Scale elasticity versus scale efficiency in banking.
Israilevich, Philip R.
I. Introduction
In the early bank cost literature many of the studies found scale
elasticities significantly different from unity. As a result, the
authors suggested that changes in industry structure could produce cost
savings through increased efficiency. Recent bank cost studies improved
upon previous methodologies by utilizing flexible functional forms,
accounting for multiproduct production processes, estimating scale
measures at both the branch and firm level, distinguishing between
branch and unit bank technologies resulting from regulatory
restrictions, etc. The typical finding from the recent studies is that
relatively minor scale economies exist in banking since the scale
elasticity measure differs little from a value of unity. This reported
finding is usually followed by a general statement that banks operate
relatively efficiently with respect to the scale of production and that
the potential cost gains from exploiting scale advantages via merger or
growth activities appear to be relatively minor. The implication from
the conclusions drawn by the authors of numerous studies is that scale
elasticity and scale efficiency are essentially synonymous; the
derivation of one automatically provides an accurate or approximate
value for the other.
The purpose of this article is to bring attention to a common
confusion in the literature between two relatively straightforward
concepts: scale elasticity and scale efficiency. The bank production
process is one of the most extensively researched aspects of bank
behavior. Until recently, however, studies have not typically evaluated
scale efficiency.(10) Instead, scale elasticity estimates have been used
as a proxy for efficiency, and elasticity measures close to 1.0 are
taken to imply that scale inefficiency is trivial. Scale inefficiency is
typically assumed to be linearly related to the scale elasticity
measure; i.e., equal to one minus the elasticity measure. Empirically,
it is also assumed that scale elasticities which are found to be
insignificantly different from one in a statistical sense imply scale
efficiency. Both statements are incorrect. Yet, failure to distinguish
between the two concepts is common in the banking literature. For
example:
1. Humphrey [16, 47] states that technical inefficiencies (the
inefficient use of inputs) are on the order of . . . "31 to 34
percent. Such a cost reduction would be equivalent to a scale economy
value of .69 to .66."
2. Mester [21, 439] finds the estimated scale elasticity for a sample
of California S&Ls to be insignificantly different from one
indicating that "from the standpoint of costs alone, the typical
S&L would not benefit from changing the levels of (output)."(2)
These statements, however, are either incorrect or the basis used to
make the statements is insufficient to support them. Scale elasticity
and scale efficiency are two distinct concepts. An elasticity measure
near one does not necessarily imply small scale inefficiency; nor does a
large difference imply substantial scale inefficiency. Below we briefly
formalize the scale inefficiency measure and show the relationship
between scale elasticity and efficiency. For illustrative purposes we
empirically apply the new efficiency measure to a group of large U.S.
banks, and also apply it to the results of previous studies to highlight
the distinction between the two concepts, The findings reenforce the
point that using elasticity alone to determine or approximate scale
efficiency is inappropriate and can produce misleading conclusions
concerning inefficiency.(3) This is particularly true in an industry,
such as banking, in which there is a broad range in firm size.
II. Elasticity and Efficiency Measures
The scale elasticity measure, [Epsilon] = [Delta] ln C/[Delta] ln Q,
where C is cost and Q output, is a point elasticity associated with a
particular output level and indicates the relative change in cost
associated with an incremental change from this output level. Scale
inefficiency, I, can be measured as the aggregate cost of F inefficient
firms ([Epsilon] [not equal to] 1.0) relative to the cost of a single
efficient firm ([Epsilon] = 1.0), where F = the size of the efficient
relative to the inefficient one. That is, I = [F [center dot]
[C.sub.I]/[C.sub.E]] - 1.0, where [C.sub.I] and [C.sub.E] are the cost
of production at the inefficient and efficient firms, respectively.
