Wage growth and the inflationary process: a reexamination.
Darrat, Ali F.
I. Introduction
The nature of the relationship between wage growth and inflation has
long been the subject of on-going debate. The expectations-augmented
Phillips-curve theory contends that the two variables are mutually
causal. However, the original wage-type Phillips-curve model argues it
is inflation that causes wage growth rather than vice versa. The
price-markup scheme holds an opposite view and asserts that wage growth
plays an independent causal role in the inflationary process. Of course,
other theories (e.g., the monetarist) deny the presence of any reliable
linkage between wages and prices.
Researchers have also expended enormous effort attempting to
investigate empirically the relationship between wage growth and
inflation, but with mixed results. For example, Mehra [24] and
Ashenfelter and Card [1] report results suggesting a bidirectional causality; Barth and Bennett [2] and Stein [37; 38] find causality
running from prices to wages without feedback; while Shannon and Wallace
[34] and Hill and Robinson [19] report results showing causality only in
the reverse direction, from wages to prices. Still, Gordon [11],
Bazdarich [4], Batten [3], and Mehra [27] find no causal linkage between
the two variables. Clearly, such remarkably mixed evidence is
unfortunate in light of the profound implications that the precise
wage/price relationship may have for economic and public policy.
A more recent and quite interesting study is that of Mehra [28].
Mehra employed the technique of cointegration and error-correction
modelling on U.S. quarterly data for the period 1959:1-1989:3. He
concluded that inflation and wage growth are cointegrated, implying that
their long-run movements are correlated as the expectations-augmented
Phillips-curve theory predicts. However, contrary to this theory, and in
accordance with the original wage-type Phillips-curve view, Mehra argued
that the inflation-wage growth long-run correlation is primarily the
outcome of the former causing the latter.
Mehra's model encompasses three basic variables; namely, prices
(p), productivity-adjusted wages (w), and an output-gap proxy (g).(1) He
tested each of the three variables (in logs) for the presence of unit
roots, finding evidence of two unit roots in p and w, but a single unit
root in g. Mehra then examined cointegration of the two variables having
two unit roots (p, w). His results suggest that first-differences (but
not levels) of prices and wages are cointegrated. Following Granger [14;
15], this finding if valid implies an error-correction model for
inflation and wage growth and the presence of a Granger-causation
between the two variables, at least in one direction. As mentioned,
Mehra's results suggest that Granger-causality exists, but only
from inflation to wage growth.
While interesting, Mehra's cointegration inferences may suffer
from a serious omission-of-variable problem potentially biasing his
results. Granger [15] has shown that cointegration and Granger-causality
are closely related concepts. As such, cointegration tests may also be
sensitive to the omission-of-variables phenomenon discussed by Lutkepohl
[22] for Granger-causality tests. It is well-known that causality (and,
by extension, also cointegration) inferences in a trivariate inflation
model are not necessarily robust to inclusion of other relevant
macroeconomic variables that could influence inflation. Interestingly,
cointegration results recently reported by Miller [29] indicate that
omission of important variables from a basic model did significantly
distort his cointegration findings.
Literature on inflation provides a logical extension to Mehra's
model. In particular, three additional variables appear potentially
important for the inflationary process: namely, money supply, foreign
exchange rate, and interest rates. The quantity theory of money places
substantial weight on monetary changes in determining growth in
aggregate demand and thus inflation. Empirical support of this
monetarist view of inflation is overwhelming, as exemplified in the work
of Fama [8], Dwyer and Hafer [5], and Hallman, Porter and Small [17]. In
fact, in other studies, Mehra [25; 26; 27] also reports results
indicating the significant role of money growth in the U.S. inflationary
process.
A theoretical basis for linking inflation to exchange rates can be
found in the theory of purchasing power parity [9; 12; 30]. Several
empirical studies have uncovered significant relationships between
movements in the dollar's exchange rate and U.S. price behavior,
especially since the advent of the floating exchange rates in 1973.
