted].

Substituting from (4) for T, and minimizing with respect to P and [T.sup.R] gives the optimal levels for P and [T.sup.R]:

[P.sup.*] = 2(2[P.sup.0] - [P.sup.0])/3; (8)

[T.sup.R*] = c/b + (4b + 2)[T.sup.0]/3b - (4 + 2b)[P.sup.0]/3b, (9)

where [P.sup.*] denotes the equilibrium price for the cooperative game and [T.sup.R*] denotes the equilibrium guideline. Substituting (8) and (9) into (4) gives the equilibrium level of care:

[T.sup.*] = 2(2[T.sup.0] - [P.sup.0])/3. (10)

Note that positive values for [P.sup.*] and [T.sup.*] require that [P.sup.0] [greater than] [T.sup.0]/2 and [T.sup.0] [greater than] [P.sup.0]/2. This we interpret as a requirement that [P.sup.0] and [T.sup.0] are "not too far apart".(27)

V. Coordination Failure

This section compares the effects of coordination failure to the social optimum. Coordination failure stems from non-cooperative behavior between agencies. AHCPR seeks to minimize (5) while HCFA seeks to minimize (6). Each agency observes the solution to the physician's problem (4).

In choosing price, HCFA substitutes for T from equation (4) and then minimizes (6) with respect to P, taking [T.sup.R] as given. The solution to this minimization problem gives HCFA's price as a function of [T.sup.R]. This is HCFA's reaction function:

P = (2b[P.sup.0] + c)/2(1 + b) - b[T.sup.R]/2(1 + b). (11)

In setting its guideline, AHCPR substitutes for T from (4), and then minimizes (5) with respect to [T.sup.R], taking P as given. The solution to this problem yields AHCPR's reaction function:

[T.sup.R] = c/b + [T.sup.0] - (2 + b)P/2b. (12)

The Nash equilibrium is found by solving (11) and (12) for P and [T.sup.R], respectively:

[P.sup.C*] = 2b(2[P.sup.0] - [T.sup.0])/(2 + 3b) (13)

[T.sup.RC*] = c/b + 4(1 + b)[T.sup.0]/(2 + 3b) - (4 + 2b)[P.sup.0]/(2 + 3b), (14)

where the superscript "[C.sup.*]" indicates the equilibrium solution given coordination failure. Substituting (13) and (14) into (4) gives the equilibrium level of care provided under coordination failure:

[T.sup.C*] = [(4b + 2)[T.sup.0] - 2b[P.sup.0]]/2 + 3b). (15)

Having derived the equilibrium levels for price, and the level of care provided, we are ready to compare the implications of coordination failures for the outcomes of interest.

Price/Attributes

The effects of coordination failure on price and hence attributes may be found by subtracting equation (8) from (13) yielding:

[P.sup.C*] - [P.sup.*] = -4(2[P.sup.0] - [T.sup.0])/3(2 + 3b) [less than] 0. (16)

Thus, coordination failure leads to a lower price and fewer attributes than are socially optimal. Under non-cooperative behavior, HCFA fails to recognize the indirect effect of a higher price on quality of care. A higher price increases quality of care.(28) In the cooperative case, this indirect effect is explicitly taken into account; price is chosen in part to promote quality of care. This creates an incentive to raise price under cooperation.

Quantity

The net effect of coordination failure on quantity of services is the difference between equations (15) and (10):

[T.sup.C*] - [T.sup.*] = 2(2[P.sup.0] - [T.sup.0])/3(2 + 3b) [greater than] 0. (17)

Thus, with coordination failure, the quantity of services exceeds the social optimum.

The changes in price and practice guidelines under coordination failure relative to the social optimum exert competing influences on the actual quantity of services provided. On the one hand, the lower price under coordination failure decreases the amount of care provided, ceteris paribus. On the other hand, the lower price increases the need to set a high practice guideline, and in fact the guideline under coordination failure is higher than in the cooperative case.(29) The higher guideline exerts a positive effect on actual treatment levels. The latter effect dominates, so that quantity of care is higher under coordination failure.

Quality

The implications of coordination failure for quality of care are straightforward. First, observe that [T.sup.C*] is always less than [T.sup.0]. This, together with the fact that [T.sup.C*] [greater than] [T.sup.*] (see equation (17)), implies that the quantity of care is closer to [T.sup.0] under coordination failure than under cooperation. Thus, coordination failure increases the actual quality of care received, but raises it above the social optimum, [T.sup.*].

