Differences in state unemployment rates: the role of labor and product market structural shifts.
Rickman, Dan S.
I. Introduction
State unemployment rates diverged dramatically in the 1980s.
Differing unemployment rates across states are an important public
policy concern because of equity concerns and the pure human
consequences of higher unemployment. Moreover, at the national level, a
greater dispersion in state and regional unemployment rates can increase
the natural rate of unemployment and shift the Phillips curve out
because of an inefficient allocation of the labor force [3; 38].
One possible cause for the divergence in unemployment rates is
national industrial restructuring. U.S. industrial restructuring was
suggested by Lilien [26] as a cause for the rise in the national
unemployment rate. Moreover, national restructuring can have
differential impacts across states because states can have dramatically
different mixes of industries from each other. One of the difficulties
of national restructuring from a regional perspective is that it is
difficult to avoid. On the other hand, if regional differences in
unemployment are due to state idiosyncratic causes, state and local
public policy can potentially play a more active role. For example, the
economic problems that plagued the Northeast and California during the
early 1990s have been typically attributed to national downsizing in the
defense industries. Conversely, economic problems in these states may
have been driven by factors that are located within the state, such as
the collapse of their real estate markets.
Even beyond the issue of national restructuring, the 1980s
represented a structural break in relative regional economic
performances. Though Neumann and Topel [35] show that state unemployment
rates can be very persistent, even over the course of decades, state
unemployment rates for the mid-1980s are not strongly correlated with
their respective unemployment rates from the 1970s or the 1990s. For
example, based on data introduced later in the paper, the correlation of
the 1977 and 1987 state unemployment rates is -0.055, while the
correlation between 1977 and 1992 state unemployment rates is 0.74.(1)
Thus, the high correlation of state unemployment rates between the 1970s
and 1990s seems to represent a return to historical patterns observed by
Neumann and Topel. Moreover, annual measures of the coefficient of
variation of the 48 contiguous state unemployment rates rise sharply
beginning in the early 1980s, peak in the late 1980s, and then fall back
to the levels experienced during the 1970s. This also indicates that
there was a structural break in the 1980s and that long-run patterns
reemerged in the early 1990s.
This study advances previous state unemployment research by unifying
several possible causes of unemployment into one empirical framework.
First, by using shift-share analysis, we separate a state's
employment growth rate into the portion due to national factors, such as
industrial restructuring, and a separate portion due to state-specific
idiosyncratic factors. This allows us to assess the relative roles of
national restructuring and state-specific factors as causes for
unemployment rates to vary cross-sectionally across states within a
given time period and over time within a given state. Another closely
associated issue examined is whether workers who lose their jobs to
national restructuring have less options for finding work elsewhere than
if they lose their jobs to state-specific causes. With the exceptions of
Gallaway [12] and Treyz et al. [40], there has been little examination
of both interindustry labor mobility and interregional mobility
together, and none related to unemployment.
Second, we also separate earnings into a wage-mix component that
arises from the industrial composition of the state and a
wage-competitiveness component. This allows us to better separate wait
unemployment effects from cost competitiveness effects. Third, while
carefully controlling for employment growth and wage structure, we also
utilize the within state variance of sectoral employment growth rates to
account for matching difficulties for workers and firms that can occur
when a large number of workers are forced to change sectors. This is
closely associated with the analysis of Neumann and Topel [35] at the
state level and Lilien [26] at the national level. Fourth, we consider
data from 1972 to the early 1990s to fully evaluate the industrial
restructuring of the 1980s.
Finally, to avoid spurious relationships between the above variables
and state unemployment rates, and to identify other state-specific
factors behind unemployment, we appraise a multitude of other possible
causes for unemployment identified in previous studies including
unionization, unemployment insurance, and demographic differences across
states that can influence a given state's natural rate of
unemployment [6; 9; 17; 21; 27; 28; 30; 32; 35; 37]. Thus, by
simultaneously considering more factors than has typically been the
case, the results are less subject to an omitted variable bias.(2)
In what follows, section II presents the underlying theoretic model
and empirical methodology. Section III contains the empirical results,
while specification issues are addressed in section IV. The final
section presents some concluding thoughts.
II. Theoretical Considerations
The unemployment rate is a reduced form function of the factors that
affect labor demand and labor supply. These factors can broadly be
categorized as industry or product market variables (IND),
non-demographic labor market variables (LABOR), demographic variables
(DEMOG), and regional characteristics (REGION). Thus, unemployment for
state i in time period t may be written as
[U.sub.it] = [Alpha] + [Beta]IND + [Gamma]LABOR + [Omega]DEMOG +
[Psi]REGION + [[Sigma].sub.i] + [[Sigma].sub.t] + [e.sub.it], (1)
where [Alpha] is the constant term, [[Sigma].sub.i] and
[[Sigma].sub.t] are state and time fixed effects and [e.sub.it] is an
error term. [Beta], [Gamma], [Omega], and [Psi] represent coefficient vectors. However, the error term [e.sub.it] could exhibit first-order
autocorrelation. This can be represented as
[e.sub.it] = [Rho][e.sub.it-1] + [v.sub.it], (2)
where [v.sub.it] is i.i.d. and [Rho] is the degree of first-order
autocorrelation that is assumed constant across all states.
Variable definitions and sources are shown in Table I. Unemployment
rates and the independent variables are measured for the 48 contiguous
states from 1972-91. The independent variables and their hypothesized
influence on unemployment are described below.
A primary factor in determining unemployment differences is
employment growth. Indeed, Abraham [1] and Medoff [31] argue that
increased regional dispersion in employment demand is one reason that
the national natural rate of unemployment drifted higher in the 1970s.
For instance, if a state has a mix of industries that are faring
relatively better at the national level, then state employment should
increase relatively. However, employment growth at the regional level
may not reduce the unemployment rate. This can occur because in-migrants
may absorb all the new jobs [7], leaving unemployment unaffected.(3)
Moreover, different sources of employment growth or decline may have
different effects on unemployment. To investigate this, employment
growth is broken into two parts using the shift-share method. Stevens
and Moore [36] provide a thorough description of the shift-share method.
