Do women receive compensating wages for earnings uncertainty?
McGoldrick, Kimmarie
I. Introduction
The area of earnings uncertainty has received considerable attention
in the literature. Many different measures of income uncertainty have
been presented. For example, when individuals choose an occupation they
face earnings uncertainty until they obtain a particular job. This
uncertainty arises from the variability in earnings within an
occupation. Once individuals find a job they face additional uncertainty
in that jobs differ in their future earnings stability. Earnings
uncertainty thus arises from the unknown wage pattern over time.
The impact of uncertainty is well documented, including its impact on
wages [3; 4; 6; 7; 8]; investment in human capital [9; 12]; and
occupational choice [10; 11]. The purpose of this study is to examine
gender differences in compensating wages associated with income risk.(1)
The contribution of this paper to the literature on income
uncertainty is the extension of the analysis to gender differences. Key
to analyzing such gender differences arc the definitions and estimation procedure of systematic and unsystematic earnings. Earnings uncertainty
for women is expected to be affected more by systematic, supply-side characteristics such as age, education, and migration differences for
which compensating differentials are not expected. Thus, women may not
receive significant compensating differentials with respect to measures
of total variation when controlling for skewness in earnings.(2)
Earnings uncertainty for men is expected to be influenced more by
unsystematic, demand-side factors for which one would anticipate
compensating differentials.
Results indicate that both men and women receive a positive wage
differential for variation in unsystematic earnings when controlling for
skewness. Men and women receive negative compensating differentials for
positively skewed unsystematic earnings, as expected. Women receive
significantly greater compensating wages for unsystematic variations in
earnings than men, but are willing to give up less for the possibility
of receiving higher earnings (as indicated by positive unsystematic
skewness).
The next section presents the theoretical framework, reviews what has
been done to date, and discusses the contribution of this paper. This is
followed by a section describing the data. Section IV includes empirical
results and discussions. A comparison of the findings of this paper to
those in earnings uncertainty literature is provided in the concluding
section.
II. Theoretical Development
This section provides theoretical support for the risk premium
hypothesis and results of this paper. The model is partially based on
the work of Bellante and Link [1]. A worker is assumed to maximize
utility:
U = U (W, R, S, X) (1)
where W represents the worker's wages over time, R is the
measure of uncertainty, S is the measure of skewness, and X represents a
vector of non-wage job characteristics. The typical assumptions of
[U.sub.W] [greater than] 0, [U.sub.WW] [less than] 0, [U.sub.R] [less
than] 0, and [U.sub.RR] [less than] 0 are made. Additionally, it is
assumed that [U.sub.S] [greater than] 0. Thus workers are assumed to be
risk averse and, ceteris paribus, will prefer entering occupations which
have less uncertainty about occupational earnings and that are
characterized by small probabilities for receiving higher earnings.
Wages are assumed to be determined in the form of the following
earnings function:
Ln [W.sub.i] = a + b [multiplied by] [R.sub.i] + c [multiplied by]
[S.sub.i] + [Delta] [multiplied by] [X.sub.i] + [[Epsilon].sub.i] (2)
where Ln [W.sub.i] is the log of real wages for individual i. By
maximizing (1) subject to (2), we obtain the following relationship.
L = U (W, R, S, X) - [Lambda](W - a - b [multiplied by] R - c
[multiplied by] S - [Delta] [multiplied by] X) (3)
First order conditions of the Lagrangian are:
[Delta]L/[Delta]W = [U.sub.W] - [Lambda] = 0 (4)
[Delta]L/[Delta]R = [U.sub.R] + b [multiplied by] [Lambda] = 0 (5)
[Delta]L/[Delta]S = [U.sub.s] + c [multiplied by] [Lambda] = 0 (6)
[Delta]L/[Delta]X = [U.sub.x] + [Delta] [multiplied by] [Lambda] = 0
(7)
[Delta]L/[Delta][Lambda] = W - a - b [multiplied by] R - [Delta]
[multiplied by] X = 0. (8)
These can be easily solved to find the following relationship:
[U.sub.W] = -[U.sub.R]/b = -[U.sub.S]/c = -[U.sub.X]/[Delta] =
[Lambda] (9)
Of primary interest are the relationships of risk and skewness with
wages. By solving (5) and (6) we find:
b = -[U.sub.R]/[U.sub.w] [greater than] 0 (10)
and
c = -[U.sub.S]/[U.sub.W] [less than] 0. (11)
Thus workers who face greater uncertainty will require higher wages
to enter riskier occupations and will be willing to receive lower
earnings for the opportunity of receiving higher incomes.
