A note on capital mobility.
Moosa, Imad A.
I. Introduction
Empirical work on capital mobility, using the Feldstein-Horioka [5]
saving-investment correlation as a measurement criterion has generally
produced two results. The first result is that even when the econometric problems (particularly the endogeniety of domestic saving) are
addressed, the Feldstein-Horioka finding of low capital mobility seems
to hold up [7, 1084]. The second result is that the surprising finding
of low capital mobility is obtained even if the data set extends well
into the 1990s as was found by, inter alia, Dar, Amirkhalkhali, and
Amirkhalkhali [4]. This finding is not consistent with the conventional
wisdom that capital mobility has increased at an accelerating rate since
the early 1970s. For example, Frankel and MacArthur [7, 1084] list the
following stylized facts: (i) the degree of capital mobility is high;
(ii) it is higher for industrial countries; and (iii) it has been rising
since the 1950s and particularly since 1973.(1) The saving-investment
correlation as a criterion does not only indicate that the degree of
capital mobility is low across the board, but also fails to show that it
has been increasing over time, thus refuting the stylized facts (i),
(ii) and (iii).
Economists have for long recognised the contradiction between the
casual-observation-based conventional wisdom that capital mobility has
reached a high level and the empirical evidence which indicates the
contrary. It seems, however, that this contradiction is due to a
combination of conceptual, methodological and econometric issues. The
objective of this note is to shed some light on these issues and to
present empirical evidence on capital mobility based on real interest
parity.
II. Some Conceptual and Methodological Issues
The literature on capital mobility and market integration seems to
have traces of ambiguity, confusion and lack of clarity, leading to
contradictory conclusions. Frankel [6, 27] makes this point clear by
asserting that "the aggregation together of all forms of capital
has caused more than the usual amount of confusion in the literature on
international capital mobility." It is possibly the case that
economists reaching the opposite conclusions about capital mobility
might refer to different things i.e., different concepts and
measurements of capital. For example, the word "capital" may
imply "micro" as opposed to "macro" capital,
"net" as opposed to "gross" capital,
"portfolio" as opposed to "physical" capital,(2) and
"short-term" as opposed to "long-term" capital.
Furthermore, it is not really clear whether or not economists regard
capital mobility and market integration as the same thing or if one is a
necessary condition for the other.
It may be the case that the controversy raised by the
Feldstein-Horioka work is due to their use of capital mobility in a
macroeconomic sense whereas most of the studies are based on capital in
a microeconomic sense. And while capital moves in all directions, it
could be the case that net capital flows are not significant, and that
it is net capital movements which Feldstein and Horioka were concerned
with. This is because net capital flows, which constitute the financial
counterpart to the transfer of real resources through payment
imbalances, arise only when saving and investment are not matched within
individual countries. On the other hand, gross capital flows can be
mutually offsetting across countries.
In this note we are concerned with financial or portfolio (gross)
capital flows. An issue that needs some clarification is the
relationship between capital mobility and market integration, two
concepts that are often used interchangeably. A careful reading of the
literature, as manifested by Goldstein, Mathieson, and Lane [8] and
Frankel [6], leads to the following propositions:
1. Macroeconomic capital mobility is not a necessary condition for
market integration.
2. Equalization of real interest rates across countries is not a
necessary condition for market integration.(3)
3. Market integration is conducive to capital mobility, or at least
it leads to increasing "potential" capital flows.(4)
4. Capital mobility is a sufficient condition for market integration,
or at least that a high level of capital mobility indicates a high level
of market integration.
5. Equalization of real interest rates does not preclude the effect
of a shortfall in domestic saving on domestic investment projects.
The literature also reveals a diversified menu of measurement
criteria. Apart from the saving-investment correlation, capital mobility
and market integration can be measured by deviations from the
international parity conditions: covered interest parity (CIP),
uncovered interest parity (UIP) and real interest parity (RIP). While
Frankel and McArthur [7, 1087] assert that CIP should be the measure of
capital mobility in the sense of the degree of integration of financial
markets, they argue against the use of RIP for this purpose because it
can be invalidated by imperfect integration of goods markets. It seems,
however, that the choice of CIP as a criterion for measuring capital
mobility is motivated by the desire to reconcile the findings of
empirical tests with the conventional wisdom that capital has become
highly mobile. This is because (conventional) RIP tests, such as Mishkin
[12], have shown significant deviations from this parity condition and
thus failed to confirm the observed high degree of capital mobility.