First, state employment growth that would occur if its industries grew
at their respective national rates is calculated (INDMIX).(4) Second,
the remaining employment growth, or state idiosyncratic change (COMPETE)
is calculated.(5) This component may reflect employment growth due to
state competitiveness or state-specific restructuring. To allow for more
complex dynamics, the lags of INDMIX and COMPETE are included
(INDMIX_LAG, COMPETE_LAG).
INDMIX and COMPETE may have differing impacts on unemployment to the
extent that worker mobility across industries differs from their
mobility across regions. If workers have limited mobility across
industries [26], the impact on unemployment will be greater if the loss
of employment occurs because of national restructuring (i.e., the
magnitude of the INDMIX coefficient will be larger). This follows
because there is less incentive for workers to migrate out of the region
if their industry is in national decline and this causes unemployment to
rise. On the other hand, workers displaced by state-specific employment
changes have a better chance of obtaining employment in their industry
outside the region. Thus, there is greater incentive to migrate, leaving
unemployment relatively unchanged.
Table I. Variable Definitions and Sources
VARIABLE DEFINITION AND SOURCE
UNEMP. RATE The civilian unemployment rate for each state.
Source: [46].
INDMIX The state's employment growth rate if employment
in the state's two-digit industries were growing
at their respective average national industry
employment growth rates for the non-farm private
sector. Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA).
COMPETE The difference between the state's actual non-farm
private sector employment growth rate and the
industrial mix employment growth rate (INDMIX).
(COMPETE = ACTUAL STATE GROWTH RATE - INDMIX)
Source: BEA.
INDVAR The employment weighted variance of two-digit
non-farm private sector employment growth rates.
To avoid possible wild fluctuations due to very
small industries in small states, industries with
employment less than 500 were excluded from the
calculation. Source: BEA.
WAGEMIX The real average annual earnings per worker
(1000s) in the state if each of the non-farm
private sector industries in the state paid their
respective national average industry earnings per
worker. The earnings were deflated by the U.S.
Consumer Price Index (1982-84 = 100). Source: BEA
and [45].
WAGE_COMP The difference between real actual non-farm
private sector average annual earnings per worker
(1000s) in the state and the real-wage mix wage
(WAGEMIX).
HERFIN The two-digit industry employment Herfindahl index
which is the sum over all non-farm private sector
industries of the square of employment share in
percent accounted for by that industry. Source:
BEA.
INDUSTRY SHARES The shares of total civilian employment in the
state that are accounted for by agriculture
(FARM); manufacturing (MANU); mining (MINING);
construction (CONST); transportation and public
utilities (TRANS); finance, insurance, and real
estate (FIRE); and all government (GOVT). Source:
BEA.
MALE_LF% The percent of total civilian employment in the
state that is accounted for by males. For some of
the smaller states, male employment was
unavailable for 1972-75. In these cases, the
earliest year where exact data was available was
interpolated with data from the 1970 census.
Source: BEA and [42; 46].
BLACK_POP% The percent of the population in the state that is
black. Data was interpolated using 1970, 1980, and
1990 as endpoints. Source: [45].
MARRIED% The percent of women over the age of 16 that are
married. Data was interpolated using 1970, 1980,
and 1990 as endpoints. Source: [42].
CHILD6_MAR The percent of women over the age of 16 that are
married with children under the age of 7. Data was
interpolated using 1970, 1980, and 1990 as end
points. Source: [42].
CHILD6_NONMAR The percent of women over the age of 16 that are
not married with children under the age of 7. Data
was interpolated using 1970, 1980, and 1990 as end
points. Source: [42].
AGE65% The percent of the population that is 65 years old
or older. Source: [43].
AGE14% The percent of the population that is 14 years old
or younger. Source: [43].
AGE15_19% The percent of the population that is between the
ages of 15 and 19. Source: [43].
HS_GRAD The percent of the population over the age of 24
that are high school graduates. Data was
interpolated using 1970, 1980, and 1990 as end
points. Source: [45].
COLL_GRAD The percent of the population over the age of 24
that are college graduates. Data was interpolated
using 1970, 1980, and 1990 as end points. Source:
[45].
BLUE_COLL The percent of civilian employment that are blue
collar employees. For 1972-75, because exact
figures were unavailable, the data was derived by
interpolating the 1976 figure with the 1970 Census
figure. Source: [42; 46].
UNION% The percent of the civilian labor force that are
union members. Source: [16; 45].
UI_BEN The real average weekly unemployment insurance
benefit for each state using the CPI as the
deflator. Source: [45; 47].
UI_COV The percent of civilian employment that is covered
by unemployment insurance in each state. Source:
[45; 47].
POPDEN Annual population density of the state. Source:
[45].
METRO% Annual percent of the state's population that
resides in a metropolitan area. Source: [45].
The wage rate in a region may also affect its unemployment rate. For
example, there may be a hedonic wage-unemployment tradeoff [14; 39] or
there may be wait unemployment where workers queue for high-wage jobs
[15; 37]. However, Blanchard and Katz [7] point out that increases in
labor demand can simultaneously increase wage and reduce unemployment.
Thus, the association between wages and the unemployment rate is
ambiguous. It should be noted though; to the extent that employment
growth can be identified as increased labor demand, inclusion of
employment growth in the equation controls for labor demand's
effect on wages and the unemployment rate.
Since the wage rate for a region is influenced by its mix of
industries, the wage rate is separated into two parts. First, the wage
rate that would result if each of the state's industries paid their
respective national average wage rate is calculated (WAGEMIX).(6)
WAGEMIX, for the most part, should capture wait unemployment influences.
Next, the state competitiveness wage effect (WAGE_ COMP) is calculated
as the difference between the state's actual earnings and WAGEMIX.
WAGE_COMP, for the most part, reflects cost effects on labor demand.
Finally, the lags of WAGEMIX and WAGE_ COMP are included to capture more
complex dynamics (WAGEMIX_LAG, WAGE_COMP_LAG).
