Increasing Returns and Efficiency.
Yoon, Yong J.
"Increasing returns" is an active area of research in
economics now. But economists use "increasing returns" in at
least three different ways. The most traditional concept of increasing
returns comes from Adam Smith, Marshall, and Allyn Young (see Buchanan
and Yoon). The idea is elegantly expressed by the Smithean proposition
that "the division of labor is limited by the extent of the
market." On the other hand, Brian Arthur and others |1; 3~
understand increasing returns as positive feedback of technology in
economic dynamics.
The book is about neither of the two. This monograph is a formal
analysis of natural monopoly, another concept of long history, in which
the firm produces by falling average cost.
There is an extensive literature on partial equilibrium analysis of
natural monopoly, but few works have been done on general equilibrium analysis. The economy consists of two sectors: a private sector with
competitive firms with decreasing (or constant) returns and a public
sector consisting of regulated firms producing with increasing returns.
The general equilibrium analysis of a competitive market introduced
by Walras excludes the possibility of increasing returns. The
Arrow-Debreu theory of general equilibrium exclude increasing returns in
production, externalities, and entry of new firms. Thus the task is not
a straightforward extension of Arrow-Debreu general equilibrium. The
tradition of Debreu's theory of value is a topological approach.
The "differential" approach taken in this book is more useful
for the analysis of non-convex production sets.
The author discusses the origin of ideas and controversies on
increasing returns and marginal cost pricing in the introductory
chapter. The falling average cost proposed a dilemma since the
production of each additional unit will cost less and increase the
profit. This is incompatible with competitive market. Marshall
introduced the internal and external economies of the firm to overcome
this difficulty.
The debate whether increasing returns are compatible with competitive
equilibrium sort of petered out because monopolistic competition can
handle both increasing and decreasing returns conditions of production.
The necessity to sell the output as a monopolist may determine the price
rather than rising marginal cost determining the price.
After the turn of the century, Pigou, Lerner, Lange, and Hotelling all advocated marginal cost principles as a necessary condition for an
efficient allocation of resources. However, Maurice Allais was against
Hotelling's proposal because firms will have no incentives for cost
minimization in the absence of budget restriction.
The author defines marginal cost pricing equilibrium in Chapter 3.
Marginal cost pricing will not recover the cost under such technology
conditions, thus the deficit has to be financed somehow. This requires a
rule for distribution of incomes, which is a new feature that does not
appear in Arrow-Debreu theory of general equilibrium. Having defined the
concept of equilibrium, the book continues, in the tradition of general
equilibrium theory, to prove the existence and the efficiency of the
"equilibrium." Assumptions are made so that a version of
Kakutani fixed point theorem applies.
Chapters 2 and 3 provide a foundation for marginal cost pricing for
non-convex economies by introducing income map. Marginal cost pricing
equilibrium is a natural extension to non-convex economies of the
competitive equilibrium.
In general, the problem of efficient allocation of resources is
difficult to solve when production set is non-convex. Arrow and Hurwicz
pointed out a pathological case of non-convex economy: Efficiency
(Pareto optimal allocation) does not always require cost minimization.
The example indicates that organization (i.e., planning) matters for the
economy. Such a problem does not appear in convex economies.
The author considers the decentralized organization by which
non-convex firms can be run. This research strategy seems to reflect the
spirit of the time. As Hayek warned, and as the fall of socialism in
this century has shown, it is not possible to achieve efficient
allocations through central planning. The firms have no incentive to
reveal the relevant information to the planning board.
Question: Does the arrangement lead to an efficient resource
allocation for the economy?
The two-part tariffs have advantage over Hotelling's lump-sum
income taxation. If the taxes are presented as fixed fees that give
agents the option to buy the goods at their marginal costs, then the
taxes become more acceptable. Two-part tariffs are particularly
appropriate for public utilities (telephony, electricity, water, etc.).
The question is sharpened now.
Question: Can an efficient allocation be supported by a two-part
tariff?
The author examines the compatibility of two-part tariffs with first
best optimality. He assumes that the fixed charges are to cover the
deficit of the whole public sector. I think this assumption is too
restrictive. More appropriate assumption would be to require each
regulated firm to cover its deficit (earmarked). The example by
Guesnerie and Quinzii is instructive for finding conditions under which
a Pareto optimum can be decentralized by a two-part tariff. A sufficient
condition is that the surplus derived from buying each good at the
equilibrium price must be larger than the fixed cost. This is what the
author calls the "Surplus condition." This justifies the
relevance of my suggestion above that requires each regulated firm to
finance its own deficit.
Production and exchange normally generate a surplus of welfare. If an
allocation is such that a subgroup of agents using only their own
resources can obtain better allocation for each of them, then the
allocation cannot be the outcome of voluntary production and exchange.
The allocation fails to be in the core.
Every competitive equilibrium of a convex economy is in the core. If
one sector of the economy produces by increasing returns, it seems that
a grand coalition would exploit the potential increasing returns most
effectively. The results in the book show that this intuition needs to
be refined. This will depend on the way of financing the deficit created
by marginal cost pricing, because some agents may not agree with the
allocation determined by a given income map. Chapter 6 discusses the
problem of finding acceptable ways of financing the deficit by a
standard cooperative game theory.
The formal theory in this book does not discuss other issues of great
concern to economists, such as incentive problems and information and
knowledge in the market mechanism as emphasized by Hayek.
References
1. Arthur, Brian. "Competing Technologies, Increasing Returns,
and Lock-in by Historical Events." The Economic Journal, 1989.
2. Buchanan, James and Y. Yoon. The Return of Increasing Returns. Ann
Arbor, Michigan: University of Michigan Press, 1993, forthcoming.
3. Waldrop, M. Complexity. New York: Simon & Schuster, 1992.