Anticipated shocks and the acceleration hypothesis: the implication of wage indexation.
Lai, Ching-Chong
I. Introduction
In his well cited contribution, Sachs [14] sets up a macromodel
embodying the wage setting process, perfect foresight, and the portfolio
balance feature. It examines the exchange-rate and current-account
responses to unanticipated fiscal expansion under alternative wage
indexation rules. He finds that, in the nominal wage rigidity (no wage
indexation) model, the exchange-rate depreciation coincides with a
current account deficit; in the real-wage rigidity (full wage
indexation) case, the exchange rate again depreciates with a
current-account deficit and appreciates with a surplus [14, 744-45].(1)
Sachs's result is consistent with Kouri's [12] acceleration
hypothesis: a current-account deficit is accompanied by currency
depreciation, and conversely.
After the publication of the Dornbusch and Fischer [8] paper, the
literature on acceleration hypothesis has shifted from unanticipated
shocks to anticipated shocks. Dornbusch and Fischer [8] find that a
negative correlation between the exchange rate and the current account
prevails prior to the implementation of anticipated shocks.
Consequently, their conclusion indicates the acceleration hypothesis is
not held when the economy experiences anticipated shocks. Bhandari [4]
and Papell [13] claim that the status of current account and the
response of exchange rate can have either a positive or a negative
correlation in response to anticipated shocks. Based on the fact that
Sachs [14] does not deal with the anticipated disturbances, the first
purpose of this paper thus tries to shed light on whether the
alternative wage indexation schemes will affect the validity of the
acceleration hypothesis in response to an anticipated fiscal expansion.
In an interesting paper, Aoki [1] bases on the modified Dornbusch [7]
model and examines the exchange-rate responses to anticipated supply
shocks. He finds that an entirely different type of exchange-rate
adjustment pattern--misadjustment path--can arise when economic
variables respond to anticipated shocks in perfect foresight models.
According to Aoki's definition, a misadjustment path of exchange
rate possesses two features: (i) impact adjustment and long-run adjustment of exchange rate are in opposite direction; (ii) the response
of exchange rate during some beginning periods moves further away from
its eventual new equilibrium value.(2) Aoki [1] further claims that two
requirements should be satisfied to establish misadjustment path: (i)
the dynamic system must have at least two unstable eigenvalues; (ii) the
first arrival of the news of a future shock must lead the realization of
the shock by more than a minimum of time [1, 415-6].(3) Based on
Sachs' [14] framework, the second purpose of this paper is to show
that even if the model exhibits a saddlepoint stability rather than the
global instability proposed by Aoki [1], the misadjustment pattern of
exchange rate can be observed in response to an anticipated fiscal
expansion.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. The structure of the
Sachs [14] model is outlined in section II. Section III will present a
complete dynamic adjustment under alternative wage indexation rules.
Finally, section IV will give the concluding remarks.
II. The Sachs Model
The Sachs [14] model can be summarized as follows. Consider an open
economy that is "small" enough to regard the foreign price and
interest rate as exogenously determined. Domestic production is limited
to a single final commodity, which is partly consumed domestically and
partly exported. Domestic consumers have access to both domestic good
and imported good. These goods are regarded by domestic residents as
imperfect substitutes. Three assets are available to domestic residents:
domestic money, domestic bonds, and foreign bonds. The latter two are
regarded as perfect substitutes. Market participants form their
expectations with perfect foresight. Accordingly, the economy can be
characterized by the following macroeconomic relationships:
q = -[Alpha](w - [p.sub.c]) + (1 - [Lambda])[Alpha] [Pi]; [Alpha] [is
greater than] 0, 0 [is less than] [Lambda] [is less than] 1 (1)
w = [w.sub.0] + [Theta] [p.sub.c]; (2)
q = [[Gamma].sub.1]D* + [[Gamma].sub.2]g + [[Gamma].sub.3]T;
[[Gamma].sub.1], [[Gamma].sub.2], [[Gamma].sub.3] [is greater than] 0
(3)
T = -[[Theta].sub.1]q + [[Theta].sub.2]q* - [[Theta].sub.3]7[Pi];
[[Theta].sub.1], [[Theta].sub.2], [[Theta].sub.3] [is greater than] 0
(4)
m - p = [Phi]q - bR + [Delta]D*; [Phi], b, [Delta] [is greater than]
0 (5)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
[Pi] = p - p* - e (8)
[p.sub.c] = [Lambda]p - (1 - [Lambda])(p* + e) (9)
where q = output, w = nominal wage, [p.sub.c] = general price level,
[Pi] = terms of trade, [w.sub.0] = minimum wage (or contract wage),
[Theta] = the degree of wage indexation, D* = nominal stock of foreign
bonds (denominated in foreign currency), g = government spending, T =
trade balance, q* = foreign output, m = nominal money supply, p =
domestic price level, R = domestic interest rate, R* = foreign interest
rate, p* = foreign prices of imported goods, e = exchange rate (defined
as the domestic currency price of foreign currency), lower-case letters
denote logarithms of upper-case variables, and an overdot denotes the
rate of change with respect to time.
