Stabilizing inflation in the open economy.
Jansen, Dennis W.
1. Introduction
Optimal monetary policy in the open economy continues to be of
interest to the profession, as in Benavie and Froyen [1], and price
level stabilization has been investigated by Bradley and Jansen [4],
Marquis and Cunningham [13], and Fischer [6], among many others. Price
level stabilization has also been investigated in the monetary policy
literature by, for example, Black [2] or Black and Gavin [3]. The
academic literature has included analysis of price level stabilization
in a variety of macroeconomic frameworks ranging from overlapping
generations models to equilibrium business cycle models and Keynesian contracting models. What has been lacking, however, is a rigorous
analysis of price level stabilization in the open economy. This apparent
omission is interesting because the most famous historical application
of price level targeting occurred in the 1930s in Sweden -- a small open
economy.[1]
In this paper we carefully examine the effectiveness of price
level or inflation stabilization in the small open economy.[2] Employing
an equilibrium business cycle model with differentially informed agents,
we find that when shocks to the economy exhibit some persistence,
inflation stabilization has favorable output stabilization properties
relative to alternative monetary policies. Further, these beneficial
aspects of inflation stabilization exist whether or not agents
contemporaneously observe the money stock. The only instance in which
inflation stabilization policy is not preferred is when all shocks to
the economy are strictly temporary shocks and when uninformed agents can
not observe the money stock contemporaneously. Finally, in all instances
we find that price level stabilization is preferred, from a
macroeconomic stabilization perspective, to exchange rate stabilization.
This last result is of some historical and policy making interest
because the Swedish government pursued an explicit policy of price level
stabilization in the 1930s.
II. The Small Open Economy Model
We employ an aggregate open economy equilibrium business cycle
model. The model combines elements of the open-economy models of
Kimbrough [8; 9] and the closed economy model of Dotsey and King [5).
Agents in the small open economy produce and consume two goods, only one
of which is traded on world markets. Purchasing power parity governs the
price of that traded good. Aggregate output is a function of the ex ante
real rate of interest, which measures the relative price of goods
between today and tomorrow and thereby captures intertemporal
substitution possibilities. The division of aggregate output between
traded and nontraded goods depends on the relative price of the two
goods.
There is also a money market and a credit market. We postulate a
money demand function that depends on real output, the domestic price
level, and the domestic interest rate. Domestic and foreign bonds are
perfect substitutes, so uncovered interest rate parity holds. Domestic
money, however, is only held by domestic residents.
Economic agents are of two types, which are distinguished by their
endowment of information. A fraction [Lambda] A are labeled
"informed" agents, and at every time t these know the
contemporaneous value of all variables and all stochastic disturbances.
The remaining fraction 1 -- [Lambda] are labeled "uninformed"
agents, and at every time t these agents know the contemporaneous value
of only a subset of the variables and disturbances in the economy. King
[11] has stressed that differentially informed agents with common access
to an economy-wide price is necessary for monetary policy to have an
effect on the informational content of prices. Our informational
structure satisfies this necessary condition. However, while policy
effectiveness results do depend on differentially informed agents, they
do not depend on the explicit structure of the differential information
assumed here. The assumption of two classes of agents, one
"informed" and one "uninformed", is for analytical convenience. Moreover, the implications of variations in the information
set of uninformed agents forms an important part of the analysis in this
paper.[3]
The model is described by equations (1)-(6) below:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Here:
[Lambda] = fraction of agents who are informed, [Y.sub.t] = log of
real output of traded and nontraded goods at time t, [Y.sub.N,t] = log
of real output of nontraded goods at time t, [R.sub.t] = nominal
interest rate at time t, [P.sub.t] = log of the price level at time t,
[r.sub.t.] = real interest rate at time t = [R.sub.t] -- [EP.sub.t+1]
+[P.sub.t.] [P.sub.N,t] = log of the price of nontraded goods at time t,
[P.sub.T,t] =log of the price of traded goods at time t, [P.sub.N,t] =
[P.sub.N,t] -- [P.sub.T,t] the relative price of traded goods, [g.sub.t]
= stochastic disturbance to productivity at time t, [M.sub.t] = log of
the nominal money stock at time t, [v.sub.t] = stochastic disturbance to
money demand at time t, [Epsilon.sub.t] = stochastic disturbance to
demand or supply of total output, [Epsilon.sub.N,t] = stochastic
disturbance to demand or supply of nontraded goods, [k.sub.i] = a
measure of persistence for disturbance i, 0 [less than or equal to]
[k.sub.i] [less than or equal to] 1, [U.sub.t] = information set of
uninformed agents at time t, [I.sub.t] = information set of informed
agents at time t, [R.sub.t.sup.*] = nominal rest of world interest rate
at time t, [P.sub.t.sup.*] = log of the rest of world price level at
time t, [S.sub.t] = log of the nominal exchange rate at time t, E =
mathematical expectation operator.