Tests of CIP, on the other hand, have indicated only insignificant
deviations from the parity condition as shown, for example, by Taylor
[14].(5)
It is arguable, however, that measures of capital mobility that are
based on rates of return (such as CIP, UIP and RIP) are superior to
saving-investment correlations because the former require no assumption
about the exogeniety of saving, nor about the sensitivity of investment
to the real interest rate. It is also arguable that CIP is only a
measure of capital mobility in a narrow sense, as it is concerned with
short-term, and not long-term, financial capital only.(6) But for
capital mobility as a general concept, RIP seems to be a more
appropriate criterion.
If this argument is accepted then one is confronted by the task of
reconciling the results obtained from RIP tests and conventional wisdom.
Several reasons can be presented to explain why the results of these
tests have not been favourable to the RIP hypothesis, and thus to the
hypothesis of high capital mobility. The first is that most of these
studies used data that did not cover the 1980s. For example, Mishkin
[12] used a sample covering the period 1967:2-1979:2. Secondly, since
the RIP model specification involves expectational variables,
measurement errors could be responsible for the failure of RIP. Thirdly,
it is possible that the tests used are not powerful enough to confirm
RIP.(7) Although this statement is not specific it can be substantiated
by the observation that studies using more powerful tests than the
conventional ones on more recent data, as demonstrated by Cavaglia [3],
have produced results that are supportive of RIP. Moreover, Goodwin and
Grennes [9] put forward the existence of non-traded goods and
transportation costs as explanatory factors for the failure of RIP and,
therefore, the apparent incompatability between the equalization of real
interest rates and market integration.
III. Model Specification and Empirical Evidence
The RiP hypothesis can be tested in a univariate framework by
detecting, or otherwise, mean reversion in ex ante real interest rate
differentials. The RIP condition can be derived by combining the
hypotheses of covered interest parity, ex ante purchasing power parity,
and unbiasedness of the forward rate as a forecaster of the
market's expectation of the future spot rate. These conditions are
given respectively by
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where [f.sub.t] is the logarithm of the one-period forward exchange
rate, [s.sub.t] is the logarithm of the spot exchange rate, [i.sub.t] is
the domestic nominal interest rate, [Mathematical Expression Omitted] is
the logarithm of the spot exchange rate expected to prevail at time t +
1, [Mathematical Expression Omitted] is the expected change in the
logarithm of the domestic price index from time t to t + 1, and the
asterisk denotes the corresponding foreign variables. Combining
equations (1) and (3), we obtain uncovered interest parity, which is
given by
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Combining equations (4) and (2) and rearranging, we obtain
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Equation (5) implies that if the Fisher closed condition is valid
both at home and abroad, then the nominal interest rate differential
adjusts fully to the expected inflation differential, maintaining the
constancy within and equality across countries of ex ante real interest
rates. Therefore
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where [Mathematical Expression Omitted] is the domestic (foreign)
real interest rate expected to prevail in period t + 1. Under the
assumption that the actual (ex post) real interest rate realised at time
t + 1 differs from the expected real interest rate by a zero mean
stationary error, the expectation formation mechanism may be represented
by
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
and
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where [Mathematical Expression Omitted] and [Mathematical Expression
Omitted]. If the ex post real interest rate is stationary, this may be
interpreted as indicating that the ex ante real interest rate is
constant over time. Thus
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where [Mathematical Expression Omitted] is a zero mean stationary
process.(8) In general, RIP holds as a long-run equilibrium condition if
the real interest differential is mean-reverting over time.
I will initially test for mean reversion in the real interest rate
differentials of five countries vis-a-vis the U.S. These countries are
Australia, Belgium, Canada, Germany and the U.K. The choice of these
countries was determined by the availability of data covering a long
period of time and extending well into the 1990s. The sample consists of
86 quarterly observations covering the period 1972:1-1993:2. Data were
obtained from Datastream (IMF series).
