Virtual prices and a general theory of the owner operated firm.
Eakin, B. Kelly
I. Introduction
Theories of entrepreneurial behavior for owner operated firms have
a long history in economics. These models treat the owner operator as
both a producer and consumer of goods. Production and consumption
choices result from utility maximization. A preponderance of the work
performed in this area has addressed two theoretical issues, the
consistency of utility and profit maximization and comparative static
behavior of the entrepreneur.
Scitovszky's seminal paper [29] demonstrates that under
certain circumstances the entrepreneur may trade-off income for leisure
giving rise to the possibility of income effects on production and
inconsistency of utility and profit maximization. Building on
Scitovszky's work, Graaff [14], Clower [6], Auster and Silver [3],
and Lapan and Brown [18], analyze the comparative static behavior of the
utility-maximizing owner operator and how this differs from the
traditional neo-classical profit-maximizing firm. Emphasis is on the
possibility of income effects on production and how they my result in
seemingly uneconomic behavior. A shortcoming of this literature is the
focus on special cases based on strong restrictions on technology
(constant returns to scale) and the market for the entrepreneurial input
(no such market exists). As of yet, a general analysis of the
comparative static behavior of the entrepreneur has not been undertaken.
Scitovszky's work also initiated a vigorous debate concerning
the consistency of utility and profit maximization for owner operated
firms. This debate centers on two principal questions. Does utility
maximization imply profit maximization? If not, can a utility-maximizing
owner operated firm survive through time? Piron [25], Olsen [23; 24],
and Hannon [15] conclude that in competitive long-run equilibrium
utility-maximizing entrepreneurs necessarily maximize profit and must do
so to remain viable. Ladd [17], Auster and Silver [3], Feinberg, [8; 9;
10], and Schlesinger [28] conclude that utility and profit maximization
may diverge. Moreover, these writers maintain that non-profit-maximizing
owner operated firms can survive through time. More recently, Formby and
Millner [11] argue that utility and profit maximization necessarily
converge for the marginal firm only.
The questions raised concerning the consistency of utility and
profit maximization have yet to be resolved. Different conclusions have
been deduced from a diversity of assumptions concerning markets for
commodities and inputs, technology, preferences, and measurement of
profit. What remains to settle this debate is a general framework of
entrepreneurial behavior that is capable of incorporating the variety of
assumptions present in the literature and yielding theoretically
consistent behavioral measure of profit.
In this paper, we present a general model of entrepreneurial
behavior for owner operated firms based on the notion of virtual prices.
Our model has three specific advantages: (1) it has existing theories as
special cases which result from restrictions on the entrepreneur's
choice set, preferences, and/or technology; (2) it provides framework
for conducting a general analysis of the comparative static behavior of
the owner operator and (3) it resolves the debate concerning the
consistency of utility and profit maximization.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section II
presents the perfect markets model of entrepreneurial behavior for owner
operated firms. We show that utility maximization implies profit
maximization when perfect markets exist for all goods and inputs.
Section III formulates the imperfect markets model based on the notion
of virtual prices and demonstrates that perfect markets are a special
case of this more general analytical framework. Section IV examines the
comparative static behavior of the entrepreneur. We conclude that
utility and profit-maximizing firm behavior are indistinguishable in an
environment of perfect markets; however, the presence of market
imperfections gives rise to the possibility of income effects on
production and ill-behaved substitution effects. Section V makes the
important distinction between economic profit, observable profit and
accounting profit. A measure of economic profit, incorporating virtual
prices, is derived from our general framework and employed to analyze
the consistency of utility and profit maximization and firm viability.
Section VI argues that non-cost minimizing owner operator behavior
results from market failures rather than X-inefficiency. Section VII
summarizes.
II. The Perfect Markets Model
The decision making unit of interest is the entrepreneur. The
entrepreneur is defined as a single individual who owns and controls a
firm where "control" implies ultimate decision making
authority. By assumption, all goods and inputs that pertain to the
entrepreneur under investigation are traded on perfect markets. A
perfect market exists when a good or input is exchanged on a competitive
market and constitutes a perfect substitute for a good or input supplied
and/or demanded by the entrepreneur. The assumption of perfect markets
places the lower bound of restrictions on the entrepreneur's choice
set and implies that market prices reflect true opportunity costs and
benefits in the decision making process.
