Income and Inequality: The Role of the Service Sector in the Changing Distribution of Income.
Whaples, Robert
For about two decades now, income in the United States has slowly
become less equally distributed. The extent and causes of this trend
have been hotly debated among scholars, in the press, and, recently, on
the campaign stump. At the December, 1992 Economic Summit, the changing
income distribution was given almost as much attention as economic
growth and health care spending. Leading Clinton administration officials, such as Secretary of Labor Robert Reich, are weighing
policies designed to reverse the trend.
Crafting successful policies requires a basic understanding of the
underlying causes of this complex phenomenon. The leading explanations
focus on shifts in the demand for skilled and unskilled labor in
conjunction with changing technology, changing product demand and the
globalization of the economy. There are important subplots about
demographic shifts (for example, increases in female labor force
participation and the percent of single-mother headed households) and
measurement errors. Less noticed has been the widening disparity in the
distribution of income across different sized communities, as, for
example, higher-paying producer services have tended to locate in
metropolitan areas, while lower-paying consumer services have been more
evenly distributed across space.
These issues are a Gordian knot. It is virtually impossible to
remove one thread for examination, since each is securely fastened to
the others. Alexander's sword won't suffice, a surgeon's
scalpel is required to carefully unravel the interacting causes.
Cathy Kassab's study is an effort to focus on one strand in
this knot. Her study, which grew out of a dissertation completed at
Pennsylvania State University, examines the impact of changing levels of
employment in the service and manufacturing sectors. It considers how
growth in the service sector affects the community income level and its
distribution, how changes in the industrial mix of communities affect
the distribution of income across places, and how the impact of the
service sector on income compares with that of manufacturing.
The bulk of the empirical work examines a sample of communities in
the Mid-atlantic region. This region was chosen because the transition
from a manufacturing-based to a service-based economy occurred there
with great clarity during the 1970s, and because the Mid-Atlantic also
has a relatively large rural population. Data from the United States
Census of Population for 1970 and 1980 are used to construct information
on aggregate family income and its distribution for the 642 communities.
Data on the types of firms and number of employees present in localities
are from Dun and Bradstreet's Marketing Identifiers file.
The data are used in a series of descriptive tables and
regressions. The aim is to determine the forces behind changes in
aggregate income and its distribution between 1969 and 1978.
Unfortunately, one must be wary of the coefficients from the
regressions, and, especially, Kassab's interpretations of them.
Because income inequality is such a complex problem almost every
simplifying assumption made by Kassab obscures one of the important
issues.
She assumes that each community is a spatial unit in which
residents are functionally interdependent, yet she provides no evidence
that her two data sets are properly linked, that individuals work and
live in the same community. To simplify, she analyzes only the
distribution of income among families, ignoring income earned by
"unrelated individuals." But, as her data show, there was a
tremendous increase in the proportion of unrelated individuals over this
period, and the distribution of this group's income shifted
dramatically. Thus, the identities of those in families have also
changed, and the groups she compares are not consistent over time. The
Dun and Bradstreet data are essential for getting information on
employment by sector, but they undercount smaller firms, and lead her to
ignore the roles of employment in agriculture, construction, mining,
government, and the nonprofit sector. Finally, she does not control for
educational levels in any of her analysis. While the community-based
approach has some strengths, its major weakness is that it loses sight
of the individual.
A second empirical chapter uses County Business Pattern employment
data and Bureau of Economic Analysis income and population data for all
the counties in the United States. The dependent variable is change in
wage and salary disbursements between 1979 and 1988. This income measure
is much less complete than is needed.
Using the regressions, Kassab argues that, while growth in the
low-wage services is associated with a decrease in aggregate income
among centrally located places, it boosts income in places remote from
the interstate highway system. "These findings support statements
made in the previous chapter regarding the positive impact of the
low-wage service sector on the nonmetropolitan economy, and the fact
that growth in this sector represents a potential source of economic
development." However, this reasoning is questionable, since the
regressions cannot determine whether these changes are causes or
effects. Kassab implies that supply creates its own demand, that the
growth in the low wage consumer service sector was exogenous to the
community and boosted its income, when it was probably endogenous,
reflecting increased incomes elsewhere in the community. While the
purpose of this research is to provide input into policy on local
economic development, the argument that isolated rural communities can
use tactics such as retail development to push growth, flies in the face
of a plethora of other studies and of common sense. At most this is a
beggar thy neighbor strategy, with a low local income multiplier.
There are some important findings in the book, especially the
regressions analyzing community-level changes in the female labor force
participation rate. While Kassab's study generally bolsters
mainstream policy implications, such as increased investment in
education, it is not the scalpel that was required to unravel the knotty problems surrounding service sector growth, economic development, and
income inequality.