The Market Structure of Sports.
Johnson, Bruce K.
At a Middlebury College conference on the economics of baseball in
1991, the keynote speaker at the opening dinner declared that everything
important and interesting about the economics of professional sports had
already been said, and no further work was necessary.
Clearly, Gerald Scully, who attended the Middlebury dinner, found the
speaker's thesis less than compelling. He has published two books
on sports economics since then.
His latest volume, The Market Structure of Sports, begins with three
good chapters, but the remaining five chapters suffer from severe
theoretical and empirical shortcomings. Perhaps publication of the book
would have best been delayed until those failures could have been
overcome.
The introductory chapter might well have been given the same title as
the book. It first covers the product market, outlining the history of
American professional baseball, basketball, and football leagues. It
also describes the restrictions leagues place on franchise numbers and
movements, the relevant antitrust cases, and the cartelization of
broadcast rights. The product market section concludes with speculation
on the possible consequences of dropping all restrictions on club entry
and relocation.
The chapter then focuses on the input market, describing the
evolution of restrictive labor practices, the history of labor disputes,
and the distribution of income among players in the major team sports.
The next two chapters treat the players' market in more detail.
Chapter Two develops a model of team rank-order tournaments to determine
optimal intrateam salary structure. The greater the clubs'
monopsony power, the narrower the pay gap between the lowest and highest
paid players will be. This salary compression reduces the incentive of
the best players to invest in their skills.
An examination of baseball and basketball salaries confirms the
predictions of the rank-order tournament model. When monopsony power was
at its peak, the pay of the top players was about ten times that of the
bottom players. But free agency has increased the salaries of the top
players to fifty times those of the bottom players.
The third chapter examines the effects of the rules of the game on
the distribution of player income. It argues that sports emphasizing
team work and player interaction, such as football, should have a more
equal distribution of income than less interactive sports such as
baseball. The highest inequality should occur in individual sports such
as golf and tennis. The chapter also looks at the impact of the number
of contests, league revenue sharing, free agency, and salary caps on
income distribution.
Salaries in all four team sports, as well as some individual sports,
are examined and found consistent with the model. As measured by the
Gini coefficient, baseball has the greatest inequality of earnings,
followed by basketball, football, and hockey. Golf exhibits greater
inequality than any sport examined.
The remainder of the book falls far short of the quality of the first
three chapters. What follows should be considered an illustrative, but
not comprehensive, description of the problems.
Part Three purports to cover the market for sports franchises. But
Chapter Four, which begins it, measures momentum, or serial correlation in winning percentages. A team's performance next year will be
correlated with its performance this year. Anyone who has heard of the
Chicago Cubs and the Boston Celtics knows this, but skeptics can examine
several pages of autocorrelation estimations. Readers may well wonder,
though, what this has to do with the market for franchises, the market
structure of sports, or economics.
Chapter Five strains to show that momentum improves a club's
reputation, and clubs with better reputations are worth more. But only
two pages away from that claim, Scully says, "The demand for wins
depends on the size of the franchise market" and on the next page,
"clubs in big cities . . . win more games than small-city
clubs." Big-city teams sell for more than small-city teams, too. A
more plausible explanation of the role of momentum is that it is the
byproduct of market size, as is franchise value.
Chapter Six examines profits, capital appreciation, and ownership
duration. It asks which sport is most profitable, but it compares profit
margins, defined as profit divided by revenue, rather than return on
investment. What do profit margin comparisons show? Nothing. Grocery
stores have much lower profit margins than car dealers, but
risk-adjusted returns on investment in groceries and cars should be
equal. So should the profitability of baseball and football teams.
Whether they are is an interesting question, but profit margin
comparisons cannot answer it.
The chapter compounds the error by computing the total returns to
club ownership as the sum of a team's profit margin and its average
annual appreciation in market value. By this method the total annual
return in all sports in the 1990s is 27 percent, a number Scully
compares to rates of return on investment in other industries. But such
comparisons are meaningless.
Even if total returns were legitimately defined, the conclusions
drawn from the book's comparisons would be dubious. For instance,
Scully says that on a recent visit to Hong Kong some people told him the
average investment recovery period in real estate was three years, an
implicit annual rate of return of 26 percent. Since the Hong Kong
economy is highly competitive, he says, the 27 percent return in sports
"should not be judged as excessive."
The book's last two chapters cover coaching issues in sports.
They fail to regain the level of quality achieved in the first three
chapters.
In short, after a strong beginning, the quality of the book falls
significantly. The later chapters ask some interesting questions, but
the theoretical and empirical work do not measure up to Scully's
usual standards. Readers interested in sports economics might be better
advised to read earlier books by Quirk and Fort [1] or Scully [2].
Bruce K. Johnson Centre College
References
1. Quirk, James and Rodney D. Fort. Pay Dirt: The Business of
Professional Team Sports. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1992.
2. Scully, Gerald W. The Business of Major League Baseball. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1989.