Beginning with Friedman and Kuznets [5], many authors have found a
distinctive relationship between average income levels and income
variability. Occupations can be classified by the level of risk as
measured by the variation observed in their income distribution.
Assuming risk aversion, the individuals in question will have little
incentive to enter a risky occupation. If risky occupations would offer
the same wage as riskless occupations, they would face a shortage of
workers. Consequently, one can expect to observe compensating wages for
occupational earnings risk.
The literature on earnings uncertainty is fairly small, thus a review
of some of these articles is appropriate. King [7] tested whether
riskier occupations offered employees higher expected average income.
Risk was measured as the standard deviation of earnings within an
occupation. Males, age 35-54, that had completed four years of college
and were currently employed in professional occupations were examined.
Compensating differentials for income variability were found to exist.
Johnson [6] used a similar approach to estimate the tradeoff between
risk and average earnings across all occupations for a sample of male
workers. He further stratified the sample into groups by race, age, and
education levels. Risk was measured as the standard deviation of
earnings within an occupation for each cohort of workers. Again,
compensating wages were found for all groups.
Feinberg [3] considered the instability of earnings over time using
six years of panel data for both men and women. Risk was measured as the
standard deviation of the residuals from a regression over time for each
individual. Results indicated that average earnings over the time period
increased with risk. Gender differences indicated that women earned
significantly lower compensating wages for income uncertainty. While
Feinberg noted this difference, he suggested that future empirical work
focusing on "how other compensating differentials vary across
classes of jobs and workers" would be useful [3, 163].
In an attempt to combine the risk affects at a point in time and
across time, Leigh [8] used a slightly different approach. Data
consisted of white and blue collar male workers who were in the same
industry over a three year period. A measure of risk was calculated that
incorporated individual wage growth and industry wage variation
components. Compensating wages were found to exist for white collar
workers but not for blue collar workers.
Despite this literature, questions concerning earnings uncertainty
remain unanswered. Gender differences in compensating differentials for
income uncertainty have not been adequately considered. For example,
King [7], Johnson [6] and Leigh [8] restrict their analysis to male
samples. Although Feinberg [3] finds significant gender difference in
risk premiums for earnings uncertainty over time, he makes no attempt to
explain this result. This study extends income risk analysis by
providing a possible explanation for the gender differences noted by
Feinberg [3]. The distinction between systematic and unsystematic
earnings uncertainty is key to these differences.
Total income variation may be separated into variation which is
anticipated (or predetermined) and unexplained variation. Systematic
risk includes variations in income which are either predetermined or are
a result of anticipated fluctuations. Variations in earnings that are
systematic arise from supply-side constraints. Variations attributable
to these factors should be purged from the estimation of risk since they
do not generate additional compensation in the labor market. Results
obtained without eliminating this type of earnings variation will lead
to an understatement of the risk premium. The discussion that follows
outlines characteristics that affect systematic variation and gender
differences in the impact of these characteristics.
Greater variability in earnings is more likely to occur for workers
who are faced with lower employment opportunities and higher
probabilities of unemployment or longer periods outside the labor
market. Factors affecting these conditions which are under control of
the individual or predetermined (i.e., systematic) include education,
experience, number of children, marital status, discrimination, city
size, and region.
Individuals with less schooling or experience confront lower
employment opportunities in the labor market and are more likely to face
periods of unemployment. Since it is commonly found that women have
lower levels of both experience and education, one might expect women to
have greater earnings variation attributable to this systematic factor.
The number of children may restrict vocational opportunities for
women as a result of limited mobility. Those who work near the home for
child-related reasons, out of choice or necessity, face limited
employment options and it is expected that this will result in greater
systematic variation in earnings.
Married women are more likely to be "tied-movers" or
"tied-stayers." Thus, gender differences in the variation in
earnings may be expected if locational measures contribute to
differences in variation in earnings. It has been shown that there is
larger variation in earnings in and across small cities than in large
cities due to limited worker mobility which prevents equalization of
wages [2]. There can also be differences in variation in earnings by
region.