Cost

Straightforward calculations yield:

[P.sup.C*][T.sup.C*] - [P.sup.*][T.sup.*] = 4[2[P.sup.0] - [T.sup.0]][[P.sup.0](4 + 12b) - [T.sup.0](8 + 15b)]/9b[(2 + 3b).sup.2]. (18)

Whether cost exceeds or falls short of the social optimum depends upon the ratio [P.sup.0]/[T.sup.0]; high values of this ratio lead to excessive cost relative to the social optimum, while low values lead to the opposite result.(30) In particular, we have:

[P.sup.C*][T.sup.C*] - [P.sup.*][T.sup.*] [greater than or less than or equal to] 0 as [P.sup.0]/[T.sup.0] [greater than or less than or equal to] (8 + 15b)/(4 + 12b).(31) (19)

Thus, if society desires a high level of attributes per unit of medical treatment, [P.sup.0]/[T.sup.0] will be high and coordination failure will lead to excessive expenditures. On the other hand, if attributes are little valued, coordination failure leads to insufficient expenditure relative to the social optimum. One interpretation of this has interesting implications. It seems likely that attributes will be much more valued in advanced economies ([P.sup.0]/[T.sup.0] will be relatively large), than in underdeveloped ones, where no frills medical care is de rigueur. This, in turn, suggests that coordination failure may work differently in developed and underdeveloped economies, leading to excessive health care expenditures in the former, but insufficient spending in the latter. An interesting issue is how different proposals to reform the medical care system would value attributes relative to medical quality as this would, under the likely scenario of coordination failure, affect expectations about expense.

VI. Conclusion

The model we have presented examines coordination failures arising when two different arms of government implement policies designed to affect the physician services market. Coordination failure among governmental agencies has implications for price, attributes, quantity, quality, and cost of care. For example, coordination failure raises the quantity and quality of service above the social optimum, while lowering price and patient-desired attributes below their socially optimal levels.

Although excessive costs and treatment levels are popularly attributed to moral hazard and/or self-interested behavior by physicians, our model traces such problems to coordination failure among regulatory agencies as well. Thus, even if physicians were perfect agents and health insurance contracts were to eliminate moral hazard, problems of excessive costs and an over provision of care could persist.

The basic approach of the model, which emphasizes social costs of coordination and information failures, applies well to other health care markets. Some health care markets - such as the market for renal dialysis - are regulated by both state and federal governments, yielding the same sorts of issues posed here. See for example Brown, Smith, and Sindelar [4]. Other industries to which the insights of our approach would apply include public utilities, banking, and agriculture.

The results of our model suggest that cooperation and information exchange among regulatory branches should be pursued. Cooperation may be promoted through informal channels or more formal arrangements such as consolidating the activities of regulatory agencies into larger departments. With dramatic changes in the organization and finance of health care on the horizon, these issues may assume even greater importance.

Earlier versions of this paper were presented at the 1993 meetings of the Southern Economic Association, the 1994 meetings of the American Economic Association, and the International Workshop in Health Economics, Paris, 1995. We thank Tom Abbott, Michael Crew, Sharon Oster, Dough Staiger, and an anonymous reviewer for helpful comments and suggestions.

1. Baron [1] is an exception to this pattern. He examines coordination failures between an agency concerned with regulating pollution emissions of a firm (the Environmental Protection Agency) and a public utility regulator who sets the firms price.

2. Bernheim and Whinston [2, 925] investigate issues of the nature and existence of equilibrium in a purely abstract model of multiple regulation. However, as the authors note, "this task is made difficult by the proliferation of highly varied institutional contexts in which common agency appears."

3. According to a recent report by the Physician Payment Review Commission [20, 222], over 50 health care organizations are actively involved in the development of practice guidelines. These organizations include professional groups, third-party payers, hospitals, academic medical centers, health maintenance organizations, independent researchers, and malpractice insurers.

4. The three main types of guidelines, diagnosis, management, and service, have been described in a recent Physician Payment Review Commission Report to Congress [20] as follows:

Diagnostic guidelines are targeted at evaluating patients with particular symptoms (such as chest pain) for the presence of diseases that would benefit from intervention (such as angina or esophagitis). They are also used to guide the screening of asymptomatic populations for early stages of disease (to detect, for example, hypertension or diabetes).

Management guidelines cover the evaluation and treatment of patients who are known to have certain conditions. Examples are guidelines dealing with low back pain or benign prostatic hypertrophy.