Not only does national and state-specific restructuring affect
relative state employment growth rates, it influences the dispersion of
industry growth rates within each state. Even when employment is not
declining, matching difficulties for employers and employees can arise
when there is high dispersion in industry growth rates. In turn, the
large number of employees that must change sectors increases frictional
unemployment [13; 17; 35].(7) In contrast to previous studies, which
based their dispersion measures on one-digit categories, a two-digit
employment weighted variance of employment growth across the
state's industries (INDVAR) is calculated. Two-digit categories are
used because one-digit categories can mask significant restructuring
within each one-digit category.(8)
Similarly, the diversity of employment opportunities in a state may
affect the unemployment rate [27; 35]. The more diverse an economy, the
more readily employment reductions in any given sector can be absorbed
into other sectors. Diversity of employment is measured by a two-digit
industry employment Herfindahl index (HERFIN).
Employment concentrations in particular sectors may have an
additional influence on the unemployment rate. Cyclically sensitive
industries such as manufacturing can have greater variations in
employment [29] or employment mobility may be limited between certain
sectors. Consistent with previous studies [6; 27; 32; 37], this is
controlled for by including employment shares by sector: agriculture
(FARM); manufacturing (MANU); mining (MINING); construction (CONST);
transportation and public utilities (TRANS); finance, insurance, and
real estate (FIRE); and government (GOVT); where trade and services are
omitted to avoid perfect collinearity.
The percent of the labor force that is unionized (UNION) may also
affect the unemployment rate by increasing wages and wait unemployment
[6; 37]. Offsetting these impacts is the possibility that union workers
are more productive [11] making the net effect ambiguous [13].
Similarly, the availability and generosity of unemployment insurance may
be positively related to the unemployment rate because it reduces the
worker's cost of unemployment or increases their reservation
wage.(9) The availability and generosity of state unemployment insurance
programs are measured by the real average weekly unemployment benefit
(UI_BEN) and the percent of the labor force covered by unemployment
insurance (UI_COV).
There are several demographic variables included that influence labor
demand and labor supply. First, we include the percent of the
labor-force that is male (MALE_LF%), which is expected to be negatively
related to the unemployment rate because males tend to have a greater
attachment to the labor-force.(10) The percent of the population that is
black (BLACK_POP%) is included to capture potential effects caused by
discrimination or by differences in tastes and preferences for market
work. The percent of females above the age of 16 that are married
(MARRIED%) is included to capture the possibility that married women
withdraw from the labor-force. Similarly, women with young children may
be more likely to withdraw from the labor-force. This is captured by the
percent of women over 16 years old that are married and have children
under 7 years old or who are not married and have children under the age
of 7 (CHILD6_MAR, CHILD6_NONMAR). Percent of the population that is over
64 years old, under 15 years old, and between 15 and 19 years old are
also included in the specification (AGE65%, AGE14%, AGE15_19%) to
control for the age structure and quality of the labor-force.
Three variables are included to control for the human capital of the
labor-force. The percent of the population above the age of 24 who are
high school graduates (HS_GRAD) and who are college graduates
(COLL_GRAD) are included. In particular, the share of the labor-force
that are college graduates should be inversely related to the
unemployment rate through its positive influence on labor demand. Also,
college graduates are geographically more mobile. The percent of the
labor-force that are blue collar workers (BLUE_COLL) is also included as
a measure of human capital.
To control for urbanization, population density (POPDEN) and the
percent of the state's population that lives in a metropolitan area
(METRO%) are included. For instance, amenities can differ between urban
and rural areas where local amenities and the unemployment rate are
positively related [28]. Alternatively, employer and employee matching
problems may be mitigated in urban areas because of their greater
diversity of employment opportunities.
Dummies for the Northeast, Midwest, and West (the South is the
omitted category) are also included to account for differences in
regional labor markets or in total regional amenities which influence
migration patterns (i.e., people tradeoff amenities with a greater
likelihood of employment). In fact, industry mix and labor markets can
differ so much across states that Murphy and Hofler [34] suggest that it
is improper to pool all of the states into one regression specification.
Fortunately, our specification controls for these and a multitude of
other factors making it unlikely that unaccounted for differences across
states will bias our results. Annual fixed effects are included to
measure national cyclical effects on state unemployment rates. Thus, the
resulting coefficients measure the impact on state unemployment rates
net of aggregate cyclical conditions.
III. Empirical Results
Column (1) of Table II presents the means and standard deviations for
the variables. Column (2) presents the ordinary least square (OLS)
estimates for state unemployment rates. The OLS results assume that
there are no state fixed effects and no autocorrelation ([[Sigma].sub.i]
= 0, [Rho] = 0). The OLS results capture both cross-sectional and
time-series differences in the independent variables. However, the
first-order autocorrelation of the OLS residuals was 0.67 suggesting the
possibility of unmeasured state fixed effects. Column (3) adds state
dummies to the specification ([[Sigma].sub.i] [not equal to] 0, [Rho] =
0).(11) Nonetheless, the first-order autocorrelation of residuals in
this specification [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE II OMITTED] still equalled
0.52 suggesting that even after including state dummies, significant
autocorrelation persists. Thus, column (4) allows for state-specific
fixed effects and corrects for first-order autocorrelation by dropping
the first observation for each state during generalized differencing
([[Sigma].sub.i] [not equal to] 0, [Rho] [not equal to] 0). The panel
results in columns (3) and (4), however, only account for within state
variations in the independent variables. Yet, for some independent
variables, almost all of the variation of the variables are
cross-sectional suggesting that only accounting for within state
variation may be overly restrictive.
The national restructuring and state idiosyncratic employment
coefficients (INDMIX, COMPETE) are robust across all three
specifications.(12) Using column (4), a one-year 1% (0.01) increase in a
state's industrial mix employment growth rate implies an
approximately 0.44 lower unemployment rate that year followed by an
unemployment rate that remains 0.08% lower the next year. A one-year 1%
increase in idiosyncratic state-specific employment results in an
approximately 0.15% lower unemployment rate that year and about a 0.10%
lower unemployment rate the following year. Both results are consistent
with Murphy's [33] finding that product market variations between
states are a significant determinant of differences in state
unemployment rates.
