Pensions and Corporate Restructuring in American Industry: A Crisis of Regulation.
Burkhauser, Richard V.
Few economic events are more painful than the collapse of a large
corporation and the subsequent unemployment of its workers. When this is
compounded by the loss of their promised pensions after a lifetime of
service, as was the case for many Studebaker workers in the 1960s, cries
for reform fill the air. This economic calamity was in fact the impetus
for the Employer Retirement Income Security Act of 1974 (ERISA). Yet in
the downsizing of the 1980s it has been argued that ERISA was not an
effective mechanism for protecting workers' pensions.
In this book, Gordon Clark, who is director of the Institute of
Ethics and Public Policy in Industrial Relations at Monash University,
wrestles with fundamental issues of equity and efficiency as they relate
to ERISA and the effectiveness of the Pension Benefit Guaranty
Corporation (PBGC) in protecting the rights of workers to promised
pension benefits. He uses three case studies--Gavalik v. Continental Can
Co.; Wisconsin Steel Company v. International Harvester Corporation, and
PBGC v. LTV Corporation--as evidence that "regulation has lost its
moral force, being now understood by managers and business consultants
alike as just another cost of doing business. This attitude stands in
contrast to the attitudes of unions and their members who look to the
courts and the legal rules . . . . as the embodiment of social right and
wrong". Most economists will have less trouble accepting the
author's first assertion than his second.
In Gavalik the courts found that Continental Can was systematically
dropping workers just prior to vesting. In Wisconsin Steel, the PBGC
accused International Harvester of a sham sale to avoid pension
liability and in PBGC, LTV was accused of illegally declaring bankruptcy
to shift pension liability to the PBGC. The author uses these three
cases to argue that "many other corporations may be deliberately
and secretly circumventing their legal responsibilities".
The author develops standard economic models of rational
decisionmaking to reinforce his claim that corporations cannot be
trusted to do the right thing with respect to their workers. But he
criticizes the work of economists who have used those same models to
explain the behavior of unions, declaring that "I do not intend
justifying here, at least, my opinion that union officials have a more
complex set of motives and reasons for action than corporate
executives". Game theory is used to show that "straightforward
maximizers" (i.e., selfish corporation leaders) will outfox "conditional maximizers" (i.e., socially-minded union
leaders). Evil triumphs!
While the author recognizes that reputation effects are possible, the
deterrent effects of a lost reputation are dismissed. Hence, the author
argues that stricter regulation is not only necessary but that our
regulatory system must be fundamentally redesigned by a Congress willing
to take greater responsibility for the political choices involved in
balancing economic self-interest with social obligation. The author
urges that this should be accomplished by Congress explicitly stating
its desired hierarchical ranking of principles and policies, and federal
regulatory agencies and the courts simply following these clear signals
of Congressional intent.
Such morality plays, complete with happy ending, filled academic
bookshelves in the first part of the century. It is surprising to find
such an asymmetrical view of the behavior of big business and big labor,
as well as such faith in Congress's ability to unambiguously set a
moral basis for reform, from a modern scholar. More to the point, the
author's emphasis on an overarching conflict between business and
labor prevents him from considering another explanation for the legal
structure of the PBGC, that business and labor, when it is in their
interest to do so, act as allies rather than antagonists in the public
policy arena. As Munnell [2] and Ippolito [1] have discussed in the two
best treatments of the PBGC, books uncited by the author, once this
possibility is considered, then what appears to be an attempt by
Congress to shift the risk of pension collapse from workers to
shareholders becomes, in fact, a transfer of this risk and its
underwriting to taxpayers. Whether this transfer makes policy sense is
another matter, but to ignore the possibility that self-interest is not
confined to scheming businessmen, as this book does, makes for extremely
naive policy analysis.
Presumably the author would be doubly disappointed if labor and
management both pursued their private interest above the social good,
and he would call all the more for a national industrial policy to
insure that both management and labor fulfilled their "social
obligations." But compelling individuals to behave in socially
responsible ways they do not perceive as in their own interest has
proven quite difficult. For instance, a much more important and
perfectly legal method that corporations have been using to reduce the
liability of future pension promises is to change the form of the
pension they provide. Since the passage of ERISA, the number of defined
contributions pension plans, which dramatically reduce the risk of
future pension liability for corporations, has increased while the
number of defined benefit plans, which are the primary target of ERISA
regulations, has decreased. Nothing in Clark's reform proposals
address this method of avoiding regulatory costs without pension
mandates.
The author concedes that economic models of rational decisionmaking
are valuable predictors of behavior but considers them flawed as models
of moral behavior. Few economists would quarrel with this proposition,
at least when self-interest is very narrowly defined. But the marvel of
the economic paradigm is its ability to show how much cooperative and
ultimately efficient behavior is possible even when self-interest is
narrowly drawn, as long as market forces are allowed to operate. After
half a century of experience with regulation and regulatory reform,
economists are split on whether regulating markets necessarily leads to
either more efficient or more equitable market outcomes. Policymakers,
in seeking the social good, must recognize both what is and what ought
to be. Most economists who evaluate public policy will find little in
this book to convince them to abandon their microeconomic tools when
they consider the efficiency and income distribution trade-offs that are
at the center of PBGC reform.
References
1. Ippolito, Richard A. The Economics of Pension Insurance. Homewood,
Ill.: Irwin, 1989.
2. Munnell, Alicia H. The Economics of Private Pensions. Washington:
The Brookings Institution, 1982.
Richard V. Burkhauser Syracuse University