Equation (1) models economy-wide supply. The coefficient [Lambda]
(0 < [Lambda] < 1) is the exogenously determined fraction of the
population which is informed. Economy-wide supply consists of supply by
[Lambda] informed and (1 - [Lambda]) uninformed agents. Uninformed and
informed agents both react with elasticity [alpha.sup.s] to the ex ante
real interest rate [r.sub.t], but their expectation of the real interest
rate are based on different information sets. For instance, an increase
in the real interest rate signals high returns to supplying output in
the present, thereby inducing an increase in supply. Supply also depends
on a productivity shock [g.sub.t] which has two effects. The first
effect is a wealth effect. The productivity shock is wealth enhancing,
and both informed and uninformed agents respond to the expected value of
this increase in wealth with elasticity -[Beta.sup.s]. Again, however,
informed agents know the value of [g.sub.t] since
E([g.sub.t]\[I.sub.t]t) = [g.sub.t], while uninformed agents form
E([g.sub.t]\[U.sub.t]). The second effect of the productivity shock is
to directly increase supply. This effect is the same for all agents, and
has elasticity [Theta.sup.s]. Note, too, the disturbance
[Epsilon].sup.s.sub.t] which affects supply.
In equation (1) (and also in equations (2)-(5)) the disturbances
are modeled as first order moving average processes of the form
[k.[Chi][Chi.sub.t] + (1 - [k.sub.[Chi])[Chi].sub.t]-1. This modeling
strategy incorporates both persistent shocks (when [k.sub.[Chi] [is not
equal to] 1) and temporary shocks (when [k.sub.[Chi] = 1).(4) Because
disturbances have this moving average form, a lagged value of [g.sub.t]
enters equation (1). The lagged value of [g.sub.t] has coefficient
([Theta.sup.s] - [Beta.sup.s]) due to the two effects of the
productivity shock. Similarly, a lagged value of [Epsilon.sup.s.sub.t]
enters equation (1).
Economy-wide demand is given by equation (2). Like supply, demand
depends on the ex ante real interest rate, [r.sub.t], which measures the
intertemporal substitution possibilities available to private agents.
Changes in the ex ante real interest rate will initiate an intertemporal
reallocation of consumption. Demanders will reduce demand when the real
interest rate is high, indicated by the elasticity -[Alpha.sup.d]. The
productivity shock has a positive wealth effect on demand with
elasticity [Beta.sup.d], and a positive direct demand effect with
elasticity [Theta.sup.d].(5) Finally, both demand and supply are subject
to the disturbances [Epsilon.sup.i.sub.t].
Equations (3) and (4) model the supply and demand for nontraded
goods. These make up only part of the supply and demand for all goods
given in equations (1) and (2). Hence equations (3) and (4) contain all
of the general features of equations (1) and (2), but with different
coefficients.(6) Equations (3) and (4) also contain the relative price
of traded goods, as this relative price determines the split of output
between these two components. This relative price does not enter
equations (1) and (2), because aggregate supply and demand are assumed
independent of relative price changes.
Equations (5) and (6) represent money demand and money supply. The
money demand equation is standard, with real money demand a function of
real output and the nominal interest rate. There is a stochastic
disturbance [v.sub.t], to money demand. The money supply rule has a
deterministic trend, and allows a contemporaneous response to variations
in the exchange rate, [S.sub.t], and the price level, [P.sub.t]. This
specification is general enough to embody a strict money rule, an
exchange rate stabilization policy, or an inflation stabilization
policy, depending on the choice of parameters [Psi.sup.s] and
[Psi.sup.p]. The relevant target levels for [S.sub.t] and [P.sub.t] are
simply their expected values formed by all agents (including the
monetary authority) in the previous period. This type of policy target
precludes the indeterminacy problem sometimes associated with this class
of policy formulation.
Equations (7)-(9) are ancillary equations defining the price
level and the various arbitrage conditions. Equation (7) defines the
price level [P.sub.t] as a weighted average of the price of traded goods
[P.sub.T,t] and nontraded goods [P.sub.N,t]. Equation (8) is the
uncovered interest rate parity condition, which states that the domestic
nominal interest rate [R.sub.t] is equal to the world nominal interest
rate [R.sup.*.sub.t] plus the expected rate of exchange rate
depreciation between t and t + 1. Finally, equation (9) is the law of
one price for traded goodys.(7)
The world nominal interest rate [R.sup.*.sub.t] and the world
price level [P.sup.*.sub.T,t] are exogenous to the small open economy.