These results support our hypothesis that if a worker's industry
declines in one state, and this decline is national, there is less
incentive for the worker to migrate.(13) However, if the decline in the
worker's industry is specific to that state, then the worker is
more likely to migrate to states where the industry is faring well,
which mitigates the increase in the original state's unemployment
rate. Together, these points imply that limited interindustry mobility
of the labor-force plays a role in affecting the unemployment rate. In
addition, these results show why specific localities hit by layoffs
induced by national restructuring seem to undergo such distress (e.g.,
defense industry communities of the 1990s).
The coefficient magnitudes indicate that a 1% current period change
in employment due to industrial mix has a larger influence than a 1%
change in employment due to competitiveness. Nonetheless, it would be
incorrect to assume that national restructuring employment changes were
more important, in general, than idiosyncratic state employment changes.
In particular, variations across states or movements over time in
industrial mix employment are relatively small. For example, the average
annual 1983-91 cross-sectional standard deviation in the industry mix
employment growth rate was only 0.004 (0.4%) compared to 0.021 (2.1%)
for competitiveness. Thus, the difference in unemployment rates between
two states, one with an industrial mix employment growth rate that has
been two standard deviations above the mean for two years and another
state with an industrial mix employment growth rate that is two standard
deviations below the [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE III OMITTED] mean is only
0.84%. The analogous difference for competitiveness is 2.01%.
Consequently, state idiosyncratic differences in employment growth were
more than twice as important in explaining annual cross-sectional
differences in state unemployment rates.
A similar analysis can be conducted for time-series within state
unemployment rate variations. The average 1983-91 annual time-series
within state standard deviation in industry mix employment growth rate
was only 0.003 (0.3%) compared to 0.018 (1.8%) for competitiveness. As
before, two different economic scenarios will be used to illustrate the
relative differences in unemployment rate behavior. Scenario one is
where the state has an industrial mix employment growth rate that has
been two standard deviations above the mean for two years and scenario
two is where the state has an industrial mix employment growth rate that
is two standard deviations below the mean. The difference in
unemployment rates between these two scenarios is only 0.66%. The
difference for analogous scenarios for competitiveness employment growth
rate is 1.75%. In this case, state idiosyncratic differences in
employment growth are almost three times more important in explaining
time-series variations of a given state's unemployment rate.
Overall, variations in national industrial restructuring are either
too small or move too slowly to significantly explain why unemployment
rates vary in a fixed time period across all the states or why a given
state's unemployment rate varies relative to the national average
over time. In addition, the simple correlation between COMPETE and
INDMIX is 0.0, which supports the notion of an independent regional
component. One implication of these results is that to understand the
performance of the U.S. economy, regional dimensions should not be
ignored.
For added perspective, Table III decomposes average regional
time-series industrial mix and competitiveness variations in the
unemployment rate for nine regions relative to the U.S. average for the
1983 to 1986 and the 1988 to 1991 time periods. These two periods have
the advantage of considering unemployment over two different phases of
the business cycle. The U.S. unemployment rate fell from 9.6% to 7.0%
between 1983 and 1986 for a total decrease of 2.6%. Similarly, it rose
from 5.5% in 1988 to 6.7% in 1991 for a total increase of 1.2%. For
example, column (3) of Table III shows that New England's
unemployment rate fell 0.42% more than the U.S. average between 1983 and
1986 (i.e., it fell by 3.02%) while column (6) shows that it increased
3.28% more than the U.S. unemployment rate between 1988 and 1991 (i.e.,
it rose by 4.48%).
One finding that stands out in Table III is that changes in national
industrial structure played very little role in explaining why regional
unemployment rates changed relative to the national average. In fact,
the West North Central region during 1988-91 represented the only case
where national restructuring influenced regional unemployment rates more
than 0.2% (i.e., -0.22%).
Competitiveness employment effects played a larger role during the
downturn in 1988-91 than during the expansion of 1983-86. Also, regions
that had a positive or negative competitiveness component during 1983-86
had the opposite effect during 1988-91 in five cases. In the South
Atlantic region, the contribution of the competitiveness term to the
unemployment rate increased by over 0.3%. Thus, taken together, this
suggests a regional cyclical component. Moreover, for individual states,
the swing in competitiveness components can be rather large. For
instance, in the case of the energy dependent states Louisiana,
Colorado, and Texas (not shown), the relative swings in their
competitiveness effects between the two periods worked to reduce their
relative unemployment rates 1.93%, 2.18%, and 1.83%, respectively (after
accounting for national industry mix effects such as oil production).
The overall cycle appears to be that a state with a greater (less) than
average competitiveness employment growth rate undergoes a pattern of
rising (falling) input prices - e.g., wages, real estate - which plants
the seeds for the subsequent downturn (upturn) in the next period.
To further investigate the cyclical nature of competitiveness, we
regressed the current period COMPETE on nine of its lag terms and on a
set of state dummies for the 1971-91 period. We then dropped the longest
lag term if we found that it had a statistically insignificant
coefficient. The fourth lag was the first case where the longest lag
turned out to be significant:
COMPETE = 0.74 COMPETE L1 - 0.08 COMPETE L2
(22.63) (1.71)
-0.03 COMPETE L3 - 0.11COMPETEL4 + STATE, (0.57) (2.95)
[R.sup.2] = 0.55, F = 1.02,
where in parentheses are the t-statistics, STATE is a vector of state
dummies, and the F-statistic is for the joint null hypothesis that the
state dummies are all equal to zero. The results show a clear cyclical
pattern where the effect of an exogenous, one-time, one-percent increase
in current period competitiveness employment is almost completely
eliminated by the fourth year and turns negative by the fifth year. This
is consistent with our cyclical pattern shown in Table III. The
F-statistic indicates that the null hypothesis for the state dummies
cannot be rejected at any conventional level of significance, which
suggests that after controlling for its lags, competitiveness employment
changes do not vary across the states. Thus, it may be difficult for
state and local policies to indirectly affect the unemployment rate by
influencing state-idiosyncratic employment growth.
