Shirking or stochastic productivity in major league baseball: reply.
Krautmann, Anthony C.
In my earlier paper in this Journal [9], I attempted to illustrate
how the stochastic nature of an input's productivity might help
explain the popular perception that Major League Baseball players shirk after receiving a longterm contract. What always made this argument hard
for me to swallow is that a player's reputation for being such an
unduly contributor would hardly enhance his ability to sign on with
another team after the contract expired. At the least, such a position
implies a very large discount rate on the part of the player.
What this debate has ignored is the tremendous variability of
players' productivity. Table I, replicated below, illustrates the
variation in mean (career) slugging averages (SA) of a sample of present
and future Hall of Famers [9, 963]. Note the sizable variation among
both players' mean performances and standard errors, as well as the
considerable variation across time of a particular player's
performance.
Table I. Variability of Players' Performances
Name Career SA Std. Err. Minimum SA Maximum SA
Tony Perez .460 .051 .372 .589
Carlton Fisk .473 .056 .361 .551
Mickey Mantle .554 .089 .398 .705
Reggie Jackson .486 .068 .340 .608
Rod Carew .436 .059 .347 .570
Pete Rose .407 .058 .386 .512
Babe Ruth .691 .095 .537 .847
If all players' productivity came from the same population,
then one could test the disincentive effect of longterm contracts by
aggregating together all players and seeing if there is a significant
dropoff from the (common) mean in the period following the new contract.
This is, in essence, the methodology proposed by Professor Scoggins in
the preceding comment [14].
Even a cursory examination, however, of Table One would lead one to
seriously question the reality of the author's assumption of
identical distributions-simply said, ability is too heterogeneous to
tolerate aggregating all players together. What I proposed was that we
treat each player separately, basing our analysis on individual-specific
distributions. Admittedly, one cost of such an approach is making
inferences on small samples, sometimes as low as 4 or 5 observations on
a player's past performances. For this reason I reported the number
of occurrences in which a player's performance fell off in the
subsequent period, both in a statistical sense (which is more sensitive
to sample size) as well as in an nonparametric sense.(1) In the first
case, I found only 2 of 110 players having statistically below-average
performances, a proportion which is not significantly different from
zero. Further, under the null hypothesis of no shirking we would expect
about 50 percent of the players to fall below (and 50 percent to be
above) their means in the subsequent period. In fact, I found only 36
percent had below-average performances! In neither case would one want
to conclude that the evidence favors the shirking hypothesis.
Professor Scoggins [14] suggests that measuring performance with
the player's slugging average would not properly measure shirking
for it ignores the days spent on the disabled list. As most "sports
economists" know, the debate about which statistic (or index) best
measures productivity is far from resolved. Some analysts prefer career
batting average [10], Run Production Average [6], a weighted average of
many statistics [3; 8], runs scored [7; 13; 17], but the most common
continues to be slugging average [1; 2; 4; 5; 15; 16; 17]. One item that
is generally agreed upon, however, is that all of these statistics do an
adequate job of measuring the contribution of the player to team
winning-the correlation between these measures and the team winning
percentage typically ranges between 0.8 and 0.95.
Professor Scoggins [14] has suggested a better measure of
productivity, total bases, which he feels will more closely reflect the
disincentive effect associated with the propensity to going on the
disabled list following a longterm contract [11; 12]. Aggregating
together all players, the author regresses total bases (BASES) against a
dummy variable (LT) equal to one if the player signed a longterm
contract in the previous period.2 Finding a significantly negative
coefficient on LT leads him to reject the hypothesis that shirking does
not occur, suggesting that my results are quite sensitive to the
performance measure used.
To examine whether using a different performance measure would lead
me to starkly different conclusions, I recalculated my model using total
bases instead of slugging average. Because of the heterogeneity issue
discussed above, I continue to base inferences on player-specific
distributions. Under the null hypothesis of no shirking, we would expect
no more than 5 percent of the sample to have realizations of performance
lying below the lower limit of the forecast interval due to purely
stochastic reasons. Using BASES as the productivity measure I found 6
such outliers, or 5.4 percent of the sample. Further, if the series is
stationary, we would expect about 50 percent of the players to have
realizations below their career average in any period, including the
subsequent one. Of the 110 players, 40 percent experienced below-average
realizations, about the same proportion as in the original study. As
before, I hardly believe the evidence favors the shirking hypothesis.
I suspect the seemingly conflicting results obtained by Scoggins
are due to his assumption that players' performances are derived
from the same population. As both a scientist and a fan of the game, I
have a very hard time accepting such an assumption.
References
[1.] Bruggink, Thomas H. and David R. Rose, Jr., "Financial
Restraint in the Free Agent Labor Market for Major League Baseball-
Players Look at Strike Three." Southern Economic Journal, April
1990, 1029-43. [2.] Cassing, James H. and Richard W. Douglas,
"Implications of the Auction Mechanism in Baseball's Free
Agency Draft." Southern Economic Journal, July 1980, 110-20. [3.]
Chelius, James R. and James B. Dworkin, "Free Agency and Salary
Determination in Baseball." Labor Law Journal, August 1982, 539-48.
[4.] Cymrot. Donald J., "Migration Trends and Earnings of Free
Agents in Major League Baseball: 1976-1979." Economic Inquiry,
October 1983. 545-56. [5.] _____ and James A. Dunlevy, "Are Free
Agents Perspicacious Peregrinators?" The Review of Economics and
Statistics, February 1987, 50-58. [6.] Dworkin, James B.,
"Collective Bargaining in Baseball: Key Current Issues." Labor
Law Journal, August 1988,480-86. [7.] Hill, James R. and William E.
Spellman, "Professional Baseball: The Reserve Clause and Salary
Structure." Industrial Relations, Winter 1983, 1-19. [8.] James,
William. "Introduction for Old Readers," in The Bill James Baseball Abstract. New York. Ballentine Books,1986. [9.] Krautmann,
Anthony C., "Shirking or Stochastic Productivity in Major League
Baseball?" Southern Economic Journal, April 1990, 961-68. [10.]
Krohn, Gregory A., "Measuring the Experience-Productivity
Relationship: The Case of Major League Baseball." Journal of
Business and Economic Statistics, October 1983. 273-79. [11.] Lehn,
Kenneth M., "Property Rights, Risk Sharing, and Player Disability
in Major League Baseball." Journal of Law and Economics, October
1982, 341-66. [12.] _____, "Information Asymmetries in
Baseball's Free Agent Market." Economic Inquiry, January 1984,
37-44. [13.] Medoff, Marshall H., "On Monopsonistic Exploitation in
Professional Baseball." Quarterly Review of Economics and
Statistics. Summer 1976, 113-2 1. [14.] Scoggins, John F.,
"Shirking or Stochastic Productivity in Major League Baseball:
Comment." Southern Economic Journal, July 1993. [15.] Scully,
Gerald W., "Pay and Performance in Major League Baseball."
American Economic Review, December 1974,915-30. [16.] _____. The
Business of Major League Baseball, Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
1989. [17.] Sommers, Paul M. and Noel Quinton, "Pay and Performance
in Major League Baseball: The Case of the First Family of Free
Agents." Journal of Human Resources, 1982, 426-35.
(1.) That is, just counting the number of occurrences in which the
subsequent performance fell below the mean. (2.) Interpreting the
author's model is difficult since inclusion into the sample
requires that the player just signed a longterm contract, meaning every
observation MUST have a I assigned to LT. Somehow another observation On
each player was included; unfortunately, the author is cryptic about
this aspect of his sample.