Intuitively, the two concepts differ because they measure different
things: elasticity is related to incremental changes in output, and
inefficiency to the change in output required to produce at the minimum
efficient scale. The inefficiency measure is typically associated with
significantly larger output changes as one measures the difference in
total or average cost at distinct output levels. The scale elasticity at
the inefficient level of output suggests the initial path to the
efficient output level. However, the initial path itself is inadequate
to determine the efficient output. In Figure 1, the average cost
relationships for three production technologies are shown. Although each
produces the same degree of scale inefficiency, the path from the
inefficient level of production to the efficient one, and the scale
elasticity measure at the inefficient output level, are significantly
different. The scale elasticity measure at output [Q.sub.I] gives little
information concerning the level of scale inefficiency found in these
three technologies. Alternatively, Figure 2 presents average cost
relationships for three technologies which have the same point
elasticity at output level [Q.sub.I]. The three technologies, however,
exhibit significantly different levels of scale inefficiency for
production at this output level. The cost savings realized by an
incremental increase in output by a scale inefficient firm is irrelevant
for measuring inefficiency since this is not the savings realized by
producing at the efficient scale. The elasticity measure is important in
determining scale inefficiency only to the extent that it can be used to
derive the cost differential over a broader range of outputs, i.e.,
between the output of the scale efficient and inefficient firms. The
elasticity value is not even needed to calculate scale inefficiency if
direct information is available on average cost at the efficient and
inefficient levels of output.
More formally, below we derive a general measure of scale
inefficiency employing a standard translog cost function. Let
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
where P denotes factor prices, Z exogenous variables relevant to the
particular industry's production process, and the other variables
are as previously defined. For simplification, we rearrange equation
(1):
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
and allow the terms in each set of brackets in equation (2) to be
replaced by the coefficients a, b, and c, respectively. Therefore:
ln C = a + b(ln Q) + .5c[(ln Q).sup.2] (3)
represents the cost relationship. For simplicity, we normalize output
levels around the level produced by the inefficient firm so that
[Q.sub.I] = 1.0 and the output of the scale efficient firm, [Q.sub.E],
is a multiple, F, of [Q.sub.I]. For the inefficient firm,(4)
ln [C.sub.I] = a + b(ln [Q.sub.I]) + .5c[(ln [Q.sub.I]).sup.2] = a,
(4)
and the scale elasticity,
[[Epsilon].sub.I] = [Delta] ln [C.sub.I]/[Delta] ln [Q.sub.I] = b.
(5)
For the scale efficient firm,
ln [C.sub.E] = a + b ln(F [center dot] [Q.sub.I]) + .5c[[ln(F [center
dot] [Q.sub.I])].sup.2], (6)
and
[[Epsilon].sub.E] = [Delta] ln [C.sub.E]/[Delta] ln(F [center dot]
[Q.sub.I]) = 1.0. (7)
Realizing that [Q.sub.I] = 1.0, by taking the difference between
equation (4) and equation (6), and with substitution, it can be shown
that
I = [F [center dot] [C.sub.I]/[C.sub.E]] - 1.0 = [F.sup..5(1 - b)] -
1.0. (8)
Since b is the elasticity coefficient resulting from the
normalization of output around that of the inefficient firm, the
inefficiency measure in equation (8) can be generalized:(5)
I = [F [center dot] [C.sub.I]/[C.sub.E]] - 1.0 = [F.sup..5(1 -
[[Epsilon].sub.I])] - 1.0. (9)
The scale inefficiency measure, in general, is obviously not equal to
1 - [[Epsilon].sub.I]. In fact, information about scale elasticity alone
is inadequate to derive the inefficiency measure because of the integral
role played by the output differential between the efficient and
inefficient firms.