Table III also presents interesting evidence regarding the defense
build-down in New England from 1988-91 (where the same pattern follows
for California). An unfavorable industry mix raised New England's
unemployment rate by only 0.03% more than the U.S. average, but
competitiveness or state-specific restructuring raised the average
unemployment rate by 1.02%. Despite the concentration of defense
industries in these areas, overall national restructuring was not
particularly severe in New England. Although changes in defense spending
may have signaled the unsustainable nature of their economic boom, other
state-specific factors played a much larger role during the actual
downturn (at least initially). These state-specific factors can include
changes in business expectations, differences in credit conditions, real
estate markets, and different economic conditions in the state's
prevalent foreign markets.
The relative wage structure of a state's industry mix (WAGEMIX)
is negatively related to the unemployment rate in all three
specifications, but it is insignificant at the 5% level. The lagged wage
structure (WAGEMIX_LAG) is also insignificant when state fixed effects
are controlled for. Thus, either the prevalence of high-wage jobs in a
state is not important or within state variation of this variable is not
great enough for the panel estimates to adequately capture the effect of
WAGEMIX with any degree of precision. Nonetheless, Blanchard and Katz
[7] also found that wage levels only had a small influence on
employment.
The deviation of a state's wages after controlling for its mix
of industries (WAGE_COMP) is insignificant in column (4), but its lag
(WAGE_COMP_LAG) is significant in all three specifications. Furthermore,
joint F-tests in all three specifications reject the null hypothesis
that both coefficients are equal to zero at the 0.001% level of
significance (F_WAGE_COMP at the bottom of Table II). The positive
response of the unemployment rate to the lag of the state-specific wage
effect suggests that higher than average earnings begin to depress employment in the second year by making businesses in the state
uncompetitive nationally, which is consistent with the regional cyclical
pattern found above.
The sectoral employment shares suggest that states with high shares
of employment in farming and construction have lower unemployment rates.
States with higher shares of employment in government have higher
unemployment rates. Nevertheless, there were no statistically
significant differences in the effects of relatively high-wage
manufacturing and relatively low-wage service producing sectors, i.e.,
transportation, FIRE, trade, and services.
The variance of within state employment growth rates (INDVAR) is
insignificant in all three specifications. This suggests that, whether
caused by national or state-specific restructuring, within state
employment mismatch difficulties induced by industries growing at
differential rates are not a significant cause of greater unemployment
rates. This result is consistent with Holzer's [17] results and
Abraham's [1] results for smaller metropolitan area labor
markets.(14) Similarly, the coefficient for the concentration of
employment in particular sectors (HERFIN) varies widely between columns
(2)-(4), which suggests that diversity of employment opportunity plays
an ambiguous role.
The percent of the labor-force that is male (MALE_LF%) is negatively
related to the unemployment rate while there is weak evidence that the
share of women with young children (CHILD6_MAR, CHILD6_NONMAR) is also
negatively related to unemployment. The percent of the population that
is black and married (BLACK_POP%, MARRIED%) appears to have no strong
association with state unemployment rates. With the exception of the
share of senior citizens in the population, there appears to be no
strong relationship between the age structure of the population and the
state's unemployment rate (AGE65%, AGE14%, AGE15_19%).
There is strong evidence that a greater share of the population that
has a college degree (COLL_GRAD%) is negatively related to the
unemployment rate. Using column (4)'s coefficient, a one standard
deviation increase in the percent of the population that has a college
degree reduces the unemployment rate by about 2.0%. This relatively
large effect is likely caused by greater education or human capital
increasing both labor demand and the worker's attachment to the
labor market. In addition, college graduates are also more likely to
migrate in response to changing unemployment rates and labor market
conditions. However, the results for the share of the population with a
high school degree (HS_GRAD) and for the share of the labor-force who
are blue collar workers (BLUE_COLL) were somewhat mixed.
The unionization coefficient (UNION%) is negative but insignificant
in the panel specifications. Thus, unionization, per se, may have very
little impact on unemployment rates, which is consistent with the
findings of cross-sectional studies of industrial nation unemployment
rates [5]. The results weakly suggest that unemployment insurance
generosity (UI_BEN) and the share of employment covered by unemployment
insurance (UI_COV) are positively associated with unemployment rates,
but the coefficients are typically insignificant.(15) However, there may
not be enough within state variation in our measures to determine their
precise effects.
The relationship between population density and the unemployment rate
is erratic across specifications. However, in all three cases, the
percent of the population that lives in a metropolitan area is
negatively related to the unemployment rate.
IV. Other Specification Issues
One empirical concern is the possibility that the error term
[v.sub.it] from equation (2) is spatially correlated (e.g., a shock in
Indiana can spillover to Illinois). Following Kelejian and Robinson [22;
23; 24], we assume the spatial correlation is of the error component
specification:
v = M[Theta] + [Epsilon], (3)
where M is a 960 x 960 matrix of weights that correspond to the
neighboring states' average value(16) [Theta] is a 960 x 1 vector,
and [Theta] and [Epsilon] are i.i.d with mean and variance-covariance
matrix of [Mathematical Expression Omitted] and [Mathematical Expression
Omitted]. The model shown in (3) assumes that two different disturbances
are formed in each region during period t, where [Theta] does spillover
to neighboring states while [Epsilon] is state-specific and does not
spillover to neighboring states.
Kelejian and Robinson [23; 24] suggest the following method to test
for the possibility of spatial correlation. Run an OLS regression of the
square of the estimated value of [v.sub.it] on a constant term and
[d.sub.it], where [d.sub.it] is the diagonal element of M x M[prime]
corresponding to year t for state i. The null hypothesis is that there
is no spatial correlation. Kelejian and Robinson suggest that the null
hypothesis should be accepted if the t-statistic on [d.sub.it] is
smaller than 1.645. For the autocorrelation corrected specification in
column (4), the t-statistic on [d.sub.it] was -0.22 suggesting little
spatial correlation of the error terms. The results for the
specifications in columns (2) and (3) were also very insignificant.