Examples include Sachs [31], Solomon [36], Whitt, Koch and Rosenweig
[41], and Himarios [20]. Finally, for models of nominal income and its
components (e.g., prices), Sims [35] strongly recommends the inclusion
of interest rates. Several empirical studies have confirmed Sims's
contention, including Fackler [7], Litterman and Weiss [21], and Stock
and Watson [39]. Furthermore, Mehra [27] also finds evidence of the
importance of interest rates (and money growth) in determining U.S.
inflation.
The preceding discussion suggests the appropriateness of testing a
general inflation model that encompasses the possible roles of money
supply, foreign exchange rates and interest rates along with the two
factors examined by Mehra [28]; namely wages and the output gap.(2)
The main purpose of this paper therefore is to reexamine Mehra's
conclusions regarding the wage-price causal linkage in the context of a
broader model. The empirical results from cointegration tests and the
implied error-correction representation significantly alter Mehra's
results and indicate their fragility to the omission of important
variables. The following section discusses the results from unit-roots
and cointegration tests. Next, findings for Granger-causality are
analyzed. Concluding remarks are offered in the final section.
II. Test Results for Unit Roots and Cointegration
Following Mehra, I employ the augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test to
examine unit roots in each of the six variables. These are again the
price level (p), productivity-adjusted wages (w), an output-gap (g),
money stock (m), foreign exchange rates (e), and interest rates (r). As
in Mehra, p is measured by the log of the fixed-weight GNP deflator, w
is the log of the index of unit labor cost of the nonfarm business
sector, and g is the log of real GNP over potential real output. The
money variable (m) is the log of M1(3) and the foreign exchange rate (e)
is the log of the exchange rate between the Japanese yen and the U.S.
dollar. Hafer [16] finds evidence favoring the use of a bilateral
exchange rate over the more common trade-weighted exchange rates in
studying the exchange rate/inflation linkage. Given the fact that Japan
is the largest trading partner with the U.S., I use the yen/dollar
exchange rate. Indeed, in their September 1985 exchange-rate conference,
the Group of Five (G-5) countries increasingly focused on the value of
the yen relative to the dollar as a key indicator of the dollar's
behavior in foreign markets [32].(4) Finally, the interest rate (r)
variable is the log of the three-month Treasury Bill rate.(5) To use
comparable data, all series come (as in Mehra's) from the Citibank
data bank, except for data on potential real output which is similarly
compiled from the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Like
Mehra, my estimation period starts in 1959:1 but it extends to 1991:4.
Terminating the sample period at 1989:3 used by Mehra produced similar
results. Following Mehra, supply stock variables (relative prices of
energy, food and imports) were included in the testing equations when
they proved significant. Also included were dummy variables representing
the periods during and immediately after Nixon's wage and price
controls. For ease of comparison, I employ similar notations to those of
Mehra's.
Table I reports the results from applying the ADF test on the six
variables in levels and first differences. The results from the
[[Phi].sub.3] statistics suggest the presence of two unit roots in four
of the variables considered; namely, prices (p), wages (w), money stock
(m), and exchange rates (e). The remaining two variables, output-gap (g)
and interest rates (r), appear to exhibit a single unit root. None of
the t-statistics for the time trend proves significant. These results
seem robust to Schwert's [33] argument that the above unit root
tests may be biased if the time series are generated by moving as well
as autoregressive elements. Following Mehra, the results were checked
for this difficulty by using longer lags than those suggested by the FPE criterion, and repeating the unit root tests. The results provided
similar inferences.
The second step is to use the Engle and Granger [6] procedure to test
for cointegration among the four variables having two unit roots. Table
II displays the results of testing for cointegration between the four
variables expressed in levels and first-differences. Unlike
Mehra's, these results suggest that residuals from the regressions
of wages in both the levels and first-differences have unit roots. On
the other hand, residuals from the remaining three regressions (of p, m,
and e) have unit roots only in the levels, but not in first-differences.
These findings indicate that while the levels of prices, money stock and
exchange rates are not cointegrated, the growth rates of TABULAR DATA
OMITTED these variables are cointegrated. Hence, long-run movements in
the growth rates of prices, money stock, and exchange rates are
correlated.
