Firm-specific advantages, multinational joint ventures, and host country tariff policy.
Purkayastha, D.
I. Introduction
In recent years multinational firms have shown a tendency to
vertically disintegrate the production process into a number of plants
across different countries. These firms have also shown an increasing
willingness to form joint ventures with local firms. For example, some
U.S.-Japanese joint ventures now assemble U.S. and Japanese autoparts in
the U.S. to sell the final products in the North American market. The
phenomenon is especially important in less developed countries (LDCS)
where, in some cases, as much as 80 percent of total foreign capital may
be in the form of joint ventures [9].
The literature on vertically integrated multinationals is
voluminous (see Rugman and Eden [12] for a survey), but very few authors
have explored the implications of vertically disintegrated joint
ventures between an upstream input supplier and a downstream final goods
producer. While Hirshleifer [8] analyzed the transfer price implications
of a vertically integrated industry, Monteverde and Teece [11] were the
first to point out that quasi-vertical integration may be a stable
organizational form when appropriable quasi-rents exist between the
downstream and the upstream firms.(1) Recently, Contractor and Lorange
[4], Beamish [2], and Harrigan [7] have pointed out that quasi-vertical
integration has evolved as an organizational form because both firms
have some firm-specific advantages which make joint ventures mutually
beneficial.(2) In the Japanese market, for example, some U.S. firms tend
to collaborate with local Japanese partners simply because the Japanese
firms have much better knowledge of the local distribution networks
[9].(3)
This paper constructs a model of multinational operation which has
the choice of forming a joint venture with a downstream firm in another
country. I assume that the downstream "local" firm is
interested in establishing an alliance with the multinational because
the multinational has some firm specific advantages. More specifically,
the multinational can produce an input in its upstream plant that is not
available to the local firm. Similarly, the multinational also finds it
advantageous to form an alliance with the local firm because the local
firm has unique entrepreneurial knowledge of local conditions, offers
cheaper inputs and has better ties to the government and the important
buyers. Welfare implications of government tariff policy are explored
and it is shown that under certain circumstances, an import-restricting
tariff may indeed increase the welfare of the domestic consumers.
II. The Model
Assume that a multinational firm has an upstream plant located in
Country 1. This plant produces a technologically complex input X with
the help of skilled labor [L.sup.s] and other inputs not available in
Country 2. With regard to Country 2, the firm now faces two choices:
(a) Produce good [Q.sub.m] in a facility in Country I and export
[Q.sub.m] to Country 2. Country 2 has a high tariff barrier against all
final goods imports.
(b) Produce [Q.sub.h] in a location inside Country 2 and sell it in
Country 2's domestic market. In this case the multinational will
have to export X to Country 2 to produce [Q.sub.h] We assume that X has
a lower tariff than [Q.sub.m].
(c) If the firm chooses option (b), it must also decide whether or
not to engage in a joint venture with a local firm. We assume that the
government does not impose any restrictions on foreign equity holdings.
A crucial assumption of the model is that in all cases, the high
technology intermediate inputs are produced by the multinational in a
location outside Country 2's territory. Clearly, options (a) and
(b) are not mutually exclusive. Assume that [Q.sub.m] and [Q.sub.h] are
closely related on the production side (i.e., [Q.sub.m] stands for
luxury cars and [Q.sub.h] stands for economy cars: both use similar
intermediate inputs), but [Q.sub.m] has a less elastic demand compared
to the demand for [Q.sub.h] in Country 2's domestic market.
In the case of (c), the possibility of a joint venture raises some
conceptual issues about bargaining power within the joint venture. First
of all, the joint venture must resolve the degree of ownership between
the two firms. Existing literature does not shed much light on this
issue. Most authors assume that the ownership decision is made by the
government of the host country which sets limits to maximum ownership
and implicitly assume that this constraint is binding. This need not
necessarily be so. The multinational's decision to form a joint
venture will stem from the costs and benefits of the project. In many
cases the multinationals decide on minority, or 50-50 joint ventures
even if there if no pre-set limit on the degree of ownership [9].(4)
A second, related, question concerns the joint venture's
price-output decisions. The joint venture must decide on the price to
set, the quantity [Q.sub.h] to produce, and determine the transfer price
of the high technology intermediate input X. In a more general model
these variables would be decided in a duopoly game; but for simplicity,
this paper does not follow this route. I assume instead that the
multinational decides the optimal level of joint venture ownership and
the transfer price of the high technology intermediate input, while the
local firm decides the price of final output.
This assumption is probably not too unrealistic because the local
firm can never have effective control over the ownership decision.