The entrepreneur wishes to maximize a twice continuously
differentiable, monotonic, quasi-concave utility function (1)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] where [X.sub.1], . . . ,[X.sub.n] are
commodities and [Y.sub.1], . . . ,[Y.sub.m] are inputs. The set of
arguments [X..sub.1], . . . ,[X.sub.n], [Y.sub.1], . . . ,[Y.sub.m] are
goods where a good is defined broadly as any object that is a direct
source of utility. We permit the entrepreneur to experience utility
directly from consumption of inputs that can alternatively be employed
to produce commodities. The most prominent example of such an input is
the entrepreneur's time input. Henceforth, the consumption of the
time input will be called leisure and designed [Y.sub.m].
The entrepreneur has at his disposal an initial endowment of
resources [Mathematical Expression Omitted], called self-owned inputs,
and given technology. Self-owned inputs must satisfy the constraint (2)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] where [Mathematical Expression
Omitted], and [Y.sub.i] are the initial endowment, factor supply, and
consumption of the jth input, respectively. Production technology is
given by (3) [Mathematical Expressions Omitted] where F is a twice
continuously differentiable quasi-concave function, [Q.sub.1], . . .
,[Q.sub.n] are outputs, [V.sub.1], . . . ,[V.sub.m-1] are typical
production inputs and [V.sub.m] is the entrepreneurial input.
The general form of the entrepreneur's budget constraint is
(4) [Mathematical Expression Omitted] where [P.sub.i] is the ith
commodity price and [W.sub.j] is the jth input price. By assumption of
perfect markets, all prices are given parametrically. The budget 8
constraint indicates that total money outlays must equal total receipts
and allows for net purchases and sales of commodities and inputs.
Constraint (4) is not independent of constraint (2) since
self-owned inputs can be transformed into commodities by consuming less
and employing more of these inputs. Substituting (2) into (4) and
rearranging yields the single constraint (5) [Mathematical Expression
Omitted] where [Mathematical Expression Omitted]. The left hand side
gives total expenditures, both explicit and implicit, on all commodities
an inputs consumed whereas the right hand side represents a modified
version of full-income [5]. The entrepreneur's full-income is
obtained from two sources: the value of his initial endowment of
resources (I) and observable profit. By definition, observable profit is
the difference between total revenue and total opportunity cost of the
firm's operations measured in terms of observable market prices.
When perfect markets exist for all commodities and inputs, observable
profit and economic profit coincide. In this case, obtaining a proper
measure of economic profit is a straightforward and unambiguous
exercise.
The problem of the entrepreneur is to maximize utility function (1)
subject to full-income constraint (5) and technology (3). Assuming
interior solutions, the first order necessary conditions for a
constrained maximum are (6a) [Mathematical Expression Omitted] (6b)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (6c) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
(6d) [Mathematical Expression Omitted] along with the budget and
technology constraints, where [Lambda] and [Mu] are the Lagrangian
multipliers attached to constraints (5) and (3), respectively. The
Lagrangian multiplier [Lambda] gives the marginal utility of
full-income. Given the assumed properties of the utility and production
functions, the second-order conditions for a maximum are satisfied. The
first order conditions can then be expressed as a set of implicit
utility-maximizing demand and supply functions for goods, inputs, and
outputs. By analyzing these first-order conditions, the economic
behavior of the utility-maximizing entrepreneur operating in an
environment of perfect markets can be deduced.
To find the entrepreneur's utility-maximizing choices, the
system of equations given by the first-order conditions can be
decomposed into two sets and solved recursively. The first set of
equations to be solved represents the production side of the model and
is given by (6c), (6d), and (3). The solution yields optimal values for
inputs and outputs of the form (7a) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
(7b) [Mathematical Expression Omitted] The second set of equations
represents the consumption side of the model and is given by (6a), (6b),
and (5). Substituting solutions (7) into budget constraint (5) and
solving the consumption equations yields optimal values for goods of the
form (8a) [Mathematical Expression Omitted] (8b) [Mathematical
Expression Omitted]
Two important conclusions emerge from this model. In a world of
perfect markets where a single entrepreneur can be identified for each
firm, utility maximization implies profit maximization. The intuition is
as follows. To maximize utility the entrepreneur must necessarily
maximize full-income. This is accomplished by choosing those quantities
of inputs and outputs that maximize observable profit. Maximization of
observable profit results in maximization of economic profit since the
two are identical when markets exist and function smoothly. This is a
generalization and rigorous affirmation of the conclusion of Feinberg
[8] and provides the foundation for a more general analysis of the
consistency of utility and profit maximization.