In sum, the above results suggest that, contrary to Mehra, growth in
wages is not cointegrated with growth in prices and thus their long-run
movements appear uncorrelated. As discussed earlier, Mehra's
finding appears to be the result of omitting some relevant variables
(particularly money stock and exchange rates) from his cointegrating
regressions.(6)
III. Test Results for Granger-Causality
The above unit-root and cointegration test results suggest that
prices, money stock, and exchange rates have an error-correction
representation of the form:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
TABULAR DATA OMITTED
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where the [Epsilon]'s are the disturbance terms, and the
error-correction terms z's are the residuals obtained from the
cointegrating regressions in first-differences reported in Table II.
That is:
[z.sub.1] = [Delta][p.sub.t] - a - [b.sub.1][Delta][w.sub.t] -
[b.sub.2][Delta][m.sub.t] - [b.sub.3][Delta][e.sub.t] -
[b.sub.4][g.sub.t] - [b.sub.5][r.sub.t]
[z.sub.2] = [Delta][m.sub.t] - [[Phi].sub.0] -
[[Phi].sub.1][Delta][p.sub.t] - [[Phi].sub.2][Delta][w.sub.t] -
[[Phi].sub.3][Delta][e.sub.t] - [[Phi].sub.4][g.sub.t] -
[[Phi].sub.5][r.sub.t]
[z.sub.3] = [Delta][e.sub.t] - [[Lambda].sub.0] -
[[Lambda].sub.1][Delta][p.sub.t] - [[Lambda].sub.2][Delta][w.sub.t] -
[[Lambda].sub.3][Delta][m.sub.t] - [[Lambda].sub.4][g.sub.t] -
[[Lambda].sub.5][r.sub.t].
Since [Delta]p, [Delta]m, and [Delta]e appear to be cointegrated,
there must be Granger-causality between them in at least one direction
[15]. The null hypothesis that money stock does not Granger-cause
prices, for example, is rejected not only if the [[Lambda].sub.2]'s
in (1) are jointly significant, but also if [h.sub.1] is significant.
Therefore, this error-correction representation of Granger-causality
allows for the finding that money stock Granger-causes prices, even when
the group coefficients on the money stock variable in the inflation
equation are jointly insignificant, provided the error-correction
coefficient ([h.sub.1]) is significant. Conversely, money is said to
Granger-cause prices even if the error-correction coefficient is
insignificant, provided that lags on the money stock are jointly
significant.
Before discussing the empirical results from the EC model, a number
of issues seem important. First, when conducting the unit-root and the
cointegration tests, Mehra used the Akaike FPE procedure to determine
the appropriate lag structure on all variables. However, when estimating
his error-correction model, Mehra abandoned the FPE criterion without
any explanation and employed instead "some arbitrarily selected lag
lengths." For consistency, nonetheless, results from applying the
same FPE procedure should also be reported. Therefore, unlike Mehra, I
also report results from the error-correction model on the basis of the
FPE criterion in addition to reporting results using similar lag
specifications that were arbitrarily selected by Mehra. To check on the
robustness of the results, I also used Hendry's general-to-specific
approach to determine the lag profile for the EC model [10].
Second, there is the possibility that a structural shift may have
occurred around the fourth quarter of 1979 corresponding to the change
in the Federal Reserve operating strategy. This was apparently the
reason that Mehra reported results for the sub-period terminated in
1979:4. However, this shift does not appear significant, judged by the
similarity of Mehra's results for the full and sub-period samples.
Yet, rather than ignoring altogether the structural instability issue
when estimating the EC model,(7) I used the Chow test to check
instability of each estimated equation, using 1979:4 as the breaking
date. Only the money growth equation appears generally unstable across
lag specifications. I used the Gujarati dummy-variable approach and
isolated significant intercept- and slope-dummy variables that remain in
the final equations.(8) Third, I tested all regressions in Table III for
significant autocorrelations using the Breusch-Godfrey test and found
none. Moreover, Ramsey's RESET test could not reject the hypothesis
of no specification errors.