Suppose the local firm decides to own a higher share of the joint
venture. Since the upstream multinational controls the transfer price,
it can always manipulate the transfer price to control the accounting
profits of the joint venture. The local firm thus may have higher
nominal ownership, but total profits of the local firm are always
determined by the transfer price set by the upstream firm. The local
firm, however, is likely to have more intimate knowledge of the domestic
market and would be able to more accurately judge the domestic demand
and cost conditions and would be able to set the optimal output
price.(5)
The formal model, therefore, is as follows [1]. Let the demand for
[Q.sub.m] in Country 2's domestic market be
[Q.sub.m] = [P.sup.-[epsilon].sub.m], [epsilon] > 1. (1)
[Q.sub.m] is the quantity demanded of the importable good, [P.sub.m]
the price of [Q.sub.m] and [epsilon] the elasticity of demand.
The demand for [Q.sub.h] in Country 2's domestic market is
[Q.sub.h] = [P.sup.-[eta].sub.h], [eta] > [epsilon] > 1. (2)
[Q.sub.h] is the quantity demanded of the domestic good produced by
the joint venture, [P.sub.h] the price of [Q.sub.h] and [eta] the
elasticity of demand. In Country 1, the high technology intermediate
input X and other primary inputs [L.sup.*] are assumed to be combined in
fixed proportions to produce [Q.sub.m]:
[Q.sub.m] = min{X,[L.sup.*]}. (3)
Similarly, [Q.sub.h] is produced with X and Country 2's primary
input L:
[Q.sub.h] = min{X,L}. (4)
X is assumed to be a function of sector-specific skilled labor
([L.sup.s]) and other factors in Country 1:
X = f([L.sup.s],[multiplied by]). (5)
Let the prices of [L.sup.*] and L be denoted by and [W.sup.*] and W
respectively, W < [W.sup.*]. Let [C.sub.[chi]] be the unit cost of
inputs required in the production of X.
The multinational enjoys certain locational and organizational
advantages if it decides to engage in a joint ienture [15]. If the
multinational decides to produce in Country 2, it not only produces
[Q.sub.h] with cheaper inputs, it can also reduce the cost of production
of [Q.sub.m], through franchising and various other cost saving
techniques.(6) Assume that these country-specific benefits increase as
the multinational increases its ownership in industry [Q.sub.h].
Denoting the multinational ownership of the joint venture by [sigma], 0
[less than or equal to] [sigma] [less than or equal to] 1, the benefit
function accruing to the multinational's production in industry
[Q.sub.m] is defined as [B.sub.m]([sigma]), where
[Mathematical Expressions Omitted]
(6)
The joint venture with the local firm also generates firm-specific
advantages,(7) but these advantages erode as the multinational assumes
progressively more ownership. Denoting these benefits by
[B.sub.h]([sigma])
[Mathematical Expressions Omitted]
(7)
Assume now that the government imposes unit taxes on imports of
intermediate and final goods given by [T.sub.[chi]] and [T.sub.m]
respectively. In view of(1)-(47), the multinational's global profit
function is
[[pi].sub.g] = {[P.sub.m][Q.sub.m] - ([C.sub.[chi]] + [W.sup.*] -
[B.sub.m] + [T.sum.m])[Q.sub.m]} + ([P.sub.[chi]] - [C.sub.[chi]])X +
[sigma]{[P.sub.h][Q.sub.h] - ([P.sub.[chi]] + W +
[T.sub.[chi]])[Q.sub.h] + [B.sub.h]/[sigma]} (8)
where [[pi].sub.g] is the global profit of the multinational and
[P.sub.[chi] is the transfer price of X. The multinational's
problem is to maximize (8) subject to (1) through (5). The first-order
conditions imply
[Q.sub.m] = [{[epsilon]/([epsilon] - 1)}([C.sub.[chi]] + [W.sup.*] -
[B.sub.m] + [T.sub.m])].sup.-[epsilon] (9)
[Mathematical Expressions Omitted]
(10)
[Mathematical Expressions Omitted]
(11) where [[pi].sub.j] is the profit of the joint venture. Notice
that the multinational does not treat [Q.sub.h] as constant. It realizes
that demand for X is a derived demand and uses the derivative property
of Shephard's lemma to derive (10).(8) The local firm has the
following profit function
(1 - [sigma]){[P.sub.h][Q.sub.h] - ([P.sub.[chi]] + W +
[T.sub.[chi]])[Q.sub.h]}. (12)
The local firm maximizes (12) subject to (2). Its first-order
condition is
[Q.sub.h] = [{[eta]/([eta] - 1)}([P.sub.[chi]] + W +
[T.sub.[chi]])].sup.-[eta] (13)
Using (2), (10), (12) and (13) the transfer price [P.sub.[chi]] can
be eliminated to derive the equilibrium values in terms of true costs of
production
[Q.sub.h] = [{[[eta].sup.2]([C.sub.[chi]] + W +
[T.sub.[chi]])}/{([eta] - 1)([eta] + [sigma] - 1)}].sup.-[eta] (14)
[[pi].sub.j] = {1/([eta] - 1)}{[eta]/([eta] -
1)}.sup.-[eta][{[eta]([C.sub.[chi]] + W + [T.sub.[chi]])/([eta] +
[sigma] - 1)}].sup.1-[eta] (15) Given the wage rates, the unit taxes and
the elasticities, the system is completely determined. Note that [sigma]
is now implicitly determined from equation (11). In general [sigma] need
not take an extreme value of 1. The multinational will weigh the
marginal benefits and costs of increasing [sigma] and decide on its
optimal ownership level of the joint venture.