These variables are determined in the rest of the world according to
equations (10) and (11).
III. The Small Open Economy: Basic Solution
Given the structure of the rest of the world's economy, we
analyze the small open economy. We begin by looking at the conditions
that the market for nontraded goods and the money market must clear
domestically. These conditions yield two equilibrium relationships for
the macroeconomic variables:
[Y.sup.s.sub.N,t] - [Y.sup.d.sub.N,t'] (12)
and
[M.sup.d.sub.t] = [M.sup.s.sub.t] (13)
There are also two arbitrage conditions that constrain die behavior
of the macroeconomic variables in the economy, the interest rate parity
condition given by equation (8), and the purchasing power parity
condition for traded goods given by equation (9). Equations (8), (9),
(12), and (13) are thus four constraints on the behavior of
macroeconomic variables in the small open economy; they are the four
constraints that aid uninformed agents in their signal extraction
problem for determining the state of the economy.
To demonstrate the information content of the market clearing
conditions, we substitute equations (3) and (4) into equation (12),
obtaining the equation describing equilibrium in the market for
nontraded goods:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Here we have defined several composite variables. In addition to
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] we have
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. We have also
defined the composite disturbance term [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT
REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
We also impose equilibrium in the money market. We write this
expression by substituting equations (5) and (6) into equation (13),
making use of the aggregate income equation (1), to obtain the equation
describing money market equilibrium as:(8)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
For convenience, we also rewrite the interest rate parity and
purchasing power parity arbitrage conditions:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
To solve for the relative price of nontraded goods and the
exchange rate, we postulate the following undetermined coefficients
solutions for these variables. Note the inclusion of the foreign
disturbance terms. These are included to capture the ability of foreign
disturbances to affect the small open economy via relative price and
exchange rate movements. The foreign variables included are those that
enter the solutions for the foreign price level and foreign interest
rate, as given in the appendix:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
The solution for the undetermined coefficients on the predetermined right hand side variables is given by:
[Phi.sub.0] = 0 [Phi.sub.1] = 0 [Phi.sub.2] = 0 [Phi.sub.3] =
([Beta.sub.n] + [Theta.sub.N]) (1 - [k.sub.g]/([Theta] +
[Alpha.sub.n][Sigma.sub.n] [Phi.sub.4] = (1 - [k.sub.n)/
([Theta.sub.n][Sigma.sub.n] [Phi.sub.5] - 0 [Phi.sub.6] = 0 [Phi.sub.12]
= [Alpha.sub.n](1 - k.sup.*.sub.R])/([Theta] +
[Alpha.sub.n][Sigma.sub.n]) [Phi.sub.13] = [Alpha.sub.n](1 -
[k.sup.*.sub.p])/ ([Theta + [Alpha.sub.n][Sigma.sub.n]) [II.sub.0] = (Mo
+ [Gamma]n) - (Mo + [Gamma]*n*) [II.sub.1] = n - n* [II.sub.2] =
[Tau.sub.2] - [k.sub.v]))/(1 + [Gamma]) [II.sub.3] = [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] [II.sub.4] = [MATHEMATICAL
EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] [II.sub.5] = [Tau.sub.5]/(1 +
[Gamma]) [II.sub.6] = [[Tau.sub.6] - [Sigma](1 - [k.sub.s])]/(1 +
[Gamma] [II.sub.12] = [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII] [II.sub.13] = [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
The solutions for the other undetermined coefficients are
considerably more complicated, and vary with the information structure
of the model and the policy rule in force. As an alternative to
explicitly solving for these coefficients, we employ a strategy proposed
by Hercowitz [7], and solve for the signals recoverable by uninformed
agents. We describe this technique in the following section of the
paper, where we use it to analyze the effects of inflation stabilization
in the small open economy.
IV. Full Information Output
The model is solved in two steps. First, we solve for the level of
output when all agents are fully informed. The full information solution
for the level of output of nontraded goods, [Y.sup.#.sub.N,t], is
obtained by setting the fraction of informed agents to unity and solving
equations (3) and (4). This yields full information output of nontraded
goods,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where [Alpha.sub.N] = [Alpha.sup.s.sub.N] + [Alpha.sup.d.sub.N]
Note that full information output of nontraded goods depends on
the stochastic disturbances [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII] and the relative price of traded and nontraded goods. Thus full
information output varies with the stochastic state of the economy.