Equation (1) is the aggregate supply function. Equation (2) describes
alternative forms of wage indexation scheme. If there is no wage
indexation ([Theta] = 0), nominal wages are rigid at [w.sub.0]. If
nominal wages are fully indexed to the general price ([Theta] = 1), real
wages are fixed at [w.sub.0].(4) Equations (3) and (4) describe the
aggregate demand function and the trade balance, respectively. Equation
(5) is the equilibrium condition for the money market. Equation (6)
describes the interest rate parity as domestic bonds and foreign bonds
are perfect substitutes. Equation (7) states that domestic holdings of
foreign bonds will change over time in response to the current-account
balance, which is the sum of the trade balance and the service balance.
Equation (8) is the definition of terms of trade. Finally, equation (9)
defines the general price to be a multiplicatively weighted average of
the price of domestic and imported goods.
III. Dynamic Adjustment
This section deals with the interaction between the dynamics of
anticipated fiscal expansion and the current account balance with
alternative wage indexation schemes.
We now proceed to analyze the dynamic behavior of the economy.
Following Sachs [14], linearize equation (7) around T = D* = 0,
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] and E = P = 1 initially and manipulate the resulting equation and equations (1)-(6), (8) and (9), it obtains(5)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where
[a.sub.11] = {[Alpha][Theta](1 - [Lambda])(1 +
[[Gamma].sub.3][[Theta].sub.1]) + [[Gamma].sub.3][[Theta].sub.3][1 +
[Alpha][Phi](1 - [Theta])]}/b[Delta] [is greater than] 0,
[a.sub.12] = ([[Gamma].sub.1] + [Delta][Delta] +
[Omega][Phi][[Gamma].sub.1])/b[Delta] [is greater than] 0,
[a.sub.21] = [Alpha](1 - [Theta])[[Theta].sub.3]/[Delta] [is greater
than or equal to] 0,
[a.sub.22] = R* - ([Omega][[Theta].sub.1] +
[[Theta].sub.3])[[Gamma].sub.1]/[Delta] [is greater than or less than
to] 0,
[c.sub.1] = [[Gamma].sub.2](1 + [Phi][Omega])/b[Delta] [is greater
than] 0, and
[c.sub.2] = -([Omega][[Phi].sub.1] +
[[Theta].sub.3])[[Gamma].sub.2]/[Delta] [is less than] 0,
[Omega] = [Alpha][(1 - [Theta])[Lambda] + (1 - [Lambda])] [is greater
than] 0, and
[Delta] = [[Gamma].sub.3][[Theta].sub.3] + (1 +
[[Gamma].sub.3][[Theta].sub.1])[Omega] [is greater than] 0.
In what follows, we will show that the sign of [a.sub.21] is
currently related to the degree of wage indexation [Theta], and in turn
generates a distinctive match between the current-account balance and
the exchange-rate adjustment, which is not presented in the
literature.(6)
Let S be the characteristic root of the dynamic system, we then have
the following characteristic equation:
[S.sup.2] - ([a.sub.11] + [a.sub.22])S + ([a.sub.11][a.sub.22] -
[a.sub.12][a.sub.21]) = 0. (11)
Since the exchange rate is a forward-looking variable, and the stock
of foreign bonds is a stock variable and will accumulate or decumulate
over time through the current-account surplus or deficit, it is
necessary to assume [S.sub.1][S.sub.2] = [a.sub.11][a.sub.22] -
[a.sub.12][a.sub.21] [is less than] 0 for the system to be
convergent.(7) This implies that the system displays the saddle-point
stability which is common to perfect foresight models. Due to the fact
that the wage indexation scheme will contribute different adjustment
patterns of exchange rate and current account behavior, in what follows
we will in turn examine the adjustment process to a current announcement
of a future increase in government spending under alternative wage
indexation rules.