PROPOSITION 1. An increase in multinational ownership of joint
venture increases total profit of the joint venture.
Proof. Differentiating equation (15) we get
d[[pi].sub.j]/d[sigma] = {[eta]/([eta] -
1)}.sup.-[eta][[eta]([C.sub.[chi]] + W +
[T.sub.[chi]])].sup.1-[eta]([eta] + [sigma] - 1).sup.[eta]-2 (16)
which is positive in view of [eta] > 1. Q.E.D.
Proposition 1 is surprising. An intuitive explanation is that if
the multinational increases its ownership of the joint venture, it is
now in its interest to reduce the transfer price [P.sub.[chi]] and it is
easy to show that [[ ]P.sub.[chi]]/[ ][sigma] < 0. Reduction in
transfer price then increases the total profit of the joint venture [1].
III. Host Country Tariff Policy
An interesting implication of the model is that the government may
now use tariff policy to increase Country 2's domestic welfare.
Define welfare as the sum of consumer's surplus and producer's
profits.(9) Assuming that the government makes a lump sum transfer of
all tariff proceeds to domestic consumers, welfare is then
[Mathematical Expressions Omitted]
(17)
Country 2's welfare in the market for [Q.sub.h] is
[Mathematical Expressions Omitted]
(18)
Notice that only domestic retained profit of the joint venture has
entered the welfare calculations.
PROPOSITION 2. An increase in [T.sub.m] - [T.sub.[chi]] will
increase the multinational's ownership of the joint venture.
Proof. Totally differentiating equation (11), using (1) and (2),
and rearranging terms we get(10)
[Mathematical Expressions Omitted]
(19)
In view of (1), (6), (7) and Proposition 1, (19) is positive. Q.E.D.
We can now explore the effect of an increase in [T.sub.m] -
[T.sub.[chi]] on welfare. From (17) and (18) it can be shown that
d([[omega].sub.m] + [[omega].sub.h]])/[dT.sub.m] =
d[[omega].sub.m]]/[dT.sub.m] + {[[eta].sup.2]/([[eta] -
1)}.sup.1-[eta]]([[C.sub.[chi]] + W + [T.sub.[chi]]).sup.1-[eta]([[eta]
+ [sigma] = 1)].sup.[eta]-2(1 - [sigma]d[sigma]/[dT.sub.m]. (20)
The first term may be negative, but from proposition 2, the second
term is always positive. Thus the expression above is positive if the
beneficial effect of further vertical integration outweighs the possible
negative welfare effects in the first market,[[ ][omega].sub.m]/[[
]T.sub.m]. This is likely to happen at a certain range of the
[B.sub.[iota]([sigma]) functions. We have thus shown that a country may
gain by creating tariff barriers for importable final goods. Tariff
barriers now force the multinational to reduce the transfer price, which
tends to increase Country 2's welfare.(11) From (19) and (20) one
can implicity derive an optimal tariff rate for Country 2.
IV. Concluding Comments
The model shows that firm-specific and country-specific advantages
may determine the extent of foreign ownership in a joint venture firm.
This may explain why the same multinational may form joint ventures with
different degrees of ownerships across different countries and over
time. The model also shows the possibility of a beneficial tariff policy
that increases domestic welfare by constructing "tariff-walls"
that encourage the multinationals to increase ownership and reduce the
transfer price. Formation of Customs Unions such as the ones in Europe
and North America may also have the same effect. Since the
multinationals are known to charge a high transfer price, a country may
impose tariff simply to lower the transfer price. The model is
especially relevant for LDCs where the local firms are unable to produce
complex high-technology inputs, but have an excellent knowledge of local
conditions to market the jointly produced commodity.