Alternatively, since F is determined by the characteristics of the
cost function, we can solve for the level of scale inefficiency in terms
of the cost parameters only. Solving for F in terms of c (the second
derivative of ln C) from equations (6) and (7), and substituting into
equation (9) gives
I = [e.sup.(.5/c)[(1 - [[Epsilon].sub.I]).sup.2]] - 1.0. (10)
That is, scale inefficiency is a function of the first and second
derivatives of the cost function with respect to output. Setting
equation (10) equal to 1 - [[Epsilon].sub.I] we can solve for c to see
when the two measures are equal:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
For [[Epsilon].sub.I] [not equal to] 1.0, there is only one point on
the cost function corresponding to I = (1 - [[Epsilon].sub.I]). For
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], larger elasticities produce
inefficiencies less than [Mathematical Expression Omitted]; and
elasticities less than [Mathematical Expression Omitted] produce
inefficiencies greater than [Mathematical Expression Omitted]. Similar
conjectures can be made for [Mathematical Expression Omitted]. Figure 3
presents the relationship between scale inefficiency and elasticity for
three different values of the second derivative.(6)
Similarly, empirical differences exist in the two cost concepts. An
estimated scale elasticity value which is insignificantly different from
unity does not imply scale inefficiency is insignificantly different
from zero. That is, not only do the measures differ, but the calculated
standard errors also differ. For example, from equation (5), at the
sample mean the statistical difference of the elasticity measure from a
value of unity depends entirely on the standard error of the estimated
coefficient b. The standard error for the scale inefficiency measure,
I = [e.sup.(.5/c)[(1 - b).sup.2]] - 1.0, (12)
differs as it depends on the variance and covariance of the estimates
for coefficients b and c. That is:
var(I) [approximately equal to] [([Delta]I/[Delta]b).sup.2] [center
dot] var(b) + [([Delta]I/[Delta]c).sup.2] [center dot] var(c) +
([Delta]I/[Delta]b) [center dot] ([Delta]I/[Delta]c) [center dot] cov(b,
c). (13)
Thus, tests for statistical significance for the two concepts can
also differ substantially.
III. Supporting Evidence
Having shown that scale efficiency and elasticity are distinct
concepts, we next present evidence of differences in the two measures. A
translog cost function, equation (1), with traditional parameter restrictions was estimated using 1987 data for 164 banks which were
holding company members and were ranked in the top 500 U.S. banks for
the previous twenty years. Exogenous variables include holding company
affiliation and the number of branches. The variable definitions,
estimation results, and properties of the estimates are presented in
Table I.(7) Scale elasticities for output [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE I
OMITTED] quartiles are presented in Table II. The estimated relationship
is a well behaved cost function having all the desirable properties, and
similar scale estimates to that found in the bank cost literature,
suggesting that our findings are not driven by unique cost
characteristics.(8) However, more is required to evaluate scale
inefficiency. Table III presents point scale elasticities for various
observations. Viewing specific data points obviously reveals detail not
available in the calculations based on output quartiles. Significant
economies of scale are found for the smaller banks, and diseconomies set
in at approximately $3.3 billion in output. From equation (10),
calculated values for scale inefficiency for these same observations are
presented in column 4. As implied by equation (11), scale inefficiency
is greater than 1 - [[Epsilon].sub.I] for some observations, and less
for others. Obviously, as suggested in Figure 3, the magnitude of the
differences in other cost studies will vary with the relevant cost
characteristics.
Table II. Scale Elasticity Estimates
Output Quartile Output (billions) Mean [Epsilon]
1 [less than]1.2 .85
2 1.2-2.5 .92
3 2.5-5.3 .99
4 [greater than]5.3 1.13
entire sample .98
Notes: [Epsilon] denotes scale elasticity.
As further evidence of the distinction between the two concepts,
Table IV presents the findings of a number of bank cost studies, and
presents estimates of scale inefficiency based on the assumptions listed
in the note to the table. The distinction between the two measures is
more pronounced in some of these studies.(9) This occurs because of the
sample range and particular [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE III OMITTED] cost
function characteristics. The findings again suggest that inefficiency
for specific firms can be substantially greater than that typically
referred to in the bank cost literature. Even minor deviations from a
value of one for the scale elasticity measure can be associated with
significant inefficiency. Again, the elasticity measure is calculated
based on incremental changes in output. To generate scale efficiency
measures, the output change required to reach the efficient scale of
production, as shown in Tables III and IV, may be quite large.
IV. Concluding Comments
The purpose of this note has been to clarify a common confusion in
the banking literature. Use of the scale elasticity measure alone to
approximate the extent of scale efficiency is inadequate. They are two
distinct concepts. We derive the inefficiency measure and provide an
empirical illustration to distinguish between the two concepts. A review
of earlier studies also shows significantly more scale inefficiency than
implied by the elasticity measure.
What do the results imply about the propensity for merger activity in
banking?(10) The evidence suggests that, for certain banks, there are
significant scale efficiency gains to be achieved by growing via
internal means or by merger.(11) Rhoades [25] found that between
1960-83, over [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE IV OMITTED] 93 percent of acquired
banks had assets less than $100 million. Nearly all bank cost studies
find scale advantages up to this size. Additionally, equation (9)
indicates that efficiency gains increase as the difference between the
output levels of the efficient and inefficient firms increases, i.e., F.