If discrimination exists, it is expected that there will be more
variation in individuals' wages resulting from limited or
restricted employment opportunities. These restrictions will hamper the
process of wage equalization and it is expected that women will face
greater variability in earnings. However, if discrimination against
women is in the form of a "glass ceiling", then the variation
observed will be smaller since there will be truncation at the upper end
of the distribution.(3)
Unsystematic risk includes only unanticipated variations which arise
from demand-side factors. Business cycle and seasonal effects on
variations in earnings of workers in the construction occupation are an
example. Demand-side factors are expected to affect men and women more
equally since they are attributable to economy-wide conditions.(4)
Unsystematic variation is expected to generate compensating
differentials.
Unsystematic variation measures may be derived in two ways.
Homogeneous samples provide a basis in which there is little or no
variation attributable to systematic factors. This is the method applied
by King [7] and Johnson [6], for example. Alternatively, systematic
variation may be purged through the standard hedonic earnings function.
This estimation consists of a two step procedure in which a standard
earnings function is estimated and residual earnings are used to provide
an estimate of unsystematic variation.
In addition to measures of variation, one might consider other
moments of the income distribution to describe income uncertainty. For
example, King [7] also examined skewness in the income distribution.(5)
A positively skewed income distribution implies a small probability of
receiving large incomes. Occupations that provide the opportunity for
such large incomes will be faced with an excess of workers. Thus, a
negative correlation between earnings and skewness is expected.
Exclusion of skewness will understate the occupational risk premium
[7,590]. Analogous [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE I OMITTED] to unsystematic
measures of variations in earnings, measures of unsystematic skewness
can be derived through homogeneous samples or residuals from a standard
hedonic earnings function.
Estimates of compensating differentials in this study will
incorporate the concepts of systematic and unsystematic earnings in
estimating variation and skewness. Specifically, compensating wages will
be estimated using unsystematic variation and skewness of earnings
within an occupation. Unsystematic measures will be estimated by
occupation using the residuals of a standard earnings function, as
described below.
III. Data Description
The analysis is based on the earnings of three-digit occupations in
the United States, using the 1980 Census Public-Use Microdata Set. The
national one-in-one-thousand sample was chosen. The current sample
includes only 18-65 year old married and never married fulltime
([greater than or equal to] 30 hours a week; [greater than or equal to]
35 weeks a year) workers. Those living in group quarters, not identified
to a SMSA, and those identified as farmers or in the military are not
included. 14,605 women and 25,862 men are included in the sample. Table
I describes the variables of interest and Table II reports the means and
tests the differences in means of these variables. Consistent with many
other studies, women have significantly lower levels of average
experience, education, and wages. Women are more likely to be in Sales
occupations, while men are more likely to be in Crafts occupations.
IV. Methodology and Results
Determining the relationship of risk and skewness with wages requires
two steps. First, systematic earnings must be eliminated in order to
derive estimates of variation and skewness based on unsystematic
earnings within an occupation. The following analysis outlines the
procedure for estimating unsystematic variation. Estimates of
unsystematic skewness are derived in a similar manner.
Table II. Variable Means and Test of Differences in Means by Gender
Variable Men Women t-statistic
Log Earnings 2.7272 2.1987 81.16(**)
Education 12.9081 12.8533 1.83(*)
Experience 18.9824 16.6124 17.50(**)
Fertility - 1.3494
Married 0.7924 0.7003 20.29(**)
City Size 23.0969 23.7143 2.30(**)
Nonwhite 0.1338 0.1745 10.80(**)
South 0.2866 0.3024 3.35(**)
West 0.2175 0.2073 2.48(**)
North Central 0.2455 0.2421 0.77
Northeast 0.2504 0.2482 0.49
Professionals 0.1321 0.1633 8.43(**)
Managers 0.1023 0.0620 14.82(**)
Sales 0.2206 0.5174 61.10(**)
Service 0.0858 0.1251 12.19(**)
Craftsmen 0.2298 0.0280 68.82(**)
Laborer 0.2284 0.1039 34.40(**)
# of individuals 25862 14605
Notes: The number of individuals differs slightly from those
presented in the final earnings estimation since some occupations
had to be dropped in calculating measures of risk and skewness.