Since profit maximization is a necessary condition for utility
maximization, the utility-maximizing entrepreneur will make the same
input and output choices as the profit-maximizing entrepreneur. However,
given the nature of the budget constraint the behavior of the
entrepreneur as consumer will differ somewhat from the traditional case.
This assertion is demonstrated formally in section IV of this paper.(1)
III. The Imperfect Markets Model
The assumption of perfect markets is clearly very stringent. For
certain types of owner-controlled firms the entrepreneurial input may be
heterogeneous or perform a firm specific function and therefore a
perfect market will not exist for this factor. Alternatively, the
entrepreneur may derive utility from nonpecuniary goods which must be
obtained within the firm since markets do not exist for these goods.
Several additional examples of imperfect markets can be cited.
The existence of one or more imperfect markets can be interpreted
as placing additional restrictions on the entrepreneur's production
and consumption choices relative to an environment of perfect markets.
In analyzing the behavior of the entrepreneur in these instances, it is
necessary to incorporate these added constraints into the perfect
markets model. These market environment constraints make explicit the
nature of markets for goods and inputs. That is, if perfect markets
exist for all goods and inputs so that they can be freely traded, then
the market environment constraints are not binding and the results are
the same as those in the perfect markets model. Alternatively, if one or
more imperfect markets prevail, then the pertinent market environment
constraints might be binding. If such a constraint is binding, the good
or input to which it relates cannot be freely exchanged. This places
additional restrictions on the entrepreneur's feasible choice set
resulting in a divergence between virtual and market prices. Since
virtual prices reflect opportunity costs and benefits that are relevant
when making utility-maximizing choices, the entrepreneur will respond
directly to virtual prices rather than market prices.(2)
The general expressions for the market environment constraints for
the ith commodity and jth input are (9a) [Mathematical Expression
Omitted] (9b) [Mathematical Expression Omitted] where [G.sub.j] and
[R.sub.j] are market restriction parameters and all other variables have
been defined previously. To make explicit the assumption about the
nature of the market for the ith commodity and jth input, it is
necessary to specify an equality or inequality constraint and the
magnitude of restriction parameters. If either (9a) or (9b) are binding,
then inclusion in the constrained utility maximization problem will
influence the entrepreneur's effective choice set and consequently
his behavior relative to the perfect markets case.
Models of the owner operated firm typically assume a market
imperfection for a good or input. The nature of this imperfection varies
among models. For example, Graaff [14] suggest that the entrepreneur
possesses an extreme form of firm-specific human capital so that his
services can be neither acquired from outside the firm nor provided to
other firms. Olsen [23; 24], Feinberg [8], and others [11; 15; 28] cite
monitoring costs, shirking, preferences for self-employment, nepotism,
and discrimination as sources of market imperfections. All of these
assumptions can be translated into market environment constraints of the
form (9) and the implications of these market imperfections on
entrepreneurial choice can then be readily deduced.
The problem of entrepreneur is (10a) max U ([X.sub.1], . . .
,[X.sub.n]; [Y.sub.1], . . . ,[Y.sub.m]) subject to(3) (10b)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (10c) F([Q.sub.1], . . . , [Q.sub.n];
[V.sub.1], . . . , [V.sub.m]) = 0 (10d) [Q.sub.i] - [X.sub.i] =
[G.sub.i] i = 1, . . . , n (10e) [V.sub.] + [Y.sub.j] - [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] = [R.sub.j] j = 1, . . . , m. The Lagrangian
function for this problem is (11) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where [Lambda], [Mu], [[Sigma].sub.i], and [[Phi].sub.j] are Lagrangian
multipliers. For generality, the constrained utility maximization
problem of the entrepreneur is written in a form that allows for the
possibility of a binding market environment constraint for any commodity
or input. If such a constraint is not binding, it merely vanishes.
Assuming interior solutions, the first-order conditions can be expressed
as (12a) [Mathematical Expression Omitted] (12b) [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] (12c) [Mathematical Expression Omitted] (12d)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] along with constraints (10b) through
(10e).
The parenthetic expressions in first-order equations (12) suggest
the notion of a utility-maximizing price that may diverge from the
observable market price. This idea can be formalized by employing the
construct of a virtual price. The notion of virtual prices was first
introduced by Rothbarth [27] and subsequently extended by Graaff [13]
and Neary and Roberts [22] who employ virtual prices to analyze
household consumption behavior under rationing. We, however, apply this
concept more generally to an entrepreneur who owns and controls a firm.