References
[1.] Bardhan, Pranab K., "Imports, Domestic Production and
Transnational Vertical Integration: A Theoretical Note." Journal of
Political Economy, October 1982, 1020-34. [2.] Beamish, Paul W.,
"Joint Ventures in LDCs: Partner Selection and Performance."
Management International Review, First Quarter 1987, 23-37. [3.]
Brander, James A. and Barbara J. Spencer, "Tariffs and the
Extraction of Foreign Monopoly Rents Under Potential Entry."
Canadian Journal of Economics, August 1981, 371-89. [4.] Contractor,
Farok J. and Peter Lorange, "Competition vs. Cooperation: A
Benefit/Cost Framework for Choosing Between Fully-Owned Investments and
Cooperative Relationships." Management international Review,
Special Issue, 1988, 5-18. [5.] Falvey, Rodney E., and Harold O. Fried,
"National Ownership Requirements and Transfer Pricing."
Journal of Development Economics, December 1986, 249-54. [6.] Grossman,
Gene M., "The Theory of Domestic Content Protection and Content
Preference." The Quarterly Journal of Economics, November 1981,
583-603. [7.] Harrigan, Kathryn R., "Strategic Alliances and
Partner Asymmetries." Managenwnt International Review, Special
Issue, 1988, 53-72. [8.] Hirshleifer, Jack, "On the Economics of
Transfer Pricing." Journal of Business, July 1956, 172-84. [9.]
Korbin, Stephen J., "Trends in Ownerships of American Manufacturing
Subsidiaries in Developing Countries: An Inter-Industry Analysis."
Management International Review, Special Issue, 1988. [10.] McConnell,
John J. and Timothy J. Nantell, "Corporate Combinations and Common
Stock Returns: The Case of Joint Ventures." Journal of Finance,
June 1985, 519-36. [11.] Monteverde, Kirk and David J. Teece.
"Appropriable Rents and Quasi-Vertical Integration." Journal
of Law and Economics, October, 1982, 321-28. [12.] Rugman, Alan M. and
Lorraine Eden, eds. Multinationals and Transfer Pricing. New York: St.
Martin's Press, 1985. [13.] Silva-Echenique, Julio,
"Quasi-Vertical Integration and Rate-of-Return Regulation."
Canadian Journal of Economics. November 1989, 852-66. [14.] Svejnar, Jan
and Stephen Smith, The Economics of Joint Ventures in Less Developed
Countries." The Quarterly Journal of Economics, February 1984,
149-67. [15.] Tabeta, Naoki. "A Model of Quasi-Vertical Integration
in the Japanese Automobile Industry." Working Paper, Takachiho
Commercial College, Tokyo, Japan, June 1991.
(*) I would like to thank an anonymous referee for extremely useful
comments on an earlier version of the paper. (1.) Silva-Echenique [13]
discusses the issues related to rate of return regulation for upstream
and downstream firms, but assumes a predetermined level of indigenous
ownership. (2.) Tabeta [15] uses a quasi-vertical model to explain the
Japanese subcontracting system in the auto industry. Svejnar and Smith
[14] use a Nash bargaining framework to explain joint ventures but
ignore the issue of firm specific costs and benefits. (3.) McConnell and
Nantell [10] show that for a sample of 210 firms listed in New York and
American Stock Exchanges, firms with joint ventures had significant
increases in their share values. (4.) In some cases, of course,
government-stipulated maximum-ownership limits or the domestic content
laws may be a binding constraint [6; 5]. Ownership or content laws can
be treated as a special case of our model. (5.) Svejnar and Smith [14]
assume that decisions are made jointly; but their approach does not shed
light on the determinants of bargaining power. I assume that the
bargaining power is based on firm-specific advantages. Note that in this
model, the domestic firm has no other means of obtaining X except from
the foreign firm. Since the domestic firm can not enter the market
without foreign collaboration, it has considerably less bargaining
power. Firm-specific advantages also enable the local firm to retain
some of its profits. If firm-specific advantages do not exist for the
local firm, the upstream firm will wholly own the downstream firm and
appropriate all profits [13; 15]. (6.) These benefits reduce
"transaction costs" as well as production costs in Country 1.
Lower wage, for example, may be a reason why a multinational may want to
operate in an LDC [4]. (7.) In a survey of multinational executives,
Beamish [2] found that the local partner's knowledge of local
business, economy, politics and customs were the most significant
perceived benefits of collaboration. (8.) This has been pointed out by
Bardhan [1]. (9.) Bardhan [1] uses the same measure for a licensed firm.
(10.) Equations (19) and (20) are derived by indexing [T.sub.m] to zero.
We assume that [[ ]B.sub.m]/[ ][sigma] is sufficiently large.