Viewing bank merger data for the second quarter of 1991, for example,
the largest size differential between the acquiring and acquired firm
was 651; i.e., the acquirer was 651 times as large as the acquiree. The
mean differential was 69; see Matthews [20]. Thus, the size
differentials in bank acquisitions appear to be quite large suggesting
significant potential gains.(12)
The efficiency gains, however, may not be realized by the larger
banks which recently have been so aggressive in pursuing acquisitions.
In fact, the larger banks in most cost studies exhibit constant returns
to scale or inefficiency resulting from operating under diseconomies of
scale. Instead, it is the acquisition of small, inefficient banks, which
will improve industry inefficiency.(13) However, as we have shown here,
these potential gains cannot be detected by simply evaluating the scale
elasticity measure.
1. Recent exceptions include Betger, Hunter, and Timme [6] and some
of the accompanying articles, Ferrier and Lovell [13], and Aly,
Grabowski and Pasurka [1]. For a review of the banking cost literature
see Evanoff and Israilevich [11]. For an early general discussion of
multiproduct cost analysis see Cowing and Holtmann [9].
2. Numerous additional examples exist. Comparing scale and non-scale
related inefficiencies in banking, Berger and Humphrey [4] evaluate
scale efficiency by contrasting the scale elasticity estimate to a value
of 1.0. Based on the finding of scale elasticity measures which
typically exceed .95 they state that non-scale inefficiencies (technical
and allocative inefficiency) of approximately 25% "dominate scale .
. . effects, which are measured to be on the order of 5% or less."
Mester [23, 558] finds slight scale economies and claims that "the
result indicates banks are operating at a scale slightly less than
minimum efficient." Analyzing savings and loans, Mester [22, 270]
finds a scale elasticity of .95 for the representative firm and asserts
that it "is operating within 5% of minimum efficient scale. Thus,
only small efficiency gains are possible from increasing the scale of
operations . . ." Other examples include Clark [8, 67], Dowling and
Philippatos [10, 245], Humphrey [17, 36], Berger, Hanweck, and Humphrey
[3, 513], or Benston [2, 541].
3. It should be emphasized that we are evaluating potential
efficiency gains from a production technology perspective only. There
may indeed be impediments to actually achieving the efficient scale of
production, e.g., local market demand may be insufficient to warrant the
expansion of output. However, past studies relating scale elasticity and
scale efficiency have taken this same perspective.
4. Neither the simplification in equation (2) nor the output
normalization will alter the analysis. The chosen functional form,
however, is important. The translog function is discussed because it is
the form most commonly used in cost studies.
5. As with the scale elasticity measure, the inefficiency measure is
functional form specific. For the quadratic form, C = a + b [center dot]
Q + .5c [center dot] [Q.sup.2], the inefficiency measure will equal [(b
+ c [center dot] [Q.sub.1])/(b + c [center dot] [Q.sub.E])]
[1/[[Epsilon].sub.1]] and can similarly be derived for alternative
forms.
6. The middle relationship corresponds to the empirical results
discussed later in the text.
7. The empirical$example should be considered a pedagogical device
for illustrative purposes only. Use of an aggregate output measure can
be criticized for incorrectly specifying bank output, and can result in
biases toward finding greater scale advantages. However, our purpose is
to illustrate the difference between the two concepts; not to accurately
capture the intricacies of the bank production process. The aggregate
output measure simplifies the model and in no way distorts the
distinction between scale elasticity and scale inefficiency. However,
multiproduct production does make the analysis of scale economies more
complex since the product mix, and resulting optimal input mix, can vary
with bank size. The ray scale measure, [[Sigma].sub.i] [Delta] ln
C/[Delta] ln [Q.sub.i], assumes banks expand along an output ray with
product-mix held constant. While this enables us to use the formulas
developed here to analyze scale inefficiency by using the ray scale
measure and summing across outputs to obtain the second derivative, this
is obviously a simplification and brings into question the usefulness of
the ray scale measure in evaluating output expansion to levels very far
removed from the point at which it is evaluated.