Another empirical concern for all three specifications is potential
endogeneity of some of the variables. Specifically, greater unemployment
rates could depress current employment growth and potentially reduce
wages. This should not be a problem for the lagged employment terms
(INDMIX_LAG, COMPETE_LAG) and lagged wage terms (WAGEMIX_LAG,
WAGE_COMP_LAG). However, endogeneity may arise for the current period
wage and employment variables. By construction, the industrial mix
variable is determined by national forces, not by state unemployment
rates. In fact, Bartik [4] and Blanchard and Katz [7] argued that the
industrial mix variable is exogenous to local labor market conditions
and used the industrial mix variable as an instrument for total
employment growth. Similarly, WAGEMIX should be influenced by average
earnings determined in the national labor market, not by an individual
state's unemployment rate. However, the state-specific
competitiveness employment effect (COMPETE) and the state-specific wage
effect (WAGE_COMP) could be influenced by the state unemployment rate.
To test for the possibility of endogeneity of the COMPETE and
WAGE_COMP coefficients, a Hausman test was conducted.(17) The Hausman
test statistic for these two variables is shown at the bottom of Table
II (HAUS.-COMPETE, HAUS.-WAGE COMP). The null hypothesis is that
potential endogeneity of the variable is not biasing the coefficients.
For COMPETE, the Hausman test was clearly insignificant in all three
specifications suggesting that potential endogeneity of COMPETE is not
biasing the coefficients. For WAGE_COMP, the Hausman test was only
significant in column (3)'s results suggesting that potential
endogeneity of WAGE_COMP was not too serious.(18)
A final empirical concern is that some of the variables are highly
correlated (e.g., industry mix and its lag). One implication is that the
coefficients could be imprecisely measured and sensitive to the choice
of variables. To examine this issue, the autocorrelation-corrected
specification was reestimated after omitting variables that were not
statistically significant at the 10% level in a two-tail test (with the
exception of the lag of industry mix). These results are shown in column
(5) of Table III. The coefficients in column (5) are essentially the
same as those in column (4) and the statistical significance of the
individual coefficients improved in every case. This suggests that our
findings are robust to possible multicollinearity concerns and
insensitive to variable selection.
V. Discussion and Concluding Thoughts
Employment shifts in the 1980s were significant for explaining state
unemployment rate differences. A decomposition of state employment
growth, however, revealed that most of the changes in employment were
state-idiosyncratic, not the result of national restructuring. Moreover,
the state-idiosyncratic employment growth was primarily cyclical, not
persistent in the long run. Thus, in spite of the limited industry
mobility implied by the large effects on unemployment of a unit change
in industry mix, national restructuring played little role in
unemployment differences in the 1980s. This result is consistent with
the conclusion by Abraham and Katz [2] that national restructuring is
not markedly influencing the natural rate of unemployment. On the other
hand, since a state's industry mix and state-idiosyncratic growth
components were not correlated, our results do not support national
aggregate demand (through cyclical industry mix effects) as being
responsible for regional unemployment differences.
The effect of other factors for unemployment differences were also
examined. A state's wage structure had a limited effect on
unemployment. This is good news for policymakers because they can
concentrate on creating and attracting high-wage industries without
dramatically changing their unemployment rate. Consistent with
cross-national studies [5], union densities played little role in
determining cross-state unemployment rate differences. Similarly, there
was not strong evidence that the availability and generosity of state
unemployment insurance increased unemployment rates. Nevertheless, the
relationship between the unemployment insurance system and unemployment
is complex suggesting that more research is still needed [5]. However,
states with a higher proportion of college graduates had lower
unemployment rates. Thus, states may either directly increase their
number of college graduates or promote industry that largely employs
college graduates to reduce their unemployment rate.
In conclusion, the results suggest that more research should be
undertaken regarding the factors that determine state-idiosyncratic
growth. Much prior research has focussed on persistent long-run factors
such as the level of state and local taxation, but little has been
undertaken regarding cyclical factors. Such factors could include
region-specific product cycles and differing vintages of regional
capital stocks. Alternatively, by changing business expectations,
changes in industry mix employment can indirectly influence regional
business cycle turning points. An understanding of the nature and timing
of the cycles may help states moderate or shorten the downturns, or at
the very least better mitigate their impacts.
1. Blanchard and Katz [7, 12] also report similar trends in
unemployment rate correlations.
2. Other approaches in exploring regional unemployment rates include
examining the time series characteristics of regional unemployment rates
[4; 7], state-specific Phillips curves [8; 19; 20; 38], and the
influence of the variance-covariance structure of state-specific
sectoral employment shocks on the state's unemployment rate [13;
35].
3. In the case of Georgia, a nationally prominent economic forecaster
predicted that a large in-migration would cause the unemployment rate to
rise from 5.8 to 6.2 percent in 1994 even while employment was
forecasted to grow by 4.2 percent (Atlanta Constitution, May 25, 1994,
p. E1).
4. Formally, INDMIX for state i in year t equals:
[INDMIX.sub.it] = ([summation of][g.sub.UStk] *
[E.sub.it-1k])/[E.sub.it-1],
where [g.sub.Stk] is the national growth rate in industry k,
[E.sub.it-1k] is state i's employment in industry k in year t - 1,
and [E.sub.it-1] is state i's total non-farm private sector
employment in year t - 1. The summation is over all non-farm private
sector industries.
5. Formally, COMPETE for state i in year t equals
[COMPETE.sub.it] = ([E.sub.it]/[E.sub.it-1] - 1) - INDMIX,
where the notation is defined in the previous footnote.
6. [WAGEMIX.sub.it] for state i in year t equals
[WAGEMIX.sub.it] = [summation of][S.sub.itk][W.sub.UStk],
where [S.itk] equals industry k's share of state i's
employment, [W.sub.UStk] equals national average annual earnings in
industry k, and the summation is over all non-farm private sector
industries.
7. Lilien [26] argues that the dispersion of employment growth rates
across industries increases unemployment because of greater matching
costs, search and hiring costs, and employer adjustment costs; and it
was a cause for the rise in the natural unemployment rate. However,
Abraham and Katz [2] show that dispersion in industry growth rates may
have ultimately been caused by cyclical considerations, though Hosios
[18] presents a model with implications inconsistent with Abraham and
Katz.
