Why parents and teachers may prefer punishment to encouragement for child education?
Lai, Ching-chong
I. introduction
Although educators and psychologists persistently advocate
encouragement rather than punishment for children's education, many
teachers and parents often argue that punishment is more effective than
encouragement to make a child study diligently. This issue is of
importance in the field of educational psychology, and some studies have
tried to explain the phenomenon from alternative points of view. This
note is a new attempt to furnish a preliminary solution for this
observed phenomenon from the economic perspective.(1)
The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows. The theoretical
framework is developed in section II. Section III investigates the
impact of punishment and encouragement on diligence. Some concluding
remarks are offered in section IV.
II. The Theoretical Framework
The optimization problem for a representative child is given by:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
s.t. S = [Alpha] + [Beta][F(T - l) - [Gamma]]; F[prime] [greater
than] 0, F[double prime] [less than] 0.(2)
Equation (1) states that the representative child seeks to maximize
his utility U, which depends positively on leisure I and encouragement
S. The encouragement may be something tangible (money) or intangible
(praise).(2) Leisure is specified as an element in the utility function
of a child to reflect the fact that students dislike studying at school
and doing homework,(3) just as leisure is an element in the utility
function of a worker which expresses his dislike for working.(4)
Equation (2) specifies how encouragement for studying is created. Define
T as the total time endowment, the production function for performance
in studying F then can be specified as an increasing function of
studying hours T - l. If his performance in studying F(T - l) exceeds
the given threshold level [Gamma], the child will enjoy encouragement
from parents and teachers. However, if his performance in studying F(T -
l) falls short of the given threshold level [Gamma], the child will
suffer punishment from parents and teachers. To generalize the analysis,
we specify that encouragement is composed of a component which is
independent of studying [Alpha] and a component which is related to the
performance of studying [Beta][F(T - l) - [Gamma]]. (5,6)
The constrained maximization problem reported in equations (1) and
(2) can be solved by setting up the Lagrange function L:
L = U(l, S) + [Lambda]{[Alpha] + [Beta][F(T - l) - [Gamma]] - S}, (3)
where [Lambda] is the Lagrange multiplier. The first-order conditions
for a maximum at optimal values [l.sup.*], [S.sup.*] and
[[Lambda].sup.*] are:
[L.sub.l] = [U.sub.l]([l.sup.*], [S.sup.*]) - [[Lambda].sup.*]
[Beta]F[prime] (T - [l.sup.*]) = 0, (4)
[L.sub.S] = [U.sub.S]([l.sup.*], [S.sup.*]) - [[Lambda].sup.*] = 0,
(5)
[L.sub.[Lambda]] = [Alpha] + [Beta][F(T - [l.sup.*]) - [Gamma]] -
[S.sup.*] = 0. (6)
The second-order condition requires that the following condition be
met:
D = 2[Beta]F[prime] [U.sub.Sl] - [([Beta]F[prime]).sup.2] [U.sub.SS]
- [U.sub.ll] - [Lambda][Beta]F[double prime] [greater than] 0. (7)
III. The Effects of Encouragement and Punishment
Now we are in a position to examine how the choice between leisure
and studying will respond to changes in encouragement-punishment
parameters [Alpha], [Beta], and [Gamma]. From equations (4)-(6), we have
the following comparative static results:
[Delta][l.sup.*]/[Delta][Alpha] = ([U.sub.lS] - [Beta]F[prime]
[U.sub.SS])/D [greater than] 0, (8)
[Delta][l.sup.*]/[Delta][Beta] = -([[Lambda].sup.*] F[prime]/D) +
[F(T - [l.sup.*]) - [Gamma]]([Delta][l.sup.*]/[Delta][Alpha]) [greater
than or equal to] [less than or equal to] 0, (9)
[Delta][l.sup.*]/[Delta][Gamma] =
-[Beta]([Delta][l.sup.*]/[Delta][Alpha]) [less than] 0. (10)
The results reported in equations (8)-(10) reveal some interesting
implications. In what follows we will discuss them respectively.
First, equation (8) indicates that, when leisure is a normal good, an
increase in the constant reward [Alpha] will induce more leisure and
less studying hours. As might be expected, a richer family will give
their children more monetary rewards which are independent of studying
effort. Teachers thus often find that students from richer families
display less diligence.(7)
Second, equation (9) states that the total effect of a rise in [Beta]
on leisure can be divided into the substitution effect and the income
effect.(8) The substitution effect -[[Lambda].sup.*] F[prime]/D is
negative. The income effect [F(T - [l.sup.*]) - [Gamma]]
([Delta][l.sup.*]/[Delta][Alpha]) is negative when the child is punished F (T - [l.sup.*]) - [Gamma] [less than] 0, and positive when the child
is encouraged F(T - [l.sup.*]) - [Gamma] [greater than] 0. As a
consequence, the total effect of a rise in [Beta] on leisure is
definitely negative under the punishment situation while the total
effect is ambiguous under the encouragement situation. This result may
explain the fact that some teachers and parents prefer punishment to
encouragement.