Three different tests are used for this purpose: (i) the
Phillips-Perron [13] (PP) test of the null hypothesis of unit root; (ii)
the Kwiatkowski-Phillips-Schmidt-Shin [10] (KPSS) test of the null
hypothesis of stationarity; and (iii) the Brock-Dechert-Scheinkman [1]
(BDS) test of the null hypothesis that the interest rate differential is
an independently and identically distributed (iid) variable with zero
mean and constant variance. The results of these tests, which are
presented in Table I, are highly supportive of RIP as a long-run
equilibrium condition.(9) First, the four PP statistics
Z([[Tau].sub.[Mu]]), Z([[Tau].sub.[Tau]]), Z([[Phi].sub.2]), and
Z([[Phi].sub.3]) reject the null hypothesis of unit root in the interest
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 1 OMITTED] rate differentials. Second, the KPSS
statistics [[Eta].sub.[Mu]] and [[Eta].sub.[Tau]] cannot reject the null
hypothesis of stationarity, thus confirming the interpretation of the PP
test results that the rejection of the null of unit root implies
stationarity of the interest rate differentials. Third, the BDS
statistic, which is based on the correlation dimension, does not reject
the null hypothesis that the differentials are iid.(10)
Table II. Testing Mean Reversion in Real Interest Differentials
(1972-93)
Z([[Tau].sub.[Mu]]) Z([[Phi].sub.2])
Australia/U.K. -8.29 22.82
Canada/U.K. -8.24 24.24
U.K./Germany -6.47 21.12
Belgium/Germany -5.52 11.42
Canada/Germany -5.58 13.76
Two points may arise out of these results. The first point is that
testing the RIP hypothesis with the U.S. being the reference country may
bias the results since the U.S. was the most volatile economy during a
large part of the period under study and has always enjoyed the most
open markets. The second issue arises from the consensus view that the
degree of capital mobility changed over time as regulations waned and
institutions evolved. Therefore, the results do not show the time
specific effects. To deal with these two points, the RIP tests are
repeated for country combinations excluding the U.S., and for
combinations including the U.S. over two sample periods, 1972-79 and
1980-93. Given the space constraint, the results of two tests only are
reported (the Phillips-Perron Z([[Tau].sub.[Mu]]) and Z([[Phi].sub.2])
tests).
Table II reports the results of testing RIP over the whole sample
period for five country combinations excluding the U.S. The results
still support RIP as the null of nonstationarity is rejected in all
cases. Table III presents the results of testing RIP vis-a-vis the U.S.
over two periods, the first of which ends in 1979:4.(11) The results
show that only in the case of Belgium did RIP not hold in the earlier
period which gives some support to the proposition pertaining to the
gradual nature [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE III OMITTED] of increasing market
integration. One reason why the results are not strongly supportive of
this proposition is that even in the 1970s market integration had
reached a high level, propelled by the removal of capital controls by
the U.S., Germany, Canada and Switzerland; by the process of financial
innovation; and by the recycling of OPEC surpluses to developing
countries [6, 28]. In fact, by the second half of the 1970s, economists
started talking about the world financial system as characterised by
perfect capital mobility. It is perhaps the case that conducting these
tests over the 1950s or the 1960s would produce evidence indicating lack
of integration and capital mobility as represented by the failure of
RIP.
IV. Conclusion
The evidence presented in this paper lends some support to the RIP
hypothesis. This is attributed to the application of some appropriate
tests to a sample of data that extends well into the 1990s, thus
capturing the full effect of recent developments which have been
conducive to market integration and capital mobility. Even if we allow
for the distinction between market integration and capital mobility and
interpret the results of the RIP tests to be favorable to the former
only, then the conclusion is that an environment that is conducive to
capital mobility has been created. If we combine this formal evidence
with the casual observation that capital flows have been large (as
indicated by the volume of trading in the foreign exchange market, for
example) we have no alternative but to question the validity of the
empirical results indicating low capital mobility.
The evidence presented in this paper can be interpreted as implying
that the mobility of capital has become so high that disparities in real
interest rates cannot persist and that in the long run the real interest
differential reverts to a mean value of zero. Such evidence is obviously
in contrast with the Feldstein-Horioka type of results, but it is
consistent with conventional wisdom that capital mobility has become
very high.
Imad A. Moosa La Trobe University Bundoora, Victoria, Australia
1. Goldstein, Mathieson, and Lane [8, 1] point out that there has
been a sharp expansion in the scale of net and gross capital flows among
industrial countries, and that the easing of capital controls and the
liberalization of financial markets have brought about a growing
integration of domestic and offshore markets.
2. The distinction between portfolio and physical capital pertains to
the distinction between portfolio and direct investment.
3. Equalization of real interest rates across countries is, however,
a positive indicator of market integration.
4. For example, Frankel [6, 27] asserts that "the increased
degree of worldwide financial integration since 1979 is identified as
one likely factor that has allowed such large capital flows to take
place over the past decade".
5. While the relaxation of capital controls has significantly reduced
deviations from CIP as implied by existing empirical evidence, there are
other reasons for the failure of UIP and RIP. Failure to find support
for UIP could be due to errors in measuring the expected change in the
exchange rate or the presence of a risk premium. Even if UIP holds, RIP
may not hold because of the failure of ex ante PPP.