Service guidelines are organized around particular diagnostic and therapeutic procedures (such as chest X-ray, colonoscopy, appendectomy, or administration of hepatitis vaccine), presenting appropriate and inappropriate indications for their use [20, 214].

5. Noll [19, 381], for example, has argued that such problems as the arbitrary nature of allocating joint costs, and reliance on "an administrative process to construct a competitive equilibrium in the structure of physician prices" renders the RBRVS approach highly questionable.

6. Cost control has long been a prominent objective of the Health Care Financing Administration. Garber and Wagner [9, 53] have argued that cost containment should be an important component in the development of practice guidelines as well. They argue that the public

... expects that the resulting guidelines will not only improve the quality of medical care but will also reduce health care costs.

The authors also illustrate how failure to take cost considerations into account will lead to wasteful health care expenditures.

7. Although there is a single payer, Medicare does not exercise its potential monopsony power. Instead, it sets price with a view to constraining costs while promoting access.

8. Alternatively, our model applies to the case where a national health insurance system is introduced, so that there is only one payer (government), but separate governmental branches set prices and establish practice guidelines. This is a likely situation in some of the health care reform scenarios.

9. Gillis, Lee, and Willke [10] report for example that almost 83% of Medicare Part B claims are accepted on assignment, so that no balance billing occurs in these cases. The authors also note that average copayments per claim were less than 28 dollars (in 1991 dollars), while balance billing amounted to less than 7 dollars per claim.

In reviewing balance billing during the mid-1980s, Zuckerman and Holahan [25, 166] concluded that "balance billing is likely to impose little, if any financial burden on the vast majority of Medicare beneficiaries." Under the recently implemented Medicare fee schedule, the amount by which the balance bill may exceed Medicare covered charges is restricted. Thus, the importance of balance billing has fallen further since the time period examined by Zuckerman and Holahan [25]. While 2 percent of Medicare beneficiaries incurred total annual balance bills over $500 in 1988, virtually no patients will incur balance bills of this amount under the Medicare fee schedule. See Physician Payment Review Commission [20] for further details.

10. That patients seek desirable attributes is supported in the literature. Surveys indicate that consumers desire attributes such as convenient location of practice, the availability of a physician answering service or other coverage at all times, an accessible and friendly demeanor by the physician toward his patients, good condition of facilities, and so on. See for example Crane and Lynch [7] and MacStravic [17].

11. While certain of these attributes may serve as indicators of the physician's technical skills, they are unlikely to be particularly informative signals of quality. For attributes to serve as quality signals, the marginal cost of producing attributes must fall the higher is physician quality, so that higher quality physicians would typically provide more attributes. However, this does not necessarily seem to he the case in this market.

12. The short run is defined as a period of time during which physician supply is fixed.

13. The time horizon is arbitrary.

14. The assumption that choice of T is conditioned on fixed A was necessary for analytic tractability. More generally, T may vary with A. For example, if A affects only the marginal patients (those willing to incur search costs), and if these patients differ in severity of illness than the average patient in the physician's practice, then T may in fact vary with A. In this case, T and A would be chosen simultaneously. We thank an anonymous reviewer for calling this point to our attention, and for providing the above example.

15. Since, as noted earlier, all patients are identical in our model save for their preferences over physician attributes, physicians' ex-ante expectations about the treatment levels required will equal actual treatment levels chosen ex-post.

16. Since all physicians are assumed to be homogeneous, subscripts denoting specific physicians are deleted from the remainder of the analysis for notational convenience.

17. The second order sufficiency conditions for a maximum guarantee that dA/dP [greater than] 0. To see this, define TT = [Pi](P, [T.sup.e])[v(A)N(A)] - g(A). Derive the first-order condition for maximizing TT, and differentiate this expression with respect to A and P. Rearranging terms yields: dA/dP = -([d.sup.2]TT/dAdP)/([d.sup.2]TT/d[A.sup.2]). The denominator is positive by the second order condition for a maximum, while [d.sup.2]TT/dAdP = (d[Pi]/dP)(dv/dA)(dN/dA) [greater than] 0. Hence, dA/dP [greater than] 0. This formulation is similar to that of Dorfman and Steiner [8], where attributes in this model play a role similar to advertising in their model.

18. Once physicians have obtained their patients, they may have the incentive to renege on the attributes they offered to entice them. To the extent that attributes take the form of capital investments, they may be sunk costs which cannot be recovered. Even if it were possible to renege on promised attributes, however, physicians depend on long term relationships with their patients, and value their reputations in the community. Breaking their implicit contract with patients to provide a certain set of attributes is unlikely to be a wise strategy, as it may cause them to lose patients and send a bad signal to other potential clients. Thus, we assume that physicians to not renege on their offered attributes ex-post.