Full Wage Indexation
Under full wage indexation ([Theta] = 1), it is clear from equation
(10) that [S.sub.1] = 1/b [is greater than] 0, [S.sub.2] = R* -
[[Alpha][[Theta].sub.1](1 - [Lambda]) +
[[Theta].sub.3]][[Gamma].sub.1]/[[[Gamma].sub.3][[Theta].sub.3] +
[Alpha](1 - [Lambda])(1 + [[Gamma].sub.3][[Theta].sub.1])] [is less
than] 0 which is required for the stability. The evolution of the system
can be illustrated by means of a phase diagram like Figure 1. It is
obvious from equation (10) that the slopes of loci [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] and [Mathematical Expression Omitted] with [Theta] =
1 are
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
As indicated by the direction of the arrows in Figure 1, the lines SS
and UU represent the stable and unstable branches, respectively.
Evidently, the convergent saddle path SS is always downward sloping and
must be flatter than the [Mathematical Expression Omitted] locus, while
the divergent branch UU coincides with the [Mathematical Expression
Omitted] schedule.
We now study the adjustment process of the economy, in which at time
t = 0 the authorities announce the government spending will increase
from [g.sub.0] to [g.sub.[Tau]] at a specific date t = [Tau] in the
future. In Figures 2(a) and 2(b), the initial equilibrium, where
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] intersects [Mathematical Expression
Omitted], is at [K.sub.0]; the initial exchange rate and foreign bonds
stock are [e.sub.0] and [D*.sub.0], respectively. Upon the shock of
anticipated fiscal expansion, both [Mathematical Expression Omitted] and
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] shift leftwards to [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] and [Mathematical Expression Omitted], but the
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] schedule shifts by more than
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] shifts.(8) The new long-run
equilibrium is at point K*, and the new stationary value of exchange
rate, [Mathematical Expression Omitted], is greater than [e.sub.0],
while the new stationary value of foreign bonds stock, [Mathematical
Expression Omitted], is smaller than [D*.sub.0].(9) As a consequence,
the line connecting the old steady state ([K.sub.0]) and the new steady
state ([K.sub.*]), namely the LL schedule, is always downward sloping.
In addition, the stable arm SS is also downward sloping from Figure 1.
Accordingly, two cases may happen.(10) Figure 2(a) corresponds to the
situation where the LL line is flatter than the stable arm; while Figure
2(b) portrays the situation where the LL line is steeper than the
convergent stable path.
Before we proceed with the analysis, three points should be noted.
First, for expository convenience, in what follows 0+ denotes the
instant after the announcement made by the authorities, and [Tau]- and
[Tau]+ denote the instant before and after policy implementation,
respectively. Second, during the dates between 0+ and [Tau]-, the
government spending remains intact and the point [K.sub.0] should be
treated as the reference point to govern the dynamic adjustment. Third,
since the public become aware that the government spending will increase
from [g.sub.0] to [g.sub.[Tau]] at the moment of [Tau]+, the economy
should move to a point exactly on the stable arm SS at that instant of
time in order to ensure the system to be convergent. Based on this
information, in Figure 2(a), at the instant of anticipated fiscal
announcement, the domestic currency will at once appreciate from
[e.sub.0] to [e.sub.0]+, while the stock of foreign bonds is fixed
because it is a predetermined variable. In consequence, the economy will
jump from the point [K.sub.0] to [K.sub.0+] on impact. Since the point
[K.sub.0+] lies vertically below the point [K.sub.0], from 0+ to [Tau]-,
as arrows indicate, e will continue to decrease and D* stays put at
[D*.sub.0], and the economy will move from [K.sub.0+] to [K.sub.[Tau]].
At time [Tau]+, a fiscal expansion has been enacted, the economy exactly
reaches the point [K.sub.[Tau]] on the convergent stable path SS.