6. CIP is unlikely to hold in long-term capital markets because of
the unavailability of long-term forward contracts.
7. For example, Frankel [6, 29] asserts that RIP "has not held
any better in recent years than it did in the past". However, he
based his assertion only on Mishkin [12] and Caramazza et al. [2].
8. The assumption of stationary expectation errors is less stringent
than the rational expectations requirement of white noise.
9. In these tests interest rates are not adjusted for differences in
national tax rates although it is arguable that when economic agents pay
taxes on interest income, the net of tax real interest rate will be more
economically meaningful [11, 196]. The main reason why taxes are not
allowed for in this study, and all other studies of RIP except Mark
[11], is the unavailability of time series on comparable national tax
rates. This is evident in the procedure used by Mark who applied a
single point value of the corporate (not income) tax rates prevailing in
1977 to the time series of nominal interest rates. In my view, this
procedure is faulty for it introduces measurement errors and cannot
serve as an empirical representation of the sound theoretical
proposition that it is more plausible to use net of tax rates. In any
case, there was no significant difference between the results based on
gross and those based on net of tax rates: both rejected RIP.
10. The BDS statistics were calculated for an embedding dimension, m,
of 2 while the distance between two m-histories, [Epsilon], was fixed at
a value equal to half a standard deviation. Trials with several other
combinations did not change the results significantly.
11. There are two reasons for using 1979:4 as a split point. The
first is that Frankel [6, 27] refers to 1979 as the year since which
increased integration is identified as one likely factor that has
triggered large capital flows. The second reason is that it divides the
full sample in such a way as to leave the sub sample sizes reasonably
suitable for empirical testing.
References
1. Brock, W. A., W. D. Dechert and J. A. Scheinkman. "A Test for
Independence Based on the Correlation Dimension." Social Systems
Research Unit, University of Wisconsin, 1987.
2. Caramazza, F., K. Clinton, A. Cote and D. Longworth.
"International Capital Mobility and Asset Substitutability: Some
Theory and Evidence on Recent Structural Changes." Technical Report
44, Bank of Canada, 1986.
3. Cavaglia, Stefano, "The Persistence of Real Interest
Differentials: A Kalman Filtering Approach." Journal of Monetary
Economics, June 1992, 429-43.
4. Dar, Atul, Saleh Amirkhalkhali and Samad Amirkhalkhali, "On
the Fiscal Policy Implications of Low Capital Mobility: Some Further
Evidence from Cross-Country, Time-Series Data." Southern Economic
Journal, July 1994, 169-90.
5. Feldstein, Martin and Charles Horioka, "Domestic Saving and
International Capital Flows," Economic Journal, June 1980, 314-29.
6. Frankel, Jeffrey. "Quantifying International Capital Mobility
in the 1980s," in International Finance: Contemporary Issues,
edited by Dilip K. Das. New York: Routledge, 1993.
7. ----- and Alan MacArthur, "Political vs. Currency Premia in
International Real Interest Differentials." European Economic
Review, June 1988, 1083-121.
8. Goldstein, Morris, Donald Mathieson and Timothy Lane. Determinants
and Systematic Consequences of International Capital Flows, IMF
Occasional Papers, No. 77, March 1991.
9. Goodwin, Barry and Thomas J. Grennes, "Real Interest
Equalization and the Integration of International Financial
Markets." Journal of International Money and Finance, February
1994, 107-24.
10. Kwiatkowski, Denis, Peter Phillips, Peter Schmidt, and Yongcheol
Shin, "Testing the Null Hypothesis of Stationarity Against the
Alternative of a Unit Root: How Sure are We that Economic Time Series
Have a Unit Root?" Journal of Econometrics, October/December 1992,
159-78.
11. Mark, Nelson, "Some Evidence on the International Inequality of Real Interest Rates." Journal of International Money and
Finance, June 1985, 189-208.
12. Mishkin, Fredric, "Are Real Interest Rates Equal Across
Countries? An Empirical Investigation of International Parity
Conditions." Journal of Finance, December 1984, 1345-58.
13. Phillips, Peter and Pierre Perron, "Testing for a Unit Root
in Time Series Regression." Biometrika, June 1988, 335-46.
14. Taylor, Mark P., "Covered Interest Parity: A High-Frequency
High-Quality Data Study." Economica, November 1987, 429-53.