In our model, virtual prices are defined as the set of prices that
would induce the entrepreneur to make the same choices in a perfect
markets environment as he actually makes when there exists one or more
imperfect markets. To make this definition explicit, consider the ith
commodity consumed. The first-order condition for this commodity is (13)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] where [Mathematical Expression
Omitted] is the virtual price. If this commodity is traded on a perfect
market the virtual price equals the market price, [P.sub.i]. However,
suppose that the ith commodity is exchanged on an imperfect market for
which the market environment constraint binds. In this case, the first
order condition is (14) [Alpha] U/ [Alpha] [X.sub.i] = [Lambda]
[P.sub.i] - [[Sigma].sub.i] where the Lagrangian multiplier
[[Sigma].sub.i] is the shadow price of the market environment
constraint.(4) Solving (13) and (14) for the virtual price yields (15)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] Equation (15) reveals that the virtual
price of the ith commodity is equal to the sum of the market price and
the ratio of the shadow price of the market environment constraint to
the marginal utility of income. If in perfect market the entrepreneur
would maximize utility by consuming more (less) of the ith commodity
than he consumes in an imperfect market, then the shadow price would be
negative (positive and consequently the virtual price would be greater
(less) than the market price. If in a perfect market the entrepreneur
would maximize utility by consuming the same amount of the ith commodity
as he consumes in an imperfect market, then the shadow price would be
zero and hence the virtual price would equal the market price. However,
this is merely the case where the market environment constraint in not
binding.
Similarly, the virtual price of the jth input consumed
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] is (16) [Mathematical Expression
Omitted] The virtual prices of the ith output produced and jth input
employed assume forms identical to (15) and 16), respectively. Since
[Sigma] i , [Phi] j, and [Lambda] are determined by the solution to the
constrained utility maximization problem, virtual prices are endogenous
variables. Moreover, it can be easily shown that the market price
divergence terms are given by [[Sigma].sub.i]/[Lambda] = [[Delta]
[[Pi].sup.obs]/[Delta] [G.sub.i] and [[Phi].sub.j]/[Lambda] = [Delta]
[[Pi].sup.obs]/[Delta] [R.sub.j], where [[Pi] [sup.obs] is observable
profit, and therefore depend on the amount by which observable profit
would change in response to an infinitesimal relaxation of the market
restriction parameter.
Analytically, the perfect markets model can be viewed as a special
case of the more general imperfect markets model since the latter
reduces to the former only if virtual and market prices coincide.
An example concerning the nature of the market for the
entrepreneurial input will help to elucidate the intuition underlying
the model. Following Olsen [24], let us suppose that the entrepreneur
perceives hired management to be non-substitutable for managerial
services which he himself provides to his firm.(5) This assumption is
made explicit by defining the market environment constraint [V.sub.m] -
[Z.sub.m] [is less than or equal to] O where [V.sub.m] is employment of
managerial services and [Z.sub.m] is the amount of input services
supplied by the entrepreneur. This constraint indicate that [V.sub.m]
> [Z.sub.m] are perceived as irrelevant alternatives and therefore
reside outside of the entrepreneur's effective choice set. Should
the entrepreneur wish to be a net supplier of input services at the
prevailing market wage [W.sub.m], the market environment constraint is
non-binding and hence market and virtual prices coincide. However, if
the entrepreneur desires to be a net hirer of a homogeneous managerial
input, this is not possible. As a result, the market environment
constraint is strictly binding and [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
which implies [Mathematical Expression Omitted]. That is, the virtual
price exceeds the observable market price and does so by the amount by
which observable profit would change as a result of a marginal
relaxation of the market environment constraint which when binding
compels the entrepreneur to equate his own work effort with the quantity
of managerial services that he employs. Relaxation of the constraint
i.e., d [R.sub.m] > O, would result in an increase in observable
profit by an amount equal to the difference between the marginal revenue product of the entrepreneurial input and observable market wage, the
former evaluated at the point of constrained utility maximization.(6)
Making assumptions explicit through the use of market environment
constraints can expose conceptually incorrect measures of cost. For
instance, implicit in the analyses of Scitovszky [29], Ladd [17], and
Piron [25] is the supposition that the entrepreneur performs a firm
specific function such that the services which he renders cannot be
purchased or sold on a market. This assumption is made explicit by the
market environment constraint [V.sub.m] - [Z.sub.m] = O.(7) In the
context of the theoretical framework employed by these writers, it is
easily demonstrated that the virtual price is given by the value of the
entrepreneur's marginal product evaluated at the at the point of
constrained utility maximization. However, following Scitovszky all of
these writers measure the cost of the entrepreneurial input using the
income/leisure indifference curve that "represents the minimum
satisfaction that will keep the entrepreneur in his profession"
[29, 58].