8. All regularity conditions are satisfied: positivity and
homogeneity by model construction, monotonicity by having all predicted
factor shares positive, and concavity by having factor shares range
between four and 96 percent (well within our predicted range). See
Evanoff, Israilevich, and Merris [12], particularly footnote 10.
9. The studies considered in Table IV are each relatively current and
utilize a flexible functional form. However, the apparent misconception between scale elasticity and efficiency is also present in earlier bank
cost studies. Benston [2] states that the elasticities estimated for
deposit accounts and loans were close to one implying that
"efficiency of operations is not largely a function of bank
size." He reports cost elasticities for the sample means in 1960,
the middle year of the analysis, for demand deposits, time deposits,
mortgage loans, installment loans, and business loans as 0.986 and
0.955, 0.959, 0.881 and 0.978, respectively. However, comparing the per
unit cost of the average bank to that of smaller banks reveals scale
inefficiency for the services of approximately 28, 10, 10, 30, and 41
percent, respectively. In some instances these figures understate the
extent of the inefficiency because data on the smaller banks were not
available. Significantly greater inefficiency existed in the sample if
comparisons were made relative to banks other than the average bank and
for other years. For example, for business loans in 1960 the within
sample inefficiency was over 100 percent.
10. Whereas we emphasize the importance of accounting for
inefficiency instead of elasticity alone, Caves, Khalilzadeh-Shirazi and
Porter [7] took a somewhat similar approach in analyzing entry barriers.
They argued that viewing minimum efficient scale as a measure of the
barrier was inadequate. One also had to account for the extent of the
disadvantage to potential entrants; their cost disadvantage ratio.
Simply viewing the output level at which efficient scale is achieved
does not indicate the true extent of the barrier. Similarly, simply
viewing the elasticity measure to detect the extent of potential gains
from achieving scale efficiency is inadequate.
11. The banking literature also suggests that potential gains from
the elimination of X-inefficiency exists in most bank mergers, but are
frequently not realized [26; 29; 14; 5].
12. It has been argued that the scale elasticity measure may fairly
accurately indicate the marginal gains from changes in bank size that
actually occur [4]. This may or may not be accurate. However, if the
merger data discussed here is representative of the population of
mergers, it casts doubt on the contention. If one is interested in
evaluating scale efficiency, the direct measure (of which the scale
elasticity measure is one component) is a more appropriate measure. It
should also be emphasized that the efficiency gains we are discussing
are those resulting from altering the size of the inefficient firm to
achieve an appropriate scale of production, e.g., by merger. One could
also view the gains of the acquiring firm in a merger or the net gains
resulting from gains (losses) by both parties.
13. The public policy implications carry a number of caveats. It is
assumed, for example, that the cost relationship and outputs are
properly modeled in these studies, input prices are held constant, etc.
However, these are the same caveats which have existed in the past when
cost studies were used to make public policy recommendations based on
the belief that no scale inefficiency existed. It may be that analysis
of balance sheet information does not allow the researcher to capture
the true characteristics of bank production. It is also possible that
the gains from scale may be partially offset by other factors. The
average cost across various size groups of banks have been shown to be
remarkably similar; see Humphrey [16]. In evaluating perspective
acquisitions, the parties involved and regulators obviously need to
consider more than scale advantages alone.
References
1. Aly, J. Y., Richard Grabowski, Carl Pasurka, and Nanda Rangan,
"Technical, Scale, and Allocative Efficiencies in U.S. Banking: An
Empirical Investigation." Review of Economies and Statistics, May
1990, 211-18.
2. Benston, George J., "Economies of Scale and Marginal Costs in
Banking Operations." The National Banking Review, June 1965,
507-49.
3. Berger, Allen N., Gerald A. Hanweck, and David B. Humphrey,
"Competitive Viability in Banking." Journal of Monetary
Economics, December 1987, 501-20.
4. Berger, Allen N. and David B. Humphrey, "The Dominance of
Inefficiencies Over Scale and Product Mix Economies in Banking."
Journal of Monetary Economics, August 1991, 117-48.
5. -----, "Megamergers in Banking and the Use of Cost Efficiency
as an Antitrust Defense." Antitrust Bulletin, Fall 1992, 541-600.