To solve for the level of nontraded goods output when some agents
are uninformed, we again equate demand and supply in equations (3) and
(4), and solving for output we obtain
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where [H.sub.N] = ([MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN
ASCII])
Inspection of equation (17) reveals that output in the nontraded
goods market deviates from its full information level only when the
expectation of the stochastic disturbance [g.sub.t] by uninformed agents
deviates from the realized value of [g.sub.t]. This leads immediately to
the conclusion that for given [Lambda], monetary policy can be judged by
how well it allows uninformed agents to extract information on [g.sub.t]
from the knowledge they possess about the state of the economy. Another
feature of the model, evident in equation (17), is that uninformed
agents are necessary for output to deviate from the full information
output level. With only fully informed agents, we have [Lambda] = 1, and
not surprisingly the difference between current output and full
information output in equation (17) is eliminated.
V. Analyzing Inflation Stabilization
In this section we turn to the main focus of the paper, the
analysis of price level stabilization in a small open economy. To
facilitate our understanding of the properties of price level
stabilization, we compare the macroeconomic performance under this
policy with the macroeconomic performance under two other well studied
policies, a money growth rule and exchange rate stabilization by, for
example, Kimbrough [9; 10] or Lachler [12]. These well known policies
can thus serve as benchmarks for measuring the effectiveness of
inflation stabilization.
As described above, policy effectiveness is evaluated in terms of
deviations of output in the non-traded goods sector from the full
information output level.(9) This deviation, in turn, will be minimized
by the policy that provides the best information to uninformed agents
about the current state of the economy. As the informational environment
improves, the uninformed agents' forecast of [g.sub.t] also
improves and output deviations are reduced.
In the following subsections we examine the case where the
information set of uninformed agents consists of the current nominal
interest rate both foreign and domestic, the exchange rate, the money
stock, and the price of both traded and nontraded goods. This is
formalized as [U.sub.t] = {[R.sub.t],[R.sup.*.sub.t], [S.sub.t],
[M.sub.t], [P.sub.T,t], [P.sub.N,t]}
Informational Signals
In this subsection we describe the technique for deriving the
informational signals under each type of monetary policy. Because the
informational structure of the economy changes with the choice of
policy, the exchange rate stabilization policy and an inflation
stabilization policy. Once the general solutions for the informational
signals are derived, the specific forms are presented and policy
rankings can be made.
We first consider a strict money growth rule, so that
[[Psi].sup.P] = [[Psi].sup.S]. In this case, there are three potential
signals available to uninformed agents: an exchange rate signal, a goods
market signal, and a money market signal. Observation of the foreign and
domestic interest rates and the exchange rate serves to reveal, from the
interest rate parity condition, the expectation of informed agents about
the one period ahead exchange rate, E([S.sub.t+1] [vertical bar]
[I.sub.t]). This provides uninformed agents with an observation on the
linear combination of disturbances which we label
[[Omega].sup.M.sub.1,t], given as:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (18)
The superscript M denotes that this signal is valid when the monetary
authority is pursuing a money aggregate policy. Notice that the signal
[[Omega].sup.M.sub.1,t] does not contain the foreign disturbances
[[Micro].sup.*.sub.R,t] and [[Micro].sup.*.sub.P,t]. This omission
arises because the values for these disturbances are already perfectly
revealed to uninformed agents by their knowledge of [R.sup.*.sub.t] and
[P.sup.*.sub.t], the latter being obtained from knowledge of [P.sub.t]
and [S.sub.t] via the equation for the law of one price.
The second signal is derived from the equilibrium condition in the
market for nontraded goods, equation (12'). This condition, and the
information set specified above, provides an observation on a second
linear combination of variables that are individually unobserved by
uninformed agents. We call this the nontraded goods market signal and
label it [[Omega].sup.M.sub.2,t]. This signal is given by:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (19)
Finally, the money market provides uninformed agents with a second
linear combination of contemporaneous disturbances. From their knowledge
of the money market equilibrium condition, equation (13'), and
their knowledge of the macroeconomic variables in [U.sub.t], uninformed
agents receive the money market signal [[Omega.sup.M.sub.2,t] given by:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (20)
Equations (18)-(20) represent three linear combinations of the
disturbances to the model that uninformed agents receive when the
monetary authority follows a strict money rule. Uninformed agents then
use these signals to form a prediction of the current [g.sub.t].