IV. Comparative Static Properties
To investigate the comparative static behavior of the entrepreneur,
we analyze the partial derivatives of the utility-maximizing choice
functions. Total differentiation of the first-order equations (12),
(10b), (10c), (10d), and (10e) yields the matrix equation (17) Hs = d
(17) where H is a square, symmetric, bordered Hessian matrix of
dimension 3n + 3m + 2, d is a vector of constants, and s is a solution
vector s = [Mathematical Expression Omitted] for i = 1, . . . , n, j =
1,..., m. Using Cramer's rule, we write all price derivatives in
the form of the following Slutsky type equations(8) (18a) Mathematical
Expression Omitted] (18b) [Mathematical Expression Omitted] (18c)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] (18d) [Mathematical Expression
Omitted] (18e) [Mathematical Expression Omitted] (18f) [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] (18g) [Mathematical Expression Omitted] (18h)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] where [Lambda] is the marginal utility
of full-income, ~H~ is the determinant of H, and [C.sub.ab] is the
cofactor of the element in the ath row and bth column of ~H~.
Derivative properties (18) indicate that a change in the price of
the ith commodity or jth input initiates two potential effects on the
optimal amount of an activity chosen. The first term on the right hand
side is a substitution effect, the second term is an income effect.
Analogous to ordinary consumer theory, utility-maximizing behavior in
general places no restrictions on the sign of the income effect.
Since the matrix H is symmetric, the cofactor matrix of H is also
symmetric so that [C.sub.ab] = [C.sub.ba] for all a and b. Thus, if
there exists only a single cofactor in the substitution term, then a set
of symmetry conditions characterize cross substitution effects.
Moreover, by the second order conditions for utility maximization, H
must be negative definite so that all direct substitution effects are
well-behaved and unambiguous in sign. However, the general expressions
for the substitution effects in (18) contain multiple cofactors. This
raises the possibility of asymmetric and ill-behaved substitution
effects on production and consumption choices. This possibility was
noted by Graaff [14] for the case where the owner operator provides an
"entrepreneurial service which can be made available to no firm but
his own". We find that this result holds generally.
The case of perfect markets is nested within the more general
imperfect markets model. If we impose the restriction of perfect markets
for all goods and inputs substitution effects become symmetric and
income effects in production disappear. If in addition, no commodities
are both produced and consumed by the owner, then the income effect on
consumption is the same as results found in Slutsky [30]. However,
income effects on consumption may differ from Slutsky income effects if
any goods are both produced and consumed by the owner. Inspection of
derivative property (19c) reveals that when the kth commodity is both
consumed and produced by the entrepreneur, the expression for the income
effect includes the additional term [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
This term, which represents the effect of a change in the price of the
ith commodity on profit and hence entrepreneurial income, could
theoretically swamp the traditional substitution and income effects
resulting in a positively sloped demand curve for a normal good.(9)
Assume that a binding market environment constraint exists for the
ith commodity or jth input both supplied and demanded by the
entrepreneur and in addition that the kth commodity (hth input) is
either supplied or demanded. In this situation, the asymmetric cofactor
in the substitution term vanishes for all kth commodity (hth input)
price derivatives, except the ith/jth price; the income effect term will
generally be non-zero. Thus, price disturbances generate income effects
on kth output (hth input) production choices and substitution effects
are symmetric and well-behaved for all choices except those pertaining to price changes for the ith commodity or jth input.
Finally, let us assume that a binding market environment constraint
exists for the ith commodity (jth input) both supplied and demanded, and
the entrepreneur both supplies and demands the kth commodity (hth
input). In this case, neither the income effect nor asymmetric element
in the substitution term vanish. Optimal kth (hth) choices are subject
to income effects and asymmetric cross substitution effects. Moreover,
the possibility of ill-behaved direct substitution effects now exists
because the second-order conditions place no restrictions on the sign of
the off-diagonal cofactors.
To summarize, binding market environment constraint for commodities
or inputs both supplied and demanded result in income effects on
production as well as consumption choices. Furthermore, these
commodities and inputs have substitution effects which are asymmetric
and ambiguous in sign. These are important results because they provide
the basis for the theoretical possibility of downward sloping output
supply curves and upward sloping input demand curves. Furthermore, these
results may prove useful in understanding other apparent irregularities
and suggest generalization of theoretical implication such as Roy's
Identity and Shephard's and Hotelling's lemmas.
