The Winner-Take-All Society.
Walker, Douglas M.
By Robert H. Frank and Philip J. Cook. New York: The Free Press,
1995. Pp. x, 272. $25.00.
Professors Frank and Cook describe what they consider to be an
increasingly serious problem in the US. economy --
"winner-take-all" (WTA) markets. The first half of their book
describes examples of this type of market, one in which very few
participants are "successful." Those who do find material
success do so in a big way, while the other participants receive little
or no pecuniary reward for their efforts. Examples of WTA makets include
professional sports, art, acting and music, the legal profession, and
corporate management.
The authors argue that even when prospective WTA market
participants correctly estimate the risk-adjusted net benefits of WTA
work, too many people -- from a social perspective -- participate in
those markets. Many of the WTA market participants could have
alternatively been producing valuable goods or services in some other
industry, and hence, national income is lower than it otherwise would
have been [pp. 8-9].
The authors fail to give a convincing theoretical explanation of
why we should consider WTA market participation socially wasteful.
Workers choose to work in the industry which they expect will make them
best-off. Market wages, to an extent, reflect the relative social value
of output from each industry. But to argue that national income is lower
than it could have been if some had chosen different careers is trivial -- and in no way does it imply social waste.
Salary is not the only important factor in choosing a career, and
national income is not the only measure of social welfare. Is it correct
to label it "socially wasteful" for someone to play basketball
on high-school and college teams, with the hope of reaching the NBA?
Perhaps that person enjoys playing basketball. Frank and Cook
characterize an activity as socially wasteful if it does not immediately
increase tangible goods output in an economy. (Interestingly, in his
book Passions Within Reason [1988], Frank argues that in many
situations, non-pecuniary incentives are more important than money. He
seems to have changed his mind.)
Another major focus of The Winner-Take-All Society is the
importance of relative living standards (i.e., positional "arms
races") compared to absolute ones. While people certainly make some
decisions based on what others do (i.e., keeping up with the Joneses),
Prank and Cook seem to overstate the importance of this motivation:
Beyond some threshold, spending tends to be concentrated on second
homes,
premium automobiles, jewelry, and other luxury items. Since the
satisfaction
afforded by these items is largely social, or positional,
in nature, little would be sacrificed if there were an
across-the-board
reduction in luxury consumption. If, for example, overall spending
on
luxury automobiles were to decline, the satisfaction from driving
a
relatively' high-qualify automobile would remain largely the
same [p. 2151.
The authors ignore the fact that the hope of having the means to
purchase second homes and premium automobiles is a strong incentive to
work hard. People buy luxury goods for many reasons -- who is to
determine which purchases are legitimate and which are
"wasteful"? Would Frank and Cook object to my buying a $70
Claiborne shirt when I could buy a shirt for $5 at Wal-Mart? Is this an
example of "positional consumption" that should be
discouraged?
In arguing for government intervention to deter
"excessive" positional consumption, the authors explain that
WTA markets are not easily influenced by citizens:
Still less under any individual's control are the contents of
books,
movies, and television
programs. We are free to choose, of course, from the existing menu
of
items. But as
individuals we have virtually no control
over the contents of that menu [p. 205].
But, how can the authors expect our government to do a good job in
determining the relative wastefulness of consumption, when to many
people the government is a prototype of wasteful spending?
Frank and Cook point to flaws in the market process and suggest
action to slow the growth of WTA markets:
Whereas free marketeers maintain that market incentives lead to
socially
efficient results, our claim is that winner-take-all markets
attract too many
contestants, result in inefficient patterns of consumption and
investment,
and often degrade our culture. If these costs are to be avoided,
firms and
individuals must somehow be restrained from taking advantage of
readily
available profit opportunities [p. 19].
But market forces are not necessarily to blame. Competition, for
example, also occurs in many non-market institutions. Two cases that
receive substantial attention are university teaching and the legal
profession. Neither of these institutions is the result solely of market
forces. Although the authors cite the legal profession as one of the
worst WTA markets, they call on its close associate, the federal
government, to "correct" market incentives. The most effective
policies for discouraging participation in WTA markets and the purchase
of positional goods, in their opinion, are more progressive income taxes
or, even better, progressive consumption taxes (i.e., luxury taxes).
Toward the beginning of the book, Frank and Cook write, "The
critics of communism were right all along: The allocation of talent by
central bureaucracy is a recipe for economic disaster" [p. 7]. Yet,
this is exactly what the authors propose with their high taxes on WTA
market winners: ". . . the effect of taxing the highest incomes in
winner-take-all markets is to reduce the allocation of labor to such
markets; and this, we have seen, tends to increase society's total
income" [p. 123].
Although Frank and Cook offer little empirical support, their
arguments are well-presented and will sound plausible to the careless reader. Their purpose, it seems, is to create yet another "market
failure" requiring higher taxes. Prospective readers of The
Winner-Take-All Society should consider some other, more socially
productive, use of their time.