On the other hand, suppose that the monetary authority stabilizes
the exchange rate. If so, [[Psi].sup.s.[right arrow] [infinity]] and the
exchange rate is pegged to E([S.sub.t][vertical bar][I.sub.t-1]). This
expected exchange rate target is general enough to involve feedback
elements, so that the rule governing the exchange rate is given by:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (21)
With this policy in place, the money stock becomes endogenous.
Although this renders the money market equilibrium condition irrelevant,
the money demand equation continues to hold. Stabilizing the exchange
rate also restricts variation in the aggregate price level [P.sub.t].
The aggregate price level is the weighted average of the traded goods
price [P.sub.T,t] and the nontraded goods price [P.sub.N,t]. The traded
goods price is restricted by the law of one price to equal [S.sub.t] +
[P.sup.*.sub.t]. Substituting the law of one price into the price level
definition and then substituting the resultant expression into the money
demand equation yields the following equation which uninformed agents
use to extract the information from the money market:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (22)
Given this new informational structure, what are the signals
available to uninformed agents? The answer will determine which policy
is preferred because the ability of uninformed agents to identify the
productivity shock influences the size of the deviation of output from
the full information level of output. To determine agents' forecast
accuracy, we must consider each of the three signals now available to
uninformed agents. First, the interest rate parity condition reveals a
linear combination of disturbances that aid uninformed agents in
forecasting next period's exchange rate. Under an exchange rate
rule, this forecast of the exchange rate is without error, and reveals
to uninformed agents the signal [[Omega].sup.S.sub.1,t], where the
superscript S indicates that the signal is valid under an exchange rate
rule:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (23)
Note that equation (23) does not contain the foreign sector
disturbances because, as before, these disturbances are revealed to
uninformed agents directly from their knowledge of the foreign sector
interest rate and price level.
As for the goods market signal, inspection of equation (12')
indicates that exchange rate stabilization, by setting the value of
[S.sub.t+1], also changes the nontraded goods market signal. The new
signal, labeled [[Omega].sup.S.sub.2,t], is given by:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (24)
Conditional on the respective information sets from the interest rate
parity condition, [[omega].sup.S.sub.2,t] is the same as
[[Omega].sup.M.sub.2,t]. These two signals differ only in the linear
combination of disturbances that are used in predicting next
period's exchange rate.
Turning finally to the money market, an exchange rate peg requires
the money supply to adjust to maintain the exchange rate. Since the
money stock is observable, uninformed agents can still observe the money
demand equation itself, written as equation (22) above. Observing
[M.sub.t], [R.sub.t], and [P.sub.t] thus allows observation of the
linear combination of shocks represented by [Y.sub.t] plus the money
demand shock [v.sub.t]. This is the same signal that we labeled
[[Omega].sup.M.sub.3,t] in equation (20) above. Thus the information
content of the money market is not influenced by the choice between a
money rule and an exchange rate peg.
Finally, what if the monetary authority decides to stabilize the
inflation rate, so that [[Psi].sup.P] [right arrow] [infinity]? Again,
since the money stock is observable, inflation stabilization does not
destroy the information available from the money market despite making
the money stock endogenous. Pegging the price level at E([P.sub.t]
[vertical bar] [I.sub.t-1]) could involve feedback elements, so that the
rule governing the price level is given by:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (25)
With predetermined growth in the price level, the money demand
equation is given by:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (26)
Substituting equation (25) into equation (26), we can derive the
equation which provides uninformed agents with information from the
money market.
Examining each signal in turn, we first look at the information
available from the interest rate parity condition:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (27)
Examining next the nontraded goods market equilibrium condition,
the signal obtained by uninformed agents is given by:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (28)
Notice that this goods market signal, conditional on the signal from
the interest rate arbitrage condition, consists only of a linear
combination of [g.sub.t] [[Epsilon].sub.N,t].
Finally, we present the signal from the money market. This signal
is available from the money demand equation, derived from substituting
the price level equation into equation (24). The signal uninformed
agents thus observe is:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (29)
This is exactly the same signal that is available from the money
market under a money stock rule, [[Omega].sup.M.sub.3,t]. In the money
market, the signal is the same for a price rule as for a money rule.
Policy Effectiveness
Having derived the signals that arise under each of the policies,
we can now compare them for ability to provide uninformed agents with a
clear signal about [g.sub.t]. These results are presented in Table I.
Note that Table I also includes the results that are obtained when the
shocks to the economy do not persist. Because this lack of persistence
is simply a special case of the general result in which all of the
"k" parameters are set to one, it is easily obtainable from
the general results obtained above.(10)
Table I lists the three signals that arise from each of the three
markets under each of the three types of policies. The first noticeable
result is that the interest rate parity condition provides a signal to
uninformed agents under either a money growth policy or an inflation
stabilization policy, but not under exchange rate stabilization.