Thereafter, from [Tau]+ onwards, the domestic currency turns to
depreciate and the stock of foreign bonds decumulates as the economy
moves along the SS curve towards its new long-run equilibrium K*.
Evidently, this adjustment pattern of exchange rate is entirely
consistent with Aoki's [1] definition on misadjustment: the
direction of impact response is opposite to that of the long-run
response; the adjustment of exchange rate during dates between 0+ and
[Tau]- moves further away from its new long-run equilibrium value
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
On the other hand, Figure 2(b) corresponds to the case that the LL
line is steeper than the convergent stable path. Following the similar
description as that in Figure 2(a), at the instant 0+, the domestic
currency will immediately depreciate from [e.sub.0] to [e.sub.0+], while
the stock of foreign bonds keeps unchanged. Consequently, the economy
will jump from the point [K.sub.0] to [K.sub.0+] on impact. Since the
point [K.sub.0+] lies vertically above the point [K.sub.0], from 0+ to
[Tau]-, as arrows indicate, e continues to increase and D* remains
intact at [D*.sub.0], and the economy moves from [K.sub.0+] to
[K.sub.[Tau]]. At the moment of fiscal expansion, the economy arrives at
the point [K.sub.[Tau]] on the stable arm SS. Thereafter, from [Tau]+
onwards, e will continue to rise and the stock of foreign bonds
decumulates, the economy thus moves along SS towards the new steady
state. Therefore, in response to anticipated fiscal shock, the exchange
rate undershoots on impact and then continues to increase until its
long-run equilibrium value, [Mathematical Expression Omitted], is
reached.
The above graphical analyses tell us that the anticipated fiscal
expansion, which will ultimately depreciate the domestic currency, can
initially lead to the combination of a balanced current account and a
home currency appreciation (or depreciation). This neutral correlation
between the exchange rate and the current account stands in contrast to
the Kouri's acceleration hypothesis and the observation from
Dornbusch and Fischer [8], Bhandari [4] and Papell [13]. Moreover, even
though the dynamic system is characterized by the saddlepoint stability,
the misadjustment phenomenon will arise if the line connecting the
long-run equilibrium states is flatter than the stable arm. This
conclusion runs in sharp contrast with Aoki's [1] result, which
claims that the misadjustment can occur only when the economy is
characterized by the global instability.
No Wage Indexation
If there is no wage indexation ([Theta] = 0), it is evident from
equation (10) that [a.sub.22] = R* -
{[[Gamma].sub.1]([Alpha][[Theta].sub.1] +
[Theta]3)/[[Gamma].sub.3][[Theta].sub.3] + [Alpha](1 +
[[Gamma].sub.3][[Theta].sub.1])]} [is greater than or less than] 0 while
[a.sub.11][a.sub.22] - [a.sub.12][a.sub.21] [is less than] 0 must be
satisfied for the stability.(11) Due to the fact that whether [a.sub.22]
is positive or negative, the anticipated fiscal expansion will generate
similar adjustment patterns of relevant variables, following Sachs [14]
we only discuss the situation where [a.sub.22] [is less than] 0.
The dynamic behavior of the system can be shown by a phase diagram
like Figure 3. From equation (10), the slopes of loci [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] and [Mathematical Expression Omitted] with [Theta] =
0 are
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
As indicated by the direction of the arrows in Figure 3, the lines SS
and UU represent the stable and unstable paths, respectively.
Apparently, the stable arm SS is always downward sloping and must be
flatter than the [Mathematical Expression Omitted] schedule, while the
unstable arm UU is always upward sloping and must be steeper than the
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] locus.
We now investigate the dynamic adjustment of the economy in which the
government spending is anticipated to expand in the future. In Figures
4(a) and 4(b), the initial equilibrium is at [K.sub.0], where
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] intersects [Mathematical Expression
Omitted]; the initial exchange rate and foreign bonds stock are
[e.sub.0] and [D*.sub.0], respectively. In response to the fiscal shock,
both [Mathematical Expression Omitted] and [Mathematical Expression
Omitted] shift leftwards to [Mathematical Expression Omitted] and
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], but the movement of [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] loci is greater than that of [Mathematical
Expression Omitted].(12) The new stationary equilibrium is at point
[K.sub.*], and the new long-run value of exchange rate, [Mathematical
Expression Omitted], is greater than [e.sub.0], while the new long-run
value of foreign bonds stock, [Mathematical Expression Omitted], is
smaller than [D*.sub.0].(13) Following the same analysis of full wage
indexation, two cases may happen. Figure 4(a) depicts the situation
where the LL line is flatter than the stable arm; while Figure 4(b)
describes the opposite situation where the LL line is steeper than the
convergent stable path.