8. The lag of INDVAR was also experimented with in some preliminary
specifications, but it was never statistically significant and the other
results were virtually identical including the results for INDVAR.
9. Levine [25] discusses the total effect of unemployment
compensation on workers who are covered by unemployment insurance and by
those who are uncovered.
10. Ehrenberg and Smith [10] summarize the demographic
characteristics related to worker turnover and unemployment rates.
11. The F-statistic for the joint null hypothesis that the state
dummies equal zero was 19.55.
12. Several alternative specifications that consisted of adding and
dropping variables were conducted to examine the robustness of the
results and to analyze the possibility of multicollinearity. The INDMIX
and COMPETE coefficients were robust to these changes. For example, one
alternative specification considered the possibility that exogenous
changes in farm employment or defense spending had a significantly
larger effect on unemployment than the average industrial mix effect. In
this case, effects that we are attributing to state-specific
competitiveness factors could really have been caused by exogenous
shocks to the defense or agriculture sectors. We examined this
possibility by including the annual percent change in employment due to
the farm sector and the annual change in the percentage of gross state
product that is accounted for by defense contracts as additional
variables in the autocorrelation corrected panel specification. Yet, the
coefficients for these two variables were either the wrong sign (i.e.,
negative) or insignificant and the competitiveness and the industry mix
coefficients and t-statistics were virtually identical. Another
possibility is that the sectoral share variables (e.g., FARM, MANU) are
masking national restructuring employment effects. Fortunately, the
industry mix coefficients were almost identical and their t-statistics
were larger when the sectoral share variables were omitted.
13. The null hypotheses that the current period coefficients for
industrial mix and competitiveness were equal were rejected at or below
the 2% level in all three cases (F_INDMIX = COMP). However, the null
hypotheses that the lagged period industrial mix and competitiveness
coefficients were equal could not be rejected at reasonable levels of
significance.
14. Like our results, Holzer found that the within labor-market
variance in sales growth across industries played a much smaller role
than between labor market variations in employment growth in determining
local labor market unemployment rates.
15. The percent of welfare expenditures as a share of personal income
and the percent of taxes as a share of personal income were also added
as additional variables to test the sensitivity of the results. However,
both coefficients were unexpectedly negative or insignificant and the
other results remained virtually identical.
16. The matrix M is ordered by state and by time period (i.e., 48
states for 20 time periods). The weights were based on the average of
1972 and 1991 non-farm employment in state i's neighboring states.
Non-farm employment was chosen because it appears to be a reasonable
measure of the degree of spillover that a state could have on its
neighbors' labor markets. See Kelejian and Robinson [22; 23; 24]
for further details of the weighting matrix. Suppose that state i is
bordered by states 1, 2, and 3. The weights in M for state i are
[m.sub.ij] = [e.sub.j]/([e.sub.1] + [e.sub.2] + [e.sub.3]), where j = 1,
2, 3, [m.sub.ij] is state j's weight for state i for every time
period, and [e.sub.j] is the average of state j's 1972 and 1991
non-farm employment.
17. The Hausman test creates predicted values for the possible
endogenous variables from an instrumental variable regression. These
predicted values are then included as additional variables in the
regression specification where the t-statistics from these predicted
variables are the test statistics. The exogenous instruments include the
remaining independent variables from the specification and the following
variables: annual international migrants as a share of the state's
population; the percent of personal income that is accounted for by
state and local taxes; regional employment growth in the state's
region (i.e., Northeast, Midwest, West, South) net of the state's
employment growth; the lag of regional employment growth in the
state's region; the state's relative fuel costs; the
state's relative housing costs; the annual change in the share of
employment accounted for by farm employment; the annual change in
military expenditures as a share of Gross State Product; the annual
change in Federal civilian expenditures as a share of Gross State
Product; and separate one-digit employment shares for durable,
non-durable, and traded goods. The tax variable is from Government
Finances [44] and the other variables are discussed in Treyz, Rickman,
and Shao [41].
18. We also estimated an autocorrelation-corrected two-stage least
squares model treating COMPETE and WAGE_COMP as endogenous to examine
the sensitivity of our results. Although there were modest differences
in the industrial mix and competitiveness coefficients, our policy
conclusions remained unchanged. For example, the difference in
unemployment between two states, one with an industrial mix employment
growth rate that has been two standard deviations above the mean for two
years and another state with it two standard deviations below the mean
is 0.86%. The comparable difference for competitiveness is 1.62%. In
both cases, they are about the same as before. Both industry mix
coefficient t-statistics were well above 2.0. The competitiveness
coefficients were imprecisely estimated where a joint F-test regarding
the significance of the two coefficients could not be rejected until the
0.115% level. Regardless, the 2SLS estimates are inefficient and the
Hausman test indicated that they should not be used in this case.
References
1. Abraham, Katharine G., "Help Wanted Advertising, Job
Vacancies, and Unemployment." Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity, 1, 1987, 207-48.
2. ----- and Lawrence F. Katz, "Cyclical Unemployment: Sectoral
Shifts of Aggregate Disturbances." Journal of Political Economy,
June 1986, 507-22.
3. Archibald, G. C., "Wage-Price Dynamics, Inflation,
Unemployment." American Economic Review, March 1969, 124-34.
4. Bartik, Timothy J. Who Benefits From State and Local Economic
Development Policies? Kalamazoo, Michigan: Upjohn Institute, 1991.
5. Bean, Charles R., "European Unemployment: A Survey."
Journal of Economic Literature, June 1994, 573-619.
6. Blackley, Paul, "The Measurement and Determination of State
Equilibrium Unemployment Rates." Southern Economic Journal, October
1989, 440-56.
7. Blanchard, Olivier J., and Lawrence F. Katz, "Regional
Evolutions." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1, 1992, 1-75.
8. Brechling, F. P. R. "Wage Inflation and the Structure of
Regional Unemployment," in Inflation and the Labor Market, edited
by D. Laidler and D. Purdy. Manchester, U.K.: Manchester University
Press, 1973, pp. 197-226.
9. Campbell, Mike, "A Spatial and Topological Disaggregation of
Unemployment as a Guide to Regional Policy." Regional Studies,
1975, 157-68.