Moreover, the quality of the signal differs under the money stock policy
and the inflation control policy.
[TABULAR DATA NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
The signal from the nontraded goods market is operative under all
three policies but is different in each case. Conditional on the signal
from the interest rate parity condition though, the nontraded goods
market signal is the same for the money stock policy and the exchange
rate policy. Finally, the money market signal is the same for all three
policies.
In terms of ranking the alternative policies, the inflation
stabilization policy leads to the lowest variance of output around its
full information level. In fact, in terms of the criteria of this model,
the inflation stabilization policy is "perfectly" stabilizing.
As can be seen by inspection of Table I, this result arises under the
inflation control policy because the signals from the nontraded goods
market and the interest rate parity condition are sufficient to fully
reveal [g.sub.t], and uninformed agents can accurately extract the
contemporaneous value of that shock.(11) Thus, an inflation
stabilization policy dominates the other two policy approaches.
When the effects of shocks to the economy do not persist, the
three types of monetary policy can be investigated directly. In the
model, a lack of persistence is generated by setting all the
"k" parameters equal to one. Inspection of Table I reveals
that this changes the informational signals and the results are
presented in part B of that table.
Without persistence the intertemporal exchange rate signal is not
operative and provides no information under any of the policies. The
signals from the other two markets, in addition, are identical. The
three classes of policies are equivalent and our criteria of minimizing
the variance of real output around its full information value provides
no basis for ranking the policies.
VI. Price Stabilization with an Alternative Information Set
We next investigate an information set including the nominal
interest rate, exchange rate, and the price of traded and nontraded
goods, but not the money stock. This case corresponds most closely to
the information assumptions used by previous authors of new classical
models, including Kimbrough [9]. We formally identify this information
set as [U.su.t] = {[R.sub.t],[R.sup.*.sub.t], [S.sub.t],[P.sub.T,t],
[P.sub.N,t]}.
To analyze the policy choice under this information set, we again
look at each policy in turn. We start with strict money growth, under
which [[Psi].sup.P] = [[Psi].sup.S = 0. The interest rate parity
condition still furnishes the signal [[Omega.sup.M.sub.1,t] to
uninformed agents. Inspection of the nontraded goods market equilibrium
condition, equation (12'), indicates that the signal
[[Omega].sup.M.sub.3,t] can again be obtained from the goods market
equilibrium condition. In the money market, the money stock is
unobserved by uninformed agents, but under a strict money rule the
otherwise unobservable money stock is pegged at a predetermined value by
the monetary authority. This act of following a deterministic money rule
allows uninformed agents to extract the signal [[Omega].sub.3,t] from
the money market. In this case, the monetary authority, by following a
money growth rule improves the informational environment by providing
uninformed agents with a signal they would not otherwise have available.
What of an exchange rate policy, under which [[Psi].sup.S] [right
arrow] [infinity]? The interest rate parity condition still furnishes
the signal [[omega].supS.sub.1,t] and the nontraded goods equilibrium
condition still provides the signal [[Omega].sup.S.sub.2,t]. In the
money market, however, the fact that [M.sub.t] is unobserved means that
pegging [S.sub.t] destroys the ability of uninformed agents to extract
an additional signal from the money market. That is, the money demand
equation no longer provides an observation on a linear combination of
disturbances to uninformed agents, because the contemporaneous money
stock is not observed. The inability to observe [M.sub.t] makes the
money demand equation uninformative about the value of [g.sub.t.] In
sum, uninformed agents are still able to observe the linear combination
of disturbances labeled [[Omega].sup.S.sub.1,t], and
[[Omega].sup.S.sub.2,t], but lose the signal [[Omega].sup.S.sub.3,t]
when the monetary authority follows an exchange rate peg instead of a
money growth rule.
Finally, we consider an inflation stabilization policy, under
which [[Psi].sup.P] [right arrow] [infinity]. For simplicity, suppose
that the price level is pegged such that [P.sub.t] = 0. This means that
[P.sub.T,t] + [[Delta].sub.NPN,t] = 0, or that [P.sup.*.sub.T,t] +
[S.sub.t] + [[Delta].sub.NPN,t] = 0. This last condition can be
rewritten as [S.sub.t] = - ([P.sup.*.sub.T,t] + [[delta].sub.NPN,t] =
which clearly shows that inflation stabilization implies a particular
type of exchange rate rule.(12) As in the case of an exchange rate
policy, however, pegging [P.sub.t] while [M.sub.t] is not observable
destroys the information in the money market signal. The goods market
signal remains [[Omega].sup.P.sub.2,t] and the interest rate parity
condition continues to provide the signal [[Omega].sup.P.sub.1,t]. As a
result, price level stabilization does not aid in recovering the signal
[[Omega].sup.P.sub.3,t] from the money market.