** and * indicate significance at the 5% 10% levels, respectively.
One method that will eliminate systematic (anticipated) variation,
which has been documented previously [6; 7], uses subsamples of
individuals categorized by education, age, and race. Within each of
these groups, individuals are characterized by the same factors
contributing to systematic variation. Thus, differences in earnings
among individuals are limited to that attributable to unanticipated
(demand-side or random) factors. The risk differences subsequently
observed are due solely to unsystematic variation. Since a limited
number of characteristics may be accounted for in this manner, an
alternative measure will be suggested.
In order to control for individual characteristics as one estimates
the effects of risk on individual incomes, Bellante and Link [1], and
Leigh [8], suggest an alternative specification of the risk variable.
Elimination of systematic variation uses residuals derived from earnings
functions including regressors contributing to this risk. Bellante and
Link estimated uncertainty as the coefficient of variation of residual
earnings for each occupation. However, Bellante and Link used this
measure only to determine what factors contributed to earnings
uncertainty, not the subsequent compensation for that uncertainty as
addressed here.
Leigh confined his analysis to two separate earnings functions, one
for professionals and managers and the other for operatives, craftsmen,
and laborers. Earnings uncertainty was estimated by industry as the
standard deviation of residual earnings of the respective earnings
equation. In this case, only men were included in the sample and
industries rather than occupations were considered.
Two methods for estimating unsystematic variation may be employed.
One approach derives unsystematic earnings from earnings functions
estimated separately for broadly defined occupations or industries (by
gender). These unsystematic earnings are then used to calculate the
measure of unanticipated earnings variation within each occupation
(again, separately for men and women).(6) This method would lead to an
overcorrection in estimating the variation in each occupation. The
overcorrection is a result of neglecting the variation that results from
alternative choices that individuals face prior to entering an
occupation. In other words, the variation would not capture all the
effects with which this study is concerned.(7)
Alternatively, unsystematic earnings may be calculated from a single
earnings function estimated across all occupations applied separately to
men and women. Variations in unsystematic earnings are calculated for
each occupation from residual earnings associated with the individuals
of that occupation. The subsequent measure of risk will be a combination
of variation between and within occupations since this earnings function
does not control for occupational choice. This is the method applied in
this paper.
The following model is used to estimate the affects of unsystematic
variation in income by controlling for characteristics contributing to
systematic earnings variation.
[Y.sub.ij] = [[Alpha].sub.i] + [[Beta].sub.i][X.sub.j] +
[[Epsilon].sub.ij] (12)
where:
[Y.sub.ij] is the (log) annual earnings/1000 for individual j in
occupation i;
[[Alpha].sub.i] is a scalar;
[[Beta].sub.i] are parameter vector estimates;
[X.sub.j] is a vector of variables affecting systematic risk of
individual j (described in Table I); [[Epsilon].sub.ij] are the
residuals for person j in occupation i.(8)
The earnings function is estimated separately for full-time men and
women. Calculation of residual earnings depends on accurate estimation
of the earnings function. Estimating the earnings equation by gender
will allow for gender differences in age earnings profiles.
The vector of variables [X.sub.j] includes factors affecting
systematic earnings, as discussed above. Education and experience are
expected to lead to greater earnings. The age-earnings profile is
expected to follow the quadratic form and thus experience will have a
positive but decreasing effect on earnings. City size has been found to
have a positive affect on earnings. A variable signifying race is
included and it is expected that white workers will receive higher
earnings than identical black workers. Locational control variables are
also included. Finally, the number of children ever born is expected to
have the typical adverse effect on earnings of women.
The earnings function (12), estimated across all occupations,
provides parameter estimates ([[Alpha].sub.i], [[Beta].sub.i]) used to
calculate the predicted (log) earnings for each individual. These
coefficient estimates are presented in Table III and are consistent with
findings of previous studies. Systematic earnings are estimated as the
predicted earnings from this regression equation. Residual earnings are
defined as the difference between actual and predicted earnings.
Unsystematic earnings are calculated as the antilog of residual earnings
for each individual ([[Epsilon].sub.ij]).