10. Ehrenberg, Ronald G. and Robert S. Smith. Modern Labor Economics.
5th ed. New York: Harper Collins, 1994.
11. Freeman, Richard, and James Medoff. What Do Unions Do? New York:
Basic Books, 1984.
12. Gallaway, Lowell E. "Geographic Labor Mobility in the United
States 1957 to 1960." Research Report #28. Social Security
Administration, Office of Research and Statistics, 1969.
13. Gruben, William C. and Keith R. Phillips, "Unionization and
Unemployment Rates: A Reexamination of Olson's Labor Cartelization
Hypothesis." The Review of Regional Studies, Winter 1990, 1-10.
14. Hall, Robert, "Turnover in the Labor Force." Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity, 3, 1972, 709-64.
15. Harris, John R. and Michael P. Todaro, "Migration,
Unemployment and Development: A Two Sector Analysis." American
Economic Review, March 1970, 126-42.
16. Hirsch, Barry T. and David A. Macpherson, "Union Membership
and Coverage Files from the Current Population Surveys: Note."
Industrial and Labor Relations Review, April 1993, 574-78.
17. Holzer, Harry J., "Employment, Unemployment, and Demand
Shifts in Local Labor Markets." Review of Economics and Statistics,
February 1991, 25-32.
18. Hosios, Arthur J., "Unemployment Vacancies with Sectoral
Shifts." American Economic Review, March 1994, 124-44.
19. Hyclak, Thomas and Geraint Johnes, "Real Wage Rigidity in
Regional Labor Markets in the U.K., the U.S., and West Germany."
Journal of Regional Science, August 1989, 423-32.
20. -----. Wage Flexibility and Unemployment Dynamics in Regional
Labor Markets. Kalamazoo, Michigan: Upjohn Institute, 1992.
21. Hyclak, Thomas, and Gerald Lynch, "An Empirical Analysis of
State Unemployment Rates in the 1970s." Journal of Regional
Science, August 1980, 377-86.
22. Kelejian, Harry H. and Dennis P. Robinson, "Spatial
autocorrelation: A New Computationally Simple Test With an Application
to Per Capita County Police Expenditures." Regional Science and
Urban Economics, September 1992, 317-31.
23. -----, "A Suggested Method of Estimation for Spatial
Interdependent Models with Autocorrelated Errors, and an Application to
a County Expenditure Model." Papers in Regional Science, July 1993,
297-312.
24. -----. "Infrastructure Productivity: A Razor's
Edge." Mimeo, University of Maryland, February 1994.
25. Levine, Phillip B., "Spillover Effects Between the Insured
and Uninsured Unemployed." Industrial and Labor Relations Review,
October 1993, 73-86.
26. Lilien, David, "Sectoral Shifts and Cyclical
Unemployment." Journal of Political Economy, August 1982, 777-93.
27. Malizia, Emil E. and Shanzi Ke, "The Influence of Economic
Diversity on Unemployment and Stability." Journal of Regional
Science, May 1993, 221-35.
28. Marston, Stephen T., "Two Views of the Geographic
Distribution of Unemployment." Quarterly Journal of Economics,
February 1985, 57-79.
29. McGee, Robert T., "State Unemployment Rates: What Explains
the Differences?" Federal Reserve Bank of New York Quarterly
Review, Spring 1985, 28-35.
30. McHugh, Richard and Richard Widdows, "The Age of Capital and
State Unemployment Rates." Journal of Regional Science, February
1984, 85-92.
31. Medoff, James L., "U.S. Labor Markets: Imbalance, Wage
Growth, and Productivity in the 1970s. "Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity, 1, 1983, 87-120.
32. Moore, Thomas S. and Aaron Laramore, "Industrial Change and
Urban Joblessness: An Assessment of the Mismatch Hypothesis." Urban
Affairs Quarterly, June 1990, 640-58.
33. Murphy, Kevin J., "Geographic Differences in U.S.
Unemployment Rates: Variance Decomposition Approach." Economic
Inquiry, January 1985, 135-58.
34. ----- and Richard A. Hofler, "Determinants of Geographic
Unemployment Rates: A Selectivity Pooled-Simultaneous Model."
Review of Economics and Statistics, May 1984, 216-23.
35. Neumann, George, and Robert H. Topel, "Employment Risk,
Diversification, and Unemployment." Quarterly Journal of Economics,
November 1991, 1341-65.
36. Stevens, Benjamin H., and Craig Moore, "A Critical Review of
the Literature on Shift-Share as a Forecasting Technique." Journal
of Regional Science, 1980, 4-37.
37. Summers, Lawrence H., "Why is the Unemployment Rate so very
High Near Full Employment?" Brookings Papers on Economic Activity,
2, 1986, 339-83.
38. Tiller, Richard B. and Robert W. Bednarzik, "The Behavior of
Regional Unemployment Rates Over Time: Effects on Dispersion and
National Unemployment." Journal of Regional Science, August 1983,
479-99.
39. Topel, Robert H. "Local Labor Markets." Journal of
Political Economy, June 1986, S111-43.
40. Treyz, George I., Dan S. Rickman, Gary L. Hunt, and Michael J.
Greenwood, "The Dynamics of U.S. Internal Migration." Review
of Economics and Statistics, May 1993, 209-14.
41. Treyz, George I., Dan S. Rickman, and Gang Shao, "The REMI
Economic-Demographic Forecasting and Simulation Model."
International Regional Science Review, #3, 1992, 221-53.
42. U.S. Bureau of the Census. Census of Population, Decennial.
Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office (1970, 1980, 1990).
43. -----. Current Population Report. Washington, DC: U.S. Government
Printing Office, Various Years.
44. U.S. Department of Commerce. Government Finances. Washington, DC:
U.S. Government Printing Office, Various Years.
45. -----. Statistical Abstract of the United States. Washington, DC:
Government Printing Office, Various Years.
46. U.S. Department of Labor. Geographic Profiles of Employment and
Unemployment. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, Various Years.
47. U.S. Employment and Training Administration. Unemployment
Insurance Data Summary. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office,
Various Years.