To summarize, this information set corroborates the policy
conclusions suggested by Kimbrough [9] with regard to choosing between a
money rule and an exchange rate rule. In particular, a money rule is
generally preferred to an exchange rate rule because it provides the
most information to private uninformed agents. This occurs because the
exchange rate policy (as well as the inflation stabilization policy)
destroy a source of information. In the case of exchange rate
stabilization, the signal extraction task of uninformed agents is
unambiguously more difficult relative to a money rule and, thus it
increases (or at least does not decrease) the variance of output about
full information output.
A clear ranking between a money growth rule and an inflation
stabilization policy does not emerge, however. The inflation
stabilization rule destroys a source of information but, at the same
time, improves the quality of the remaining signals relative to those
provided by the money rule. In this situation, the choice between these
two rules is ambiguous and a ranking cannot be made without further
specification of the stochastic structure of the economy.
When there are persistent shocks to the economy, uninformed agents
receive the signals reported in part A of Table II. As discussed above,
even when the money stock is not contemporaneously available the money
growth rule continues to reveal a signal from the money market. This
signal is not available to uninformed agents under the other policies.
As in the case when agents observe the money stock, the interest
rate parity condition reveals an informational signal under both the
money growth and inflation stabilization policies but not under an
exchange rate peg. Finally, the nontraded goods market reveals a signal
under each policy, although the signal under an inflation stabilization
policy differs from that available under the other two policies.
The ranking of alternative policies is also the same here as when
agents observe the money stock. Inspection of Table 11 reveals that the
two signals available when the monetary authority is stabilizing
inflation again fully reveal g, to uninformed agents. This type of
policy thus continues to be perfectly stabilizing. In contrast,
stabilization of the exchange rate does not yield the minimum variance
of output around its full information value. A money growth rule reveals
three signals to uninformed agents but these signals include more than
three shocks. Consequently, these signals are not sufficient to reveal
[g.sub.t] to uninformed agents except under a most fortuitous
combination of parameter values.
Part B of Table II contains the signals available when there is no
persistence in the stochastic structure of the economy. As in Table I,
the signal from the interest rate parity condition disappears under
these conditions and the signal from the nontraded goods market is again
identical under the three policy choices. Because the money stock is not
observable by uninformed agents, the signal from the money market is
destroyed under the exchange rate and inflation stabilization policies.
The strict money rule restores this signal, however, and this becomes
the preferred policy. As part B of Table II shows, the money growth rule
provides an additional signal to uninformed agents that is not available
under the two types of policies and thus provided the minimum variance
of real output around its target.
VII. Conclusion
We analyze the effect of price level stabilization on the variance
of output in an open economy equilibrium business cycle model with
uninformed agents. We find that in most cases inflation stabilization is
as good as other traditional policies and that when shocks to the
economy persist, inflation stabilization is preferred. This result is
robust over specifications of the information set available to
uninformed agents. We also find that, in all cases, inflation
stabilization dominates exchange rate stabilization in terms of its
macroeconomic stabilization properties.
References
[1.] Benavie, Arthur and Richard Froyen, "A Note on Optimal
Monetary and Wage Indexation Policies in a Small Open Economy."
Australian Economic Papers, December 1991, 33440.
[2.] Black, Robert P., "Reflections on the Strategy of Monetary
Policy." Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond,
July/August 1990, 3-7.
[3.] Black, Susan and William T. Gavin, "Price Stability and the
Swedish Monetary Experiment." Economic Commentary, Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland, December 15, 1990.
[4.] Bradley, Michael D. and Dennis W. Jansen, "Informational
Implications of Money, Interest Rate, and Price Rules." Economic
Inquiry, July 1988, 437-48.
[5.] Dotsey, Michael and Robert G. King, "Informational
Implications of Interest Rate Rules." American Economic Review,
March 1986, 33-42.
[6.] Fischer, Stanley, "Monetary Rules and Commodity Money
Schemes Under Uncertainty." Journal of Monetary Economics, January
1986, 21-35.
[7.] Hercowitz, Zvi. "Money and the Dispersion of Relative
Price." Unpublished doctoral thesis, University of Rochester, 1980.