Earnings uncertainty in a particular occupation is measured by the
standard deviation of unsystematic earnings associated with the
individuals of that occupation. Each individual is then assigned the
level of risk associated with their respective occupation. A measure of
skewness is also calculated from unsystematic earnings within each
occupation and is assigned to the respective workers. This measure of
skewness is included to control for the individuals preference for
positively skewed income distributions.(9)
Table III. Earnings Equations Used to Estimate Unsystematic Risk
Variable Men Women
Intercept 1.1747(**) 0.8886(**)
(0.0211) (0.0290)
Education 0.0676(**) 0.0776(**)
(0.0012) (0.0018)
Experience 0.0409(**) 0.0316(**)
(0.0012) (0.0014)
Experience(2) -0.0006(**) -0.0005(**)
(0.00002) (0.00003)
City Size 0.0013(**) 0.0020(**)
(0.0002) (0.0002)
Fertility - -0.0445(**)
(0.0036)
Married 0.2584(**) 0.0235(**)
(0.0105) (0.0118)
South -0.0181(*) -0.0212(**)
(0.0105) (0.0131)
West 0.0362(**) 0.0212
(0.0108) (0.0138)
North Central 0.1134(**) 0.0229(*)
(0.0104) (0.0132)
Nonwhite -0.2253(**) -0.0188
(0.0110) (0.0125)
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.25 0.16
Number 25862 14605
Notes: Dependent variable is log (earnings/1000). Standard errors in
parentheses. ** and * indicate significance at the 5% 10% levels,
respectively.
Table IV presents a summary of earnings, uncertainty, and skewness
categorized into that which is attributable to systematic and
unsystematic factors. Men have greater total, systematic, and
unsystematic earnings. Women have a greater percentage of earnings
attributable to systematic factors, as expected. Men are faced with
greater uncertainty in total, systematic, and unsystematic earnings but
have a greater percentage of earnings uncertainty attributable to
systematic factors, contrary to expectations.(10) Finally, women have
greater positively skewed earnings in all three categories while the
percentage attributable to systematic factors is not significantly
different from [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE IV OMITTED] the same percentage
for men. Thus, the evidence indicating whether systematic factors affect
the earnings of women more than men is mixed.
Table V provides an analysis of the risk and skewness an individual
faces categorized by education and experience levels. This table allows
for a rough analysis of uncertainty for different cohorts.
Average income uncertainty increases with education. This result
indicates that men and women with higher levels of education are
accepting higher levels of risk. Average income uncertainty first
increases and then decreases with experience. Average unsystematic
skewness decreases with education for both men and women. This implies
that workers with higher levels of education are likely to face less
positively skewed unsystematic earnings. Additionally, skewness
increases for higher levels of experience for women but increases and
then decreases for men. Married and white workers have higher levels of
unsystematic risk and greater positively skewed earnings distribution
compared to their respective single and nonwhite counterparts.
It is interesting to note that (in all but one case) men have
significantly greater unsystematic risk and significantly less
unsystematic skewness than women. These initial estimates are not
intended to be a comprehensive analysis of uncertainty and skewness
estimates.(11) Rather, they are provided in order to determine the
patterns of unsystematic risk for various cohorts.
The incorporation of these derived measures of unsystematic risk and
skewness into an otherwise [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE V OMITTED] standard
hedonic wage function will allow for compensating wage estimates. The
following model is estimated separately by gender.
Ln [Y.sub.i] = a + b [center dot] [R.sub.i] + c [center dot]
[S.sub.i] + [Delta][X.sub.i] + [[Epsilon].sub.i] (13)
where Y denotes earnings/1000, R represents uncertainty (as measured
by the standard deviation of unsystematic earnings), S indicates the
estimated skewness of unsystematic earnings, and X is a vector of
individual and job characteristics.
Typical human capital variables such as schooling and experience are
included in the earnings equation. Influences of these variables follow
the usual assumptions. Earnings have been found to increase with city
size and the same is expected to be true in this case. Location and
occupational control variables are included. Individual characteristics
such as marital status, race, and number of children are also included.
It is expected that married workers and whites will earn more than their
associated counterparts. The number of children is expected to decrease
the earnings of women.
If an occupation exists in which there are no fluctuations in
unsystematic income, individuals will be paid according to their
characteristics. In occupations characterized by fluctuations in
unexplained income, a risk exists that individuals may not receive the
income that could be earned solely on the basis of their
characteristics. Assuming risk aversion and limited migration
opportunities, the individual will receive a premium for facing
unsystematic variation. Therefore, those occupations with larger
fluctuations in unsystematic earnings will pay individuals higher
incomes and a positive relationship between unsystematic income
variability and income will exist. Consistent with King [7], it is
expected that workers would be willing to give up a portion of their
income to encounter a positively skewed income distribution.