TABULAR DATA OMITTED
Finally, the method of estimating the EC equations requires some
discussion. Apparently, Mehra used ordinary least-squares to estimate
his wage and price regressions. Yet, more efficient estimates are
possible using methods like the Zellner Seemingly-Unrelated Regressions
(SUR) procedure, provided the errors across equations exhibit
significant correlation. This is the case in the implied EC model,
particularly for the money and exchange rate equations whose errors are
highly significant at better than the one-percent level (correlation
coefficient = 0.26, t = 3.06). Therefore, results for the three-equation
EC model reported in Table III come from the Zellner SUR technique for
each triad of equations.(9)
These results indicate that the error-correction coefficients in the
price regressions across alternative lag specifications are generally
not statistically significant. Also interesting is the finding that lags
on the wage variable in the price regressions [Mathematical Expression
Omitted] are statistically insignificant. Together with an insignificant
error-correction coefficient, these results imply that wages do not
Granger-cause prices. Such evidence further corroborates the earlier
finding that long-run movements in wages and prices are not correlated.
The price regressions in Table III also show that the remaining
variables (money stock, exchange rates, output-gap, and to a lesser
extent also interest rates) generally Granger-cause prices across the
alternative specifications (see the values of [Mathematical Expression
Omitted], [Mathematical Expression Omitted], [Mathematical Expression
Omitted], and [Mathematical Expression Omitted]). The overall
statistical significance of these variables in the error-correction
model may serve as additional evidence for the potential bias in
Mehra's trivariate price equations.
Table III further suggests that the error-correction coefficients in
the money and exchange rate regressions are statistically significant
across alternative specifications. This finding implies the presence of
Granger-causality from all right-hand-side variables included in these
regressions to the money and exchange rate variables. Note that the
exchange-rate variable in the money equation and the money variable in
the exchange-rate equation consistently appear with significant lagged
coefficients. Combined with a significant error-correction coefficient
in the respective regressions, it can be argued that a strong
bidirectional Granger-causality exists between money stock and exchange
rates. Although the other four variables also Granger-cause money and
exchange rates (prices, wages, output-gap, and interest rates), it
appears that their Granger-causality effect is transmitted primarily
through the error-correction term in the respective regressions.
IV. Conclusion
This paper reexamines the issue of causality between wages and prices
using unit-root and co-integration tests and their implied
error-correction representation. Unlike Mehra's [28] recent
trivariate model (wages, prices, and output-gap), I expand the model to
include other theoretically relevant determinants of the inflationary
process; namely, money supply, exchange and interest rates. It is
well-known that omitting relevant variables can bias inferences from
Granger-causality tests. The results reported in this paper demonstrate
that cointegration inferences too, as reported in Mehra, are subject to
similar omission-of-variable biases.
The most striking finding in this paper is that, contrary to
Mehra's conclusion, wages and prices are not cointegrated and thus
do not exhibit a reliable long-run relationship.(10) This finding is
consistent, at least in spirit, with Gordon's [13] regression
results and offers a new piece of evidence supporting Gordon's view
that wages and prices are irrelevant to each other, and that they
"live a life of their own".(11) The life of prices, it should
be noted, seems correlated over the long-run with the behavior of money
supply and exchange rates (rather than with wages). The results further
show that Granger-causality underlying the movements in prices, money
stock, and exchange rates is not one-sided, but rather mutual and
complex. Therefore, a fruitful inquiry into the behavior of prices
should be performed within a simultaneous-equation framework that
emphasizes the joint determination of prices, money supply, and exchange
rates.
1. In addition, some of Mehra's regressions included
price-control dummies and supply-shock (relative-price) variables for
food, energy, and imports.
2. A theoretical derivation of a similar general model of inflation
can be found in Haslag and Ozment [18] and Stockton and Struckmeyer
[40]. These researchers report further empirical evidence showing the
superiority of such general inflation models to alternative views that
ignore one or more possible determinants underlying the inflationary
process.
3. Use of M2 or the monetary base instead of M1 did not alter the
main conclusions of the paper. Results using these alternative monetary
aggregates are available upon request.