In Figure 4(a), following the same illustration as that of Figure 2,
at the instant of anticipated fiscal announcement, the domestic currency
will instantaneously appreciate from [e.sub.0] to [e.sub.0+], while the
stock of foreign bonds remains intact because it is a predetermined
variable. As a consequence, the economy will jump from the point
[K.sub.0] to [K.sub.0+] on impact. Since the point [K.sub.0+] lies
vertically below the point [K.sub.0], from 0+ to [Tau]-, as arrows
indicate, e will continue to fall and D* will continue to decrease, the
economy will move from [K.sub.0+] to [K.sub.[Tau]]. At time [Tau]+, a
fiscal expansion has been implemented, the economy arrives at the point
[K.sub.[Tau]] on the convergent stable path SS. Thereafter, from [Tau]+
onwards, the domestic currency turns to depreciate and the stock of
foreign bonds continues to decumulate as the economy moves along the SS
curve towards its new long-run equilibrium [K.sub.*]. Obviously, an
important feature of this adjustment pattern in response to an
anticipated fiscal expansion is that an appreciation of domestic
currency is coupled with a current-account deficit. This runs in sharp
contrast with the acceleration hypothesis proposed by Kouri [12]. In
addition, the evolutional pattern of exchange rate is exactly in
conformity with Aoki's [1] definition on misadjustment.
In Figure 4(b), following the similar description as that in Figure
4(a), at the instant 0+, the domestic currency will immediately
depreciate from [e.sub.0] to [e.sub.0+], while the stock of foreign
bonds remains fixed. Consequently, the economy will jump from the point
[K.sub.0] to [K.sub.0+] on impact. Since the point [K.sub.0+] lies
vertically above the point [K.sub.0], from 0+ to [Tau]-, as arrows
indicate, e continues to increase and D* continues to accumulate with
the current-account surplus, and the economy moves from [K.sub.0+] to
[K.sub.[Tau]]. At time [Tau]+, a fiscal expansion is carried out, the
economy exactly reaches the point [K.sub.[Tau]] on the stable arm SS.
Thereafter, from [Tau]+ onwards, the exchange rate keeps rising and the
stock of foreign bonds turns to decumulate as the economy moves along
the SS curve towards its new long-run equilibrium K*. Apparently, the
adjustment pattern of a current-account surplus accompanying a currency
devaluation prior to the policy implementation is again opposite to the
acceleration hypothesis.
Why do alternative wage indexation rules lead to the sharp difference
in the status of the current account and the behavior of the exchange
rate prior to the implementation of fiscal expansion? This question can
be illuminated by examining the current-account balance (equation (7)
with (4)). Given that the economy is initially in equilibrium, the
fiscal expansion is not as yet carried out and D* is a predetermined
variable, full wage indexation will completely insulate the domestic
output (q) and the terms of trade ([Pi]) from disturbances via
exchange-rate adjustment. As a result, the trade balance (and hence the
current account) is balanced regardless of the response of exchange rate
to an expected fiscal expansion.(14) By contrast, no wage indexation
will lead to a contraction (expansion) of domestic output and an
increase (decrease) in [Pi] as the domestic currency appreciates
(depreciates). As a consequence, the trade account (and hence the
current account) ultimately runs into deficit (surplus) and results in a
decumulation (accumulation) in the stock of foreign bonds.(15)
IV. Concluding Remarks
Based on the Sachs model, this paper has analyzed the evolutional
behavior of exchange rate and current account in response to an
anticipated fiscal expansion under alternative wage indexation schemes.
Two central conclusions emerge from the analysis. First, Kouri's
acceleration hypothesis which defines a current-account surplus
(deficit) in association with a currency appreciation (depreciation)
will not hold as the economy faces an anticipated fiscal disturbance.