Table VI presents the results for the earnings equation estimation.
Human capital variables describing experience and education have the
appropriate signs and are significant for men and women. Married and
white men earn significantly more than their associated male
counterparts while neither of these characteristics are significant for
women. The number of children significantly decreases the earnings of
women. Larger city sizes significantly increase earnings, as expected.
Both men and women earn significantly more in the West and North Central
regions and significantly less in the Southern region compared to the
omitted reference category - the Northeast region of the country.
Occupational control variables suggest that both men and women earn
significantly more in all occupations compared to the reference Services
category.
Table VI. The Model: Ln [Y.sub.i] = a + b [center dot] [R.sub.i] +
c [center dot] [S.sub.i] + [Delta][X.sub.i] + [[Epsilon].sub.i]
Variable Men Women
Intercept 1.0233(**) 0.8373(**)
(0.0261) (0.0337)
Risk 0.0246(**) 0.0307(**)
(0.0012) (0.0027)
Skewness -0.0265(**) -0.0093(**)
(0.0033) (0.0025)
Education 0.0543(**) 0.0512(**)
(0.0015) (0.0022)
Experience 0.0404(**) 0.0291(**)
(0.0011) (0.0014)
Experience(2) -0.0006(**) -0.0004(**)
(0.00002) (0.00003)
City Size 0.0013(**) 0.0018(**)
(0.0001) (0.0002)
Fertility - -0.0305(**)
(0.0035)
Married 0.2375(**) 0.0148
(0.0104) (0.0115)
Nonwhite -0.1954(**) 0.0123
(0.0110) (0.0123)
South -0.0319(**) -0.0305(**)
(0.0103) (0.0127)
West 0.0297(**) 0.0233(*)
(0.0106) (0.0134)
North Central 0.1094(**) 0.0290(**)
(0.0103) (0.0128)
Professional 0.2008(**) 0.4498(**)
(0.0179) (0.0199)
Manager 0.2386(**) 0.4600(**)
(0.0176) (0.0232)
Sales 0.1583(**) 0.2967(**)
(0.0150) (0.0144)
Laborer 0.1814(**) 0.2307(**)
(0.0144) (0.0190)
Craft 0.2212(**) 0.3316(**)
(0.0145) (0.0309)
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.27 0.21
Number 25817 14511
Notes: Dependent variable is log (earnings/1000). Standard errors in
parentheses. ** and * indicate significance at the 5% 10% levels,
respectively.
Both men and women receive compensating wages for earnings
uncertainty when controlling for skewness in unsystematic earnings.
Since uncertainty is estimated as the antilog of residuals earnings, it
is measured in thousands of dollars. Thus, a $1,000 increase in the
standard deviation of unsystematic earnings will increase men's
earnings by 2.5 percent and women's earnings by 3.1 percent. The
difference in risk premium between men and women is significant at the
one percent level.
As stated above, if workers prefer a positively skewed (unsystematic)
earnings distribution, they will receive negative compensating wages as
skewness increases. The coefficient on the skewness of unsystematic
earnings is negative and significant for both men and women, consistent
with expectations. Like the measure of uncertainty, this variable is
measured in thousands of dollars. Men are willing to forego 2.7 percent
of their income for an increase in skewness by $1,000 whereas women are
only willing to forego 0.9 percent of their income. The difference in
earnings that men and women are willing to forego is significant at the
one percent level.
V. Conclusion
These results are consistent with previous studies that have found
positive and significant compensating wages for income uncertainty [3;
6; 7; 8]. They are also consistent with findings that suggest workers
are willing to give up earnings for a small probability of receiving
greater earnings (as indicated by a positively skewed unsystematic
earnings distribution) [7].
The findings differ from previous work by Feinberg [3] with respect
to the magnitude of the risk premium paid to men and women. Feinberg
found that women received lower risk premiums than men, yet in the
current study women are found to receive significantly greater risk
premiums for earnings uncertainty. These results are not necessarily
inconsistent. In the work by Feinberg, systematic earnings are not
purged from the estimate of earnings uncertainty and a measure of
skewness is not included in the estimation of risk premiums. As
suggested above, each of these factors will lead to understatement of
risk premiums and their effects are expected to be greatest for women.