19. The physician also has fixed expenses in the form of providing attributes (g(A)). This term would merely drop out of equation (3), as fixed costs do not affect the physician's decision at this point. Thus, we omit such costs for ease of exposition.

20. See McGuire and Pauly [18] for a discussion of psychic costs associated with demand inducement. Coleman [6], more generally, discusses internal sanctions that individuals place on themselves if they deviate from social norms.

21. Evidence suggests that physicians engage in a significant amount of defensive medicine. See for example Reynolds, Rizzo, and Gonzalez [21]; Institute of Medicine [14; 15]. It is also conceivable that physicians whose practice patterns deviate substantively from guidelines may be subject to greater malpractice insurance premiums.

22. Recently, the Physician Payment Review Commission has explicitly recommended that AHCPR pay attention to cost considerations as well as quality in guideline development:

Practice guidelines should be constructed to help improve the value of health care by addressing its cost as well as quality. The Agency for Health Care Policy and Research (AHCPR) should give greater priority to developing practice guidelines ... that could potentially reduce the amount of resources spent on unnecessary medical care. AHCPR should specify the elements that should be incorporated in guidelines so that they can be used to improve both the effectiveness and the efficiency of care. All federally sponsored guidelines should be required to contain these elements to the greatest extent possible [20].

23. Since the total number of patients treated by all physicians is fixed, nothing is gained by multiplying (5) by the fixed number of patients treated. Without loss of generality, we may regard (5) as setting this number equal to 1. With M physicians treating N/M patients each, total program costs will be found by multiplying PT by the constant N.

24. All prices and costs are taken to be expressed in terms of some numeraire good. If we were to drop this assumption, the square of the difference between dollar-denominated prices would be in units of dollars-squared. We assume that the square of this difference is instead expressed in terms of a numeraire. Thus, P, [P.sup.0], and all other parameters and variables in this model should be thought of as pure numbers, not as dollar-denominated quantifies.

25. Note that this loss function does not measure the full social costs of non-optimal delivery of care, however. The full social costs include losses from receiving less than the maximum quality (given by the expression [(T(P, [T.sup.R]) - [T.sup.0]).sup.2] described above) as well from receiving less than the utility maximizing level of attributes. The term [(P - [P.sup.0]).sup.2] only measures the latter social costs, which result from HCFA's pricing decisions.

26. [P.sup.0] may be regarded as a "bliss" point. Beyond this point, the marginal utility of attributes is zero, or even negative (negative attributes could occur with fawning physicians and nurses, or information overload).

27. Notice that [T.sup.*] will always be less than [T.sup.0]. To see this, note from equation (10) that [T.sup.*] achieves its maximum value as [P.sup.0] approaches its minimum permissible value, which must exceed [T.sup.0]/2. When [P.sup.0] = [T.sup.0]/2, [T.sup.*] = [T.sup.0]. For all values of [P.sup.0] greater than [T.sup.0]/2, we must have [T.sup.*] [less than] [T.sup.0].

28. To see this, recall that a higher price raises the profit maximizing level of care T, as can be seen from equation (4). Since [T.sup.*] is always less than [T.sup.0] (see footnote 27), a higher price also raises quality of care under cooperative behavior.

29. Subtracting the socially optimal practice guideline (9) from the equilibrium guideline under coordination failure (14) and simplifying terms yields: (4 + 2b)(2[P.sup.0] - [T.sup.0])/3b(2 + 3b) [greater than] 0 (recall that positivity of P requires that [P.sup.0] [greater than] [T.sup.0]/2 - see equation (8) in the text).

30. High values of [P.sup.0]/[T.sup.0] may be considered to represent a high value placed on desirable attributes of care relative to medical quality of care. Thus low [P.sup.0]/[T.sup.0] may represent the "no fringes" provision of health care while higher values of [P.sup.0]/[T.sup.0] represent higher provision of attributes relative to medical quality per se.

31. Notice that, as b becomes arbitrarily small, the range of permissible values for [P.sup.0]/[T.sup.0] for which [P.sup.C*][T.sup.C*] - [P.sup.*][T.sup.*] [greater than] 0 becomes smaller and smaller. There will always be a permissible range for [P.sup.0]/[T.sup.0] over which [P.sup.C*][T.sup.C*] [greater than] [P.sup.*][T.sup.*], however. This is because the second order conditions for a social optimum require that b [greater than] 0. But b [greater than] 0 allows [P.sup.C*][T.sup.C*] [greater than] [P.sup.*][T.sup.*] for values of [P.sup.0]/[T.sup.0] between 1.25 and 2 (the precise cutoff point depending on the value of b), which is in the permissible range for [P.sub.0]/[T.sup.0].