Finally, equation (10) indicates that students will allocate more
time to studying following an increase of the threshold level. This
conclusion can explain the phenomenon that students will display better
performance in studying if teachers demand a higher standard.
IV. Concluding Remarks
A main concern of modern parents and teachers is to discover what
educational method can improve their children's scholastic
performance. This topic is of importance in the field of educational
psychology, and some studies try to explain how punishment, on the one
hand, or encouragement, on the other hand, affect study habits. This
paper develops a simple economic model to interpret why punishment is
more effective than encouragement in increasing children's
diligence in studying. Based on the framework, three main conclusions
are drawn:
(i) If the children are given more monetary rewards which have
nothing to do with their scholastic performance, they will show less
diligence.
(ii) A rise in the proportional rate of monetary rewards will
definitely have a negative effect on leisure if the children are under
the punishment situation, while an ambiguous effect is revealed under
the encouragement situation.
(iii) The children will allocate more time to studying if parents and
teachers raise their threshold level of studying performance necessary
to avoid punishment.
Chung-cheng Lin Institute of Economics, Academia Sinica Taiwan,
Republic of China
Ching-chong Lai Sun Yat-Sen Institute for Social Sciences and
Philosophy, Academia Sinica Taiwan, Republic of China
1. The field of the economics of education mainly concerns the issues
of human capital theory, the calculation of rates of return to
education, the cost structures of education, finance for education, and
education and economic growth [1; 3; 6]. However, a burgeoning
literature suggests that labor supply theory will be useful to
understand the study effort of children. Owen [7] offers a comprehensive
survey.
2. This paper assumes that money and praise are equivalent forms of
encouragement, so that there is no difference in the child's
behavior depending on the form of encouragement.
3. In recent years psychologists and sociologists have undertaken
systematic studies concerning student attitudes towards study. The
studies find that students dislike studying. To take some examples,
Csikszentmihalyi and Larson [5, 39] examine middle-class students in a
"very good high school" with excellent teachers. They find
that the teenagers feel best when they are with their friends; in school
they are bored; at home they tune out. Covington [4] argues that
students dislike studying because tests, grades, and teacher comments
are all structured to provide estimates of the child's ability, and
for many students the result is that learning diminishes their
self-esteem. Furthermore, Owen [7] indicates that there are many other
activities that compete with study time. Students find that studying
interferes with other activities that they prefer, such as eating,
sports, hobbies, listening to music, taking naps, watching television,
and spending time with friends.
4. In Becker's [2] terminology, the proper elements in the
utility function are "commodities," which are produced by
combining leisure time with other inputs.
5. This paper does not consider parents' possible strategy
"do well and you can spell less time on homework."
6. It seems reasonable to assume that students intend to please not
only their parents (or teachers) but also their peers. Under such a
situation, it is plausible that it takes time for the students to please
their peers. This means that there is one more activity which competes
with study time and leisure. Such consideration will complicate the
model, but will not alter the basic outcomes.
7. The model ignores that the richer family may provide a better
learning environment for their children. To incorporate this idea, the
production function for studying should be modified as:
F(T - l, W); [Delta]F/[Delta](T - l) [greater than] 0,
[Delta]F/[Delta]W [greater than] 0, [[Delta].sup.2]F/[[Delta]W[Delta](T
-/)] [greater than] 0,
where W is the wealth of the family.
8. in equation (9), the first term on the right hand side is the
substitution effect, and the second term is the income effect.
References
1. Atkinson, G. B. J. The Economics of Education. London: Hodder and
Stoughton, 1983.
2. Becker, Gary S., "A Theory of the Allocation of Time."
Economic Journal, September 1965, 493-517.
3. Blaug, Mark. The Economic Value of Education: Studies in the
Economics of Education. Aldershot, U.K.: Edward Elgar, 1992.
4. Covington, Martin V. "The Motive for Self-Worth," in
Research on Motivation in Education: Student Motivation, edited by
Russell E. Ames and Carole Ames. Orlando: Academic Press, 1965.
5. Csikszentmihalyi, Mihaly and Reed Larson. Being Adolescent:
Conflict and Growth in the Teenage Years. New York: Basic Books, 1984.
6. Johnes, Geraint. The Economics of Education. New York: St.
Martin's Press, 1993.
7. Owen, John D. Why Our Kids Don't Study: An Economist's
Perspective. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1995.