6. Berger, Allen N., William C. Hunter, and Stephen G. Timme,
"The Efficiency of Financial Institutions: A Review and Preview of
Research Past, Present, and Future." Journal of Banking and
Finance, April 1993, 221-50.
7. Caves, R. E., J. Khalilzadeh-Shirazi, and M. E. Porter,
"Scale Economies in Statistical Analyses of Market Power."
Review of Economics and Statistics, May 1975, 133-40.
8. Clark, Jeffrey A., "Estimation of Economies of Scale in
Banking Using a Generalized Functional Form." Journal of Money,
Credit, and Banking, February 1984, 53-67.
9. Cowing, Thomas G. and Alphonse G. Holtmann, "Multiproduct
Short-run Hospital Cost Functions: Empirical Evidence and Policy
Implications From Cross-section Data." Southern Economic Journal,
January 1983, 236-48.
10. Dowling, William A. and George C. Philippatos, "Economies of
Scale in the U.S. Savings and Loan Industry." Applied Economics,
February 1990, 236-48.
11. Evanoff, Douglas D. and Philip R. Israilevich, "Productive
Efficiency in Banking" Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve Bank
of Chicago, July 1991, 11-32.
12. -----, -----, and Randall C. Merris, "Relative Efficiency,
Technical Change, and Economies of Scale for Large Commercial
Banks." Journal of Regulatory Economics, September 1990, 281-98.
13. Ferrier, Gary D. and C. A. Knox Lovell, "Measuring Cost
Efficiency in Banking: Econometric and Linear Programing Evidence."
Journal of Econometrics, December 1990, 229-45.
14. Fixler, Dennis J. and Kimberly D. Zieschang, "An Index
Number Approach to Measuring Bank Efficiency: An Application to
Mergers." Journal of Banking and Finance, April 1993, 437-50.
15. Gilligan, Thomas W., Michael L. Smirlock, and William Marshall,
"Scale and Scope Economies In The Multi-product Banking Firm."
Journal of Monetary Economics, May 1984, 393-405.
16. Humphrey, David B., "Cost Dispersion and the Measurement of
Economies in Banking" Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond, May 1987, 24-38.
17. -----, "Why Do Estimates of Bank Scale Economies
Differ?" Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond,
September 1990, 38-50.
18. Hunter, William C., Stephen G. Timme, and Won Keun Yang, "An
Examination of Cost Subadditivity and Multiproduct Production in Large
U.S. Banks." Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, March 1990,
504-25.
19. Lawrence, Colin and Robert Shay. "Technology and Financial
Intermediation in a Multiproduct Banking Firm: An Econometric Study of
U.S. Banks, 1979-82," in Technological Innovation, Regulation, and
the Monetary Economy, edited by Colin Lawrence and Robert Shay.
Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1986, pp. 53-92.
20. Matthews, Gordon, "Latest Mergers Won't Dry Up
Overcapacity." American Banker, July 9, 1991.
21. Mester, Loretta J., "A Multiproduct Cost Study of Savings
and Loans." Journal of Finance, June 1987, 423-45.
22. -----, "Agency Costs Among Savings and Loans." Journal
of Financial Intermediation, June 1991, 257-78.
23. -----, "Traditional and Nontraditional Banking: An
Information-theoretic Approach." Journal of Banking and Finance,
June 1992, 545-66.
24. Noulas, Athanasios G., Subhash C. Ray, and Stephen M. Miller,
"Returns to Scale and Input Substitution for Large U.S.
Banks." Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, February 1990,
94-108.
25. Rhoades, Stephen A., "Mergers and Acquisitions by Commercial
Banks." Staff Study, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, 142, January 1985.
26. -----, "Efficiency Effects of Horizontal (In-market) Bank
Mergers." Journal of Banking and Finance, April 1993, 411-22.
27. Shaffer, Sherrill, "Scale Economies in Multiproduct
Firms." Bulletin of Economic Research, May 1984, 51-58.
28. -----. "A Revenue-restricted Cost Study of 100 Large
Banks." Unpublished Research Paper, Federal Reserve Bank of New
York, 1988.
29. -----, "Can Megamergers Improve Bank Efficiency?"
Journal of Banking and Finance, April 1993, 423-36.