References

1. Baron, David P., "Noncooperative Regulation of a Nonlocalized Externality." Rand Journal of Economics, Winter 1985, 553-68.

2. Bernheim, B. Douglas and Michael D. Whinston, "Common Agency." Econometrica, July 1986, 923-42.

3. Brook, Robert H. and Elizabeth A. McGlynn. "Maintaining Quality of Care," in Health Services Research: Key to Health Policy, edited by Eli Ginzberg. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1991, pp. 284-314.

4. Brown, Eric J. Douglas Smith, and Jody L. Sindelar, "Can We Regulate the Quality of Care?: The Case of Dialysis in Connecticut." American Journal of Kidney Disease, June 1992, 609-13.

5. Coate, Stephen. "Altruism, the Samaritan's Dilemma, and Government Transfer Policy." Working Paper, Department of Economics, University of Pennsylvania, April 1992.

6. Coleman, James, Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1990.

7. Crane F. G. and J. E. Lynch, "Consumer Selection of Physicians and Dentists: An Examination of Choice Criteria and Cue Usage." Journal of Health Care Marketing, September 1988, 16-19.

8. Dorfman, Robert and Peter O. Steiner, "Optimal Advertising and Optimal Quality." American Economic Review, December 1954, 826-36.

9. Garber, Alan M. and Judith L. Wagner, "Practice Guidelines and Cholesterol Policy." Health Affairs, Summer 1991, 52-66.

10. Gillis, Kurt D., David W. Lee and Richard J. Willke, "Physician-Based Measures of Medicare Access." Inquiry, Fall 1992, 321-31.

11. Hadley, Jack. "Theoretical and Empirical Foundations of the Resource-Based Relative Value Scale," in Regulating Doctors' Fees, edited by H. E. Frech III. Washington: AEI Press, 1991, pp. 97-125.

12. Hansson, Ingemar and Charles Smart, "Social Security as Trade among Living Generations." American Economic Review, December 1989, 1182-95.

13. Hsiao, William C., Douwe B. Yntema, Peter Braun, Daniel Dunn and Christine Spencer, "Resource Based Relative Values." Journal of the American Medical Association October 28, 1988, 2347-60.

14. Institute of Medicine. Medical Professional Liability and the Delivery of Obstetrical Care, Volume 1. Washington: National Academy Press, 1989.

15. ----- Medical Professional Liability and the Delivery of Obstetrical Care, Volume 2. Washington: National Academy Press, 1989.

16. Kotlikoff, Laurence J., "Justifying Public Provision of Social Security." Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, Summer 1987, 674-89.

17. MacStravic, Robin S., "Manageable Evidence in Medical Care Marketing." Journal of Health Care Marketing, December 1987, 52-59.

18. McGuire, Thomas G. and Mark V. Pauly, "Physician Response to Fee Changes with Multiple Payers." Journal of Health Economics, December 1991, 385-410.

19. Noll, Roger G. "On Regulating Prices for Physicians," in Regulating Doctors' Fees, edited by H. E. Frech III. Washington: AEI Press, 1991, pp. 381-86.

20. Physician Payment Review Commission. Annual Report to Congress. Washington: 1992.

21. Reynolds, Roger A., John A. Rizzo and Martin L. Gonzalez, "The Cost of Medical Professional Liability." Journal of the American Medical Association, May 22/29 1987, 2776-81.

22. Satterthwaite, Mark A., "Consumer Information, Equilibrium Industry Price, and the Number of Sellers." Bell Journal of Economics, Autumn 10 1979, 483-502.

23. -----. "Competition and Equilibrium as a Driving Force in the Health Services Sector," in Managing the Service Economy: Prospects and Problems, edited by Robert P. Inman. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1985, pp. 239-67.

24. Veall, Michael R., "Public Pensions as Optimal Social Contracts." Journal of Public Economics, November 1986, 237-51.

25. Zuckerman, Stephen and John Holahan. "The Role of Balance Billing in Medicare Physician Payment Reform," in Regulating Doctors' Fees, edited by H. E. Frech III. Washington: AEI Press, 1991, pp. 143-69.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有