With full wage indexation, the balanced current account can associate
with either currency appreciation or currency depreciation prior to the
fiscal expansion. However, with no wage indexation, a current-account
deficit (surplus) will couple with an appreciation (depreciation) of
home currency. Second, the adjustment pattern of exchange rate in
response to an anticipated fiscal expansion may be misadjusting, even if
the system exhibits the saddlepoint stability rather than the global
instability proposed by Aoki.
1. From the following graphical analyses in this paper, we can
understand that an unanticipated fiscal expansion cannot possibly lead
to the situation where the exchange-rate appreciation coincides with a
current-account surplus in the real-wage rigidity case.
2. Aoki [2; 3] uses somewhat complicated models to derive the
misadjusting pattern of exchange rate and of terms of trade.
3. Aoki [1,419] claimed in his footnote 2, "..., the existing
literature does not deal adequately with one basic difference between
the adjustment paths due to anticipated and unanticipated shocks,
because each of the models reported in the literature usually contains
only one unstable eigenvalue and adjustment paths generated by dynamics
with two unstable roots are not considered. In the former situations, no
misadjustment phenomenon can be observed." In his other article,
Aoki [3, 287] also made similar argument in footnote 4. In effect,
however, we will show below that the misadjustment can arise in a model
containing only one unstable eigenvalue.
4. Equations (1) and (2) can be justified by the behavior of firms,
labor, and contract-setting developed by Gray [11] and Fischer [9]. The
detailed derivations of similar equations are provided by Flood and
Marion [10] for an open economy.
5. The procedure to derive equation (10) is as follows. First,
substituting equations (2), (4), (8) and (9) into equations (1), (3) and
(5), we have the following results:
q = [[Alpha][[Gamma].sub.3][[Theta].sub.3](1 - [Theta])e +
[Omega][[Gamma].sub.1]D* + [Omega][[Gamma].sub.2]g]/[Delta],
p = {[[[Gamma].sub.3][[Theta].sub.3] + [Alpha][Theta](1 - [Lambda])(1
+ [[Gamma].sub.3][[Theta].sub.1])]e + [[Gamma].sub.1]D*
[[Gamma].sub.2]g}/[Delta],
R = {{[Alpha][Theta](1 - [Lambda])(1 +
[[Gamma].sub.3][[[Theta].sub.1]) + [[Gamma].sub.3][[Theta].sub.3][1 +
[Alpha][Phi](1 - [Theta])]}e
+ ([[Gamma].sub.1] + [Delta][Delta] + [Omega][Phi][[Gamma].sub.1])D*
+ [[Gamma].sub.2](1 + [Phi][Omega])g}/b[Delta].
Then, as Sachs [14] does, linearizing equation (7) around T = D* = 0,
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] and E = P = 1 initially and
substituting the above equations into the resulting equation and
equation (6), we will obtain equation (10) in the text.
6. The coefficient [a.sub.21] runs in sharp contrast with that of
Sachs [14, 744]. More specifically, under full wage indexation ([Theta]
= 1), [a.sub.21] = 0 will result. In addition, under zero wage
indexation which associates with [Theta] = 0, although the sign of
[a.sub.21] is the same as [b.sub.21] in Sachs' paper, the value of
both coefficients is entirely different.
7. If [S.sub.1][S.sub.2] [is greater than] 0 is assumed, the system
may be characterized by either two stable roots or two unstable roots.
Obviously, the former leads that the number of stable roots is greater
than the number of predetermined variables, and the analysis will
involve the problem of nonuniqueness. The latter implies that the number
of stable roots is less than the number of predetermined variables, and
the perfect foresight equilibrium does not exist. See Burmeister [6] and
Buiter [5] for a detailed discussion.
8. Given that stability condition requires [S.sub.2] [is less than]
0, it is clear from equation (10) with [Theta] = 1 that
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Then, a comparison of the above relationships gives
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
9. At the long-run equilibrium, [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
From equation (10) with [Theta] = 1 and [S.sub.2] [is less than] 0, we
can easily derive the following long-run relationships:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
10. The detailed mathematical derivations for dynamic adjustment are
upon request from the authors.