[8.] Kimbrough, Kent P, An Examination of the Effects of Government
Purchases in an Open Economy." Journal of International Money and
Finance, 1985, 113-33.
[9.] _____, "Aggregate Information and the Role of Monetary
Policy in an Open Economy." Journal of Political Economy, April
1984, 208-85.
[10.] _____, "Price, Output, and Exchange Rate Movements in the
Open Economy." Journal of Monetary Economics, January 1983, 25-44.
[11.] King, Robert G., "Monetary Policy and the Information
Content of Prices." Journal of Political Economy, April 1982,
247-79.
[12.] Lachler, Ulrich, "Fixed Versus Flexible Exchange Rates in
an Equilibrium Business Cycle Model." Journal of Monetary
Economics, July 1985, 95-107.
[13.] Marquis, Milton H. and Steven R. Cunningham, "Is There a
Role for Commodity Price in the Design of Monetary Policy? Some
Empirical Evidence."
(1.) See Black and Gavin [3] and the references cited therein.
(2.) In our model, as in most analyses, aggregate price level
stabilization takes place through minimization of deviations of the
actual price level from a pre-announced target for the price level which
is known by all agents in the economy. Because that pre-announced target
for the current price level could embody a non-zero level of expected
inflation, price level stabilization is equivalent to inflation
stabilization. Only if the pre-announced target level precludes any
growth in the aggregate price level would price level stability imply
zero inflation. As we do not impose this condition in this paper we will
use the terms price level stabilization and inflation stabilization
interchangeably.
(3.) In this work the information structure is exogenous. This
abstracts from issues regarding informational equilibrium and the
endogenous determination of the fraction [Lambda] of informed agents.
This interesting avenue for research is beyond the scope of the present
paper.
(4.) Clearly the persistence of these moving average shocks is only
for two periods, but this is sufficient to yield the qualitatively
different results for persistent shocks. An autoregressive specification
would result in additional algebraic complexity without yielding any
further qualitative results.
(5.) The direct demand effect of [g.sub.t], is included only for
completeness. We could "zero out" this demand effect without
changing our results.
(6.) The coefficients of equations (1) and (2) are related to the
coefficients of equations (3) and (4). For example, the coefficient of
the expected real interest rate in aggregate supply, [Alpha.sup.s], is
equal to the weighted average of coefficient of the expected interest
rate in nontraded goods supply, [Alpha.sup.s.sub.N], and the coefficient
of the expected interest rate in traded goods supply.
(7.) It is also true that the market for traded goods clears each
period. However, this equilibrium condition is not explicitly examined
here. Note that the domestic excess demand for traded goods is equal to
the value of net imports. It is not necessary to further analyze this
equilibrium condition for two reasons. First, we allow an equilibrium in
which net imports are non-zero. That is, we do not analyze a long run
equilibrium in which capital flows make net exports zero. Second, we do
not give uninformed agents information on current commodity flows such
as quantities supplied or demanded. Since net imports is such a measure,
we also do not allow uninformed agents to observe net imports.
Information on any of these variables would be very useful to uninformed
agents, but is assumed to be unavailable contemporaneously. The
practical justification for not permitting uninformed agents to observe
either output or the trade accounts contemporaneously is that such
information is available only with significant lags in the real world.
Thus, there is no information available to uninformed agents from the
equilibrium condition in the market for traded goods.
(8.) Aggregate supply defines aggregate income. Using equation (1),
we substitute in the values of E([r.sub.t]/[I.sub.t]) and
E([r.sub.t][U.sub.t]) implied by equilibrium in the nontraded goods
market. This gives an equation for aggregate income as:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
(9.) If the nontraded goods sector is stabilized at the full
information level of output, then so is the traded goods sector and
aggregate output. However, there may still be non-zero net exports, as
discussed in footnote 7.
(10.) We also analyzed the case in which policy makers pursued
"feedback" policies in an economy with persistent shocks. We
find, like many previous authors, that a complicated feedback rule will
be perfectly stabilizing. In this paper we focus on simpler and more
feasible policy rules and find that price level stabilization can
replicate the "perfect" stabilization of complicated feedback
rules in an economy with persistence.
(11.) The result occurs because under an inflation stabilization
policy (but not under either of the other two policies) the two signals
each contain a linear combination of the two shocks [g.sub.t] and
[[Epsilon].sub.N,t], and it is well known that two independent linear
combinations of two variables can be solved for the value of each of the
two variables.
(12.) This is analogous to the demonstration by Dotsey and King [5),
in a closed economy setting, that an interest rate peg is equivalent to
a certain