These two factors could contribute to women's lower risk premium as
found by Feinberg.
In addition, the measures of uncertainty in the current context and
that of Feinberg differ significantly. While Feinberg measures
uncertainty over time, the current study considers uncertainty over
occupations. Indeed, future work may focus on the implications of
differing definitions of income uncertainty and the resulting
differences in estimated risk premiums by gender.(12)
1. I use the terms "uncertainty" and "risk"
interchangeably.
2. This is true even if women receive significant compensating
differentials with respect to unsystematic measures of variation since
inclusion of systematic variation will lead to an understated risk
premium.
3. This problem is somewhat resolved by including skewness to capture
other distributional differences in addition to variation.
4. The exception to this would be the demand for goods from
particular occupations which are more male or female concentrated.
5. Since the literature typically defines income risk as the
variability in earnings, I will continue with this standard and refer to
skewness as a separate concept.
6. Leigh [8] used a similar approach estimating earnings functions
for managerial and professional occupations separately from operators,
craftsman, and labor workers.
7. Estimation of the earnings function separately by broad industry
and occupational categories (and gender) was performed and results were
consistent with those present below. Results available upon request.
8. The traditional assumptions for [[Epsilon].sub.ij] (identically
distributed within occupations and expected value equal to zero) are
made.
9. Note that in this procedure, occupations containing less than
three individuals are dropped from the analysis at this stage since
there are insufficient observations to calculate skewness.
10. One possible explanation for this seemingly contradictory result
is the exclusion of any control for labor force participation. If women
adjust to labor market conditions by altering their level of labor force
participation, one would expect those earning low wages to drop out more
often than those earning high wages. The tendency to drop out will
decrease the observed variation in earnings. Unfortunately, the Census
data does not provide any reasonable control for labor force
participation.
11. This is the case since many factors affecting these estimates are
not held constant.
12. In a current working paper by this author these differences are
under investigation. Using a sample of the PSID similar to
Feinberg's original sample, both earnings uncertainty over time and
over occupations are analyzed. Preliminary results suggest that while
earnings uncertainty measured over time indicates women having
significantly lower risk premiums, unsystematic earnings uncertainty
measured over occupations (including a measure of skewness) indicates no
significant gender differences in risk premium.
References
1. Bellante, Don and Albert Link, "Are Public Sector Workers
More Risk Averse than Private Sector Workers?" Industrial Labor
Relations Review, April 1981, 408-12.
2. Clark, David, James Kahn, and Haim Ofek, "City Size, Quality
of Life, and the Urbanization Deflator of the GNP: 1910-1984,"
Southern Economic Journal, January 1988, 701-14.
3. Feinberg, Robert, "Earnings-Risk as a Compensating
Differential." Southern Economic Journal, July 1981a, 156-63.
4. -----, "Employment Instability, Earnings, and Market
Structure." Applied Economics, June 1981b, 257-65.
5. Friedman, Milton and S. Kuznets. Income from Independent
Professional Practice. New York: NBER, 1945.
6. Johnson, William. "Uncertainty and the Distribution of
Earnings," in The Distribution of Economic Well-Being, edited by F.
T. Juster. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Ballinger, 1977, pp. 379-96.
7. King, Allan, "Occupational Choice, Risk Aversion, and
Wealth." Industrial Labor Relations Review, July 1974, 586-96.
8. Leigh, J. Paul, "Job Choices across Industries when Earnings
are Uncertain." Quarterly Review of Economics and Business, Autumn
1983, 54-69.
9. Levhari, David and Yoram Weiss, "The Effect of Risk on the
Investment in Human Capital." American Economic Review, December
1974, 950-63.
10. Orazem, Peter and J. Peter Mattila, "Occupational Entry and
Uncertainty: Males Leaving High School." Review of Economics and
Statistics, May 1986, 265-73.
11. Siow, Aloysius, "Occupational Choice Under
Uncertainty." Econometrica, May 1984, 631-45.
12. Snow, Arthur and Ronald Warren, "Human Capital Investment
and Labor Supply Under Uncertainty." International Economic Review,
February 1990, 195-206.