11. It is clear from equation (10) with [Theta] = 0 that
[a.sub.11][a.sub.22] - [a.sub.12][a.sub.21] =
[[Theta].sub.3][(R*[[Gamma].sub.3] - [[Gamma].sub.1])(1 + [Alpha][Phi])
- [Alpha][Delta]] /b[[Gamma].sub.3][[Theta].sub.3] + [Alpha](1 +
[[Gamma].sub.3][[Theta].sub.1])] [is greater than or less than] 0
as
[(R*[[Gamma].sub.3] - [Gamma].sub.1])(1 + [Alpha][Phi]) -
[Alpha][Delta]] [is greater than or less than] 0.
For ensuring the system to be convergent, [(R*[[Gamma].sub.3] -
[[Gamma].sub.1])(1 + [Alpha][Phi]) - [Alpha][Delta]] [is less than] 0
must hold.
12. From equation (10) with [Theta] = 0, we have
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Following similar procedure of footnote 8, we obtain
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
13. At the long-run equilibrium, [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Given that stability condition requires [(R*[[Gamma].sub.3] -
[[Gamma].sub.1])(1 + [Alpha][Phi]) - [Alpha][Delta]] [is less than] 0,
it is obvious from equation (10) with [Theta] = 0 that
[Mathematical Expression Omitted],
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
14. Substituting equation (4) into equation (7) and recalling q and p
from footnote 5, we have
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Obviously, under full wage indexation ([Theta] = 1), the above
relationship will reduce to
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Since initially the combination of D* and g keeps the current account
in equilibrium (i.e., [Mathematical Expression Omitted]), and g remains
at its initial level prior to the implementation of fiscal expansion,
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] must prevail during the dates between
0+ and [Tau]-.
15. If there is no wage indexation ([Theta] = 0), it is easily
derived from equations (4) and (7) that
[Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Following the same illumination as the case of full wage indexation,
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] is positively related to the
adjustment of e.
References
1. Aoki, Masanao, "Misadjustment to Anticipated Shocks: An
Example of Exchange-Rate Response." Journal of International Money
and Finance, September 1985, 415-20.
2. -----, "Dynamic Adjustment Behaviour to Anticipated Supply
Shocks in a Two-Country Model." Economic Journal, March 1986,
80-100.
3. -----, "Effects of Anticipated Central Bank Actions on
Tobin's Q, Share Prices and Exchange Rate in a Small Open
Economy." European Economic Review, April 1986, 285-304.
4. Bhandari, Jagdeep S., "Intermediate Imports, the Current
Account and Flexible Exchange Rates: A Dynamic General Equilibrium Model." Southern Economic Journal, January 1982, 792-801.
5. Buiter, Willem H., "Saddlepoint Problems in Continuous Time
Rational Expectations Models: A General Method and Some Macroeconomic
Examples." Econometrics, May 1984, 665-80.
6. Burmeister, Edwin, "On Some Conceptual Issues in Rational
Expectations Modeling." Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking,
November 1980, 800-16.
7. Dornbusch, Rudiger, "Expectations and Exchange Rate
Dynamics." Journal of Political Economy, December 1976, 1161-76.
8. ----- and Stanley Fischer, "Exchange Rates and the Current
Account." American Economic Review, December 1980, 960-71.
9. Fischer, Stanley. "Wage Indexation and Macroeconomic
Stability," in Stabilization of the Domestic and International
Economy, edited by Karl Brunner and Allan Meltzer. Amsterdam:
North-Holland Publishing Co., 1977.
10. Flood, Robert P., and Nancy P. Marion, "The Transmission of
Disturbances under Alternative Exchange-Rate Regimes with Optimal
Indexing." Quarterly Journal of Economics, February 1982, 43-66.
11. Gray, Jo Anna, "Wage Indexation: A Macroeconomic
Approach." Journal of Monetary Economics, April 1976, 231-35.
12. Kouri, Pentti J. K. "Balance of Payments and the Foreign
Exchange Market: A Dynamic Partial Equilibrium Model," in Economic
Interdependence and Flexible Exchange Rates, edited by Jagdeep S.
Bhandari and B. Putnum. Cambridge, Mass.: The MIT Press, 1983.
13. Papell, David H., "Anticipated and Unanticipated
Disturbances: The Dynamics of the Exchange Rate and the Current
Account." Journal of International Money and Finance, August 1984,
179-93.
14. Sachs, Jeffrey D., "Wages, Flexible Exchange Rates, and
Macroeconomic Policy." Quarterly Journal of Economics, June 1980,
731-47.