4. The increased share and importance of Japan in U.S. international
trade is also evident in the recent heated discussion in government and
popular media circles regarding the huge trade deficit between the two
countries. Note also that the need to employ a comparable sample period
to that of Mehra's precluded the use of trade-weighted exchange
rates whose series does not date back to 1959.
5. Alternative measures, like the 4-6 month commercial paper rate,
yielded similar results.
6. Interestingly, my finding of no reliable relationship between
inflation and wage growth is consistent with the Granger-noncausality
evidence between the two variables reported by Mehra [27]. Instead of
the wage growth, Mehra concluded that the output gap, money growth and
interest rates are the three main causal variables underlying the U.S.
inflation.
7. Lutkepohl [23] demonstrates that structural stability is required
to produce reliable inferences from Granger-causality tests.
8. The significant dummy variables in the FPE and general-to-specific
selected money equations are the intercept-dummy and the slope-dummy for
the first lag of interest rates. For other money equations, the
significant dummy variables are the first and third lags of interest
rates in the four common-lag model; and the first lag of interest rates
along with the first and fourth lags of the output gap. None of the
dummy variables is significant in the eight common-lag model.
9. Following Mehra, the price-control dummies and the supply-stock
variables for food, energy, and imports were included in each equation
(using alternative lags) only when they prove statistically significant.
10. It should be noted that available cointegration tests are all
designed to searching for long-run linear relationships among
macroeconomic variables. Thus, the evidence reported above does not
necessarily preclude the possibility that wages and prices may still
exhibit, in some unknown fashion, a non-linear long-run relationship.
11. Earlier, Gordon arrived at essentially the same verdict. He
states, "the wage-push hypothesis appears to be alive and well as
an explanation of wage rate, but not as a theory of inflation" [11,
433].
References
1. Ashenfelter, Orley and David Card, "Time Series
Representation of Economic Variables and Alternative Models of the Labor
Market." Review of Economic Studies, 1982, 761-81.
2. Barth, James R. and James T. Bennett, "Cost-Push Versus
Demand-Pull Inflation: Some Empirical Evidence." Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking, August 1975, 391-97.
3. Batten, Dallas S., "Inflation: The Cost-Push Myth."
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Review, June/July 1981, 20-26.
4. Bazdarich, Michael T., "Inflation and Monetary Accommodation
in the Pacific Basin." Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco,
Economic Review, Summer 1978, 23-36.
5. Dwyer, Gerald P. and R. W. Hafer, "Is Money Irrelevant?"
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Review, May/June 1988, 3-17.
6. Engle, Robert F. and Clive W. J. Granger, "Cointegration and
Error-Correction: Representation, Estimation, and Testing."
Econometrica, March 1987, 251-76.
7. Fackler, James S., "An Empirical Analysis of the Markets for
Goods, Money and Credit." Journal of Money, Credit and Banking,
February 1985, 28-42.
8. Fama, Eugene F., "Inflation, Output, and Money." Journal
of Business, April 1982, 201-31.
9. Frenkel, Jacob A., "Purchasing Power Parity: Doctrin
Perspective and Evidence for the 1920s." Journal of International
Economics, May 1978, 169-91.
10. Gilbert, C. L., "Professor Hendry's Econometric Methodology." Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, August
1986, 282-303.
11. Gordon, Robert T., "World Inflation and Monetary
Accommodation in Eight Countries" Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity, 1977, 409-468.
12. -----. "Inflation, Flexible Exchange Rates, and the Natural
Rate of Unemployment," in Workers, Jobs, and Inflation, edited by
Martin N. Baily. Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1982.
13. -----. "The Role of Wages in the lnflationary Process."
American Economic Review, May 1988, (Papers and Proceedings), 276-83.
14. Granger, Clive W. J., "Developments in the Study of
Cointegrated Economic Variables." Oxford Bulletin of Economics and
Statistics, August 1986, 213-28.
15. -----. "Some Recent Developments in the Concept of
Causality." Journal of Econometrics, September/October 1988,
199-211.
16. Hafer, R. W., "Does Dollar Depreciation Cause
Inflation?" Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Review, July/August
1989, 16-28.
