Playing the Field: Why Sports Teams Move and Cities Fight to Keep Them.
Siegfried, John J.
Playing the Field is about the imbalance of power in negotiations
between professional sports teams and their urban hosts. That
professional sports teams have cities over a barrel in negotiations is
beyond question. The largesse that teams have extracted in concessions
from cities since the Dodgers and Giants bolted New York for California
is staggering. Many professional sports teams have persuaded cities to
build stadiums for their use and then have secured lease arrangements
that would make the holder of a well-maintained rent-controlled New York
penthouse blush. This power to extract rents is rooted in the geographic
mobility of professional sports teams.
Euchner's diagnosis of the underlying cause for this
metropolitan impotence in bargaining with professional sports teams is
the insulation of professional sports league admission and team transfer
rules from the Sherman Antitrust Act. Baseball acquired its protection
in the 1922 Supreme Court Federal Baseball Club v. National League decision written by Justice Oliver Wendell Holmes, in which the Court
decided that baseball at the time was not interstate commerce. Baseball
has eluded the wider definition of interstate commerce that has evolved
since then, although it currently is under Congressional assault,
specifically by Florida Senator Connie Mack. In 1962 professional
football obtained a statutory exemption for its collective sales of
broadcasting rights, and insulated its practice of restricting entry
into the league from antitrust scrutiny by including a provision
allowing such limitations in its agreement with the National Football
League Players Association. Provisions of collective bargaining
agreements negotiated at arms length are exempt from the Sherman Act.
The specific practice which brings cities to their knees when
bargaining with professional sports teams is the barrier to entry of new
teams into the premier league in each sport. This contrived scarcity
drives up the value of having a team. Some cities have professional
sports teams and others do not, making the acquisition of a franchise a
"positional good." Cities that host professional sports teams
believe they are recognized as "big league," relish the vivid
symbolism of growth and vitality represented by a professional sports
franchise, and enjoy the chance to promote a common interest in an urban
environment where conflict is more common than cooperation in the
perpetual battle for scarce resources. Because there are few decent
substitutes for a professional sports franchise, the demand for
franchises is very inelastic. Couple this with the fact that teams'
resources are mobile--their valuable assets are the rights to operate a
team in the premier league and player contracts, both of which can be
shipped in a small file cabinet--and there is excess supply of cities
yearning for a professional sports franchise. The result is that
city-team negotiations are no-contest.
Euchner's analysis of sports teams' successful bargaining
with municipalities is grounded in a well established public choice
paradigm--the concentration of benefits among a few contrasted with the
diffusion of costs among many. He supplements the traditional free-rider
story of the manipulation of government for the purpose of wealth
re-distribution with an analysis of the fragmentation of local politics
in America. Euchner notes that professional sports teams in other
countries seem unable to extract much, if anything, in the way of rents
from their local governments. This, he claims, is a function of both the
organization of sports leagues in other countries--where there is a
continuous hierarchy of leagues, and teams move up and down the
hierarchy on the basis of their playing success rather than at the
discretion of incumbents--and the greater central control of local
government authorities. The former reduces the elasticity of demand for
premier league franchises, and the latter limits cannibalistic competition among local government authorities.
It is remarkable how such an economically unimportant industry as
sports--the annual revenues of a typical major league baseball team are
roughly equivalent to those of a single large grocery store--can extract
so much more from local governments than can more important
manufacturing businesses. Euchner's explanation is the fact that
sports is a visible, symbolic, "big ticket" investment, the
kind of thing that a mayor can be remembered for, much more so than
marginal improvements in parks, libraries, schools, or street festivals.
Sports is also popular with elite established interest groups. Elites
self-identify with sports teams in a way that manufacturing firms seldom
enjoy. Euchner compares Baltimore's obviously greater concern for
retaining the Colts and Orioles, for example, than for keeping the
Esskay meat company in town, even though the latter was a much more
important local employer asking for substantially fewer concessions from
Baltimore taxpayers. But, then, who ever heard of the "Baltimore
cold cuts?"
The role of elites in metropolitan give-aways to sports teams is
usually submerged in discussions of sports, which are frequently
characterized as a service provided primarily for the lower middle class
blokes who populate the bleachers. But, in fact, the incomes of ticket
purchasers to sporting events are generally above average. And the
fraction of people in a metropolitan area who attend the events of a
professional sports franchise is quite small. Because large fractions of
stadiums are sold out to season ticket holders, those who attend do so
frequently, which is one source of their intense interest in securing or
retaining a franchise. For a relatively few people, a professional
sports franchise creates enormous consumer surplus; but for most it
creates no benefits and a modest increase in taxes to subsidize
stadiums.
The interested elites have the incentives, small numbers, connections
and organizational skills to successfully press their demands on city
governments. They are usually part and parcel of the planning process,
which helps them pass by the public so-called "studies" of
planned stadiums and arenas that are usually no more than optimistic
guesses about future bookings and attendance. These studies invariably "prove" that the impact of a sports team on local economic
development and employment will be unprecedented. The public, unable to
dissect such studies, rarely sees through the inflated multipliers,
exaggerated benefits and overlooked opportunity costs that characterize
these reports. Such studies seem to suggest that all of the inputs for
construction and sports team operations will originate in the local area
(enhancing the multiplier), and never mention the potential benefits
that are sacrificed when the invested capital is unavailable for use in
improving the city's housing stock, secondary education, or
transportation corridors.
The limited hard evidence about the economic impact of new stadiums
and sports teams on metropolitan areas summarized by Euchner provides
virtually no support for the use of sports teams to develop a local
economy. Rather than spurring industries that can develop strong export
potential, investments in stadiums for professional sports franchises
tend to simply rearrange what has already been produced. People who
attend sporting events would have spent their entertainment dollars on
other local services. The diffused general public, who are asked to foot
the bill for a free stadium to attract or retain a franchise do not
object because they do not have the individual incentive or
organizational skills to resist these demands.
Playing the Field is an interesting book about local politics in
America. It illustrates how the less-than-zero-sum game of inter-city
competition for jobs can get out of hand when the benefits are
concentrated among the relatively few elite and the costs are dispersed.
It is also fun to read. The dust cover photo of a packed Baltimore
Camden Yards stadium is a gem.
John J. Siegfried Vanderbilt University