17. Hallman, Jeffrey J., Richard D. Porter and David H. Small,
"M2 Per Unit of Potential GNP as an Anchor for the Price
Level." American Economic Review, September 1991, 841-58.
18. Haslaq, Joseph H. and D'Ann M. Ozment, "Money Growth,
Supply Shocks, and Inflation." Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas,
Economic Review, May 1991, 1-17.
19. Hill, John K. and Kenneth J. Robinson, "Money, Wages, and
Factor Scarcity as Predictors of Inflation." Federal Reserve Bank
of Dallas, Economic Review, May 1989, 21-29.
20. Himarios, Daniel, "The Impact of the Exchange Rate on U.S.
Inflation and GNP Growth: Comment." Southern Economic Journal,
April 1989, 1044-51.
21. Littermon, Robert B. and Lawrence Weiss, "Money, Real
Interest Rates and Output: A Re-interpretation of Postwar U.S.
Data." Econometrica, January 1985, 128-56.
22. Lutkepohl, Helmut, "Non-Causality Due to Omitted
Variables." Journal of Econometrics, August 1982, 367-78.
23. -----. "The Stability Assumption in Tests of Causality
Between Money and Income," in Econometrics of Structural Change:
Studies in Empirical Economics, edited by Walter Kramer-West Germany:
Physica-Verlaq Heidelberg, 1989.
24. Mehra, Yash P., "Money Wages, Prices, and Causality."
Journal of Political Economy, December 1977, 1227-44.
25. -----. "The Forecast Performance of Alternative Models of
Inflation." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Economic Review,
September/October 1988, 10-18.
26. -----. "Cointegration and a Test of the Quarterly Theory of
Money." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Working Paper 89-2, April
1989.
27. -----. "Real Output and Unit Labor Costs as Predictors of
Inflation." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Economic Review,
September/October 1990, 31-39.
28. -----. "Wage Growth and the Inflationary Process: An
Empirical Note." American Economic Review, September 1991, 931-37.
29. Miller, Stephen M., "Monetary Dynamics: An Application of
Cointegration and Error-Correction Modeling." Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking, May 1991, 139-54.
30. Officer, Lawrence H., "The Purchasing-Power Parity Theory of
Exchange Rates: A Review Article" International Monetary Fund,
Staff Papers, March 1976, 1-60.
31. Sachs, Jeffrey D., "The Dollar and the Policy Mix:
1985." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1985, 117-85.
32. Sakamoto, Tomohiko, "The Japan-US Bilateral Trade."
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, Economic Review, Spring 1988,
3-13.
33. Schwert, G. Williams, "Effects of Model Specification on
Tests for Unit Roots in Macroeconomic Data." Journal of Monetary
Economics, July 1987, 73-103.
34. Shannon, Russell and Myles S. Wallace, "Wage and Inflation:
An Investigation into Causality." Journal of Post-Keynesian
Economics, Winter 1986, 182-91.
35. Sims, Christopher, "Macroeconomic and Reality."
Econometrica, January 1980, 1-48.
36. Solomon, Robert. "Effects of the Strong Dollar," in The
U.S. Dollar-Recent Developments. Outlook, and Policy Options. Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City, 1985, pp. 65-88.
37. Stein, Jerome L., "The Acceleration of Inflation."
Journal of Post-Keynesian Economics, Fall 1979, 26-42.
38. -----, "Reply to McKenna and Zannoni." Journal of
Post-Keynesian Economics, Spring 1984, 479-80.
39. Stock, James and Mark Watson, "Interpreting the Evidence on
Money-Income Causality." Journal of Econometrics, January 1989,
161-82.
40. Stockton, David T. and Charles S. Struckmeyer, "Tests of the
Specification and Predictive Accuracy of Non-nested Models of
Inflation." Review of Economics and Statistics, May 1989, 275-83.
41. Whitt, Joseph A., Paul D. and J. A. Rosenweig, "The Dollar
and Prices: An Empirical Analysis." Federal Reserve Bank of
Atlanta, Economic Review, October 1986, 4-18.