V. Economic Profit, Observable Profit and Accounting Profit
Consistency of utility and profit maximization has been an ongoing
debate [17; 25; 23; 24; 3; 8; 9; 10; 28; 15; 11]. The meaningful
questions are 1) does utility maximization imply maximization of
observable profit? and 2) if the firm does not maximize observable
profit, can it survive in the long run? The debate has been unclear on
what is meant by profit maximization because there has not been an
explicit distinction between economic, observable and accounting profit.
Once these different profit concepts are clearly defined, the debate is
easily resolved.
Since optimal choices of the entrepreneur are based on virtual
prices, these prices are the prices relevant for a behavioral profit
measure. Therefore, we define economic profit, [Pi]*, as the difference
between revenue and cost calculated using virtual prices. That is, (19)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] The prices in (19) are virtual prices
given in (15) and (16). This measure of [Pi]* is not an exact measure of
profit because virtual prices are marginal rather than average prices.
However, we believe the measure given by (19) is appropriately called
economic profit because it directly embodies the optimizing behavior of
the entrepreneur and consequently assumes the resource allocation role
played by profit in traditional theory.
Defining an exact behavioral measure of profit is neither possible
nor necessary in analyzing entrepreneurial behavior when utility
maximization is postulated. An exact measure is not possible because
virtual prices are only defined when the entrepreneur is in
equilibrium.(10) An exact measure is not needed because economic profit
as defined by (19) answers the meaningful questions regarding
entrepreneurial behavior.
Observable profit is the difference between total revenue and total
cost measured by observable market prices. To calculate observable
profit, implicit revenue and cost from self-produced consumption and
self-owned inputs are evaluated using market prices. The measure of
observable profit is (20) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
Accounting profit is defined in the traditional way as the
difference between explicit revenue and explicit cost. That is, (21)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] Accounting profit represents cash flow
and differs from observable profit if there are any self-produced
consumption commodities or self-owned inputs.
Observable profit is equal to economic profit if perfect markets
exist for all commodities and inputs relevant to the entrepreneur under
investigation because then there is a coincidence of virtual and market
prices. However let us suppose that kth commodity and lth input are not
traded on perfect markets. In this case, economic profit becomes (22)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] which can be rewritten as (23)
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] It follows directly from (23) that
(24) [Mathematical Expression Omitted] That is, for the
utility-maximizing entrepreneur, economic profit can be greater than,
equal to, or less than observable profit.
It is clear that employing observed profit, equation (20), as a
measure of economic profit can be in error when dealing with a
utility-maximizing entrepreneur who makes choices in an environment of
imperfect markets. However, Olsen [23] and Feinberg [8;9] implicitly
impose binding market environment constraints on at least one commodity
or input but then employ a measure equivalent to (20) for profit. Olsen
argues that this is an "objective" measure of economic profit
while Feinberg maintains that using any magnitude other than an
observable market price reduces the notion of economic profit to a
tautology. We disagree with both these views. Virtual prices are the
prices determining individual behavior. These prices are derived from
the individual's subjective utility function and embody market
environment constraints. Only in a world of perfect markets can
objective market prices be used to calculate a behavioral measure of
profit.
Economic profit as defined above embodies entrepreneurial behavior
and explains resources allocation. In this form it is easy to verify
that economic and observable profit in general do not coincide and that
utility maximization does not imply maximization of observable profit.
The second question of the debate is whether firms that fail to
maximize observable profit can survive in the long run.(11) Our measure
of economic profit based on virtual prices further illuminates this
question. There are two aspects to the survivability questions: i) under
what conditions would the firm choose to stay in the industry? and ii)
under what conditions will the firm be forced to exit the industry?
Assuming no irregularities such as non-convexities, the firm chooses to
remain in the industry if economic profit is non-negative. The owner is
deriving greater utility from operating in the industry than he would
derive from using self-owned inputs in their best alternative areas of
employment. The utility-maximizing firm nevertheless faces a cash flow
constraint. This constraint requires non-negative accounting profit
given by (21). If accounting profits are continually negative, then the
firm would eventually be forced from the industry.
Consider the following scenario. Let us suppose that we have two
types of firms selling a homogenous product in a competitive commodity
market and purchasing inputs in competitive factor markets. Type A firms
are comprised of traditional neoclassical profit maximizers. Type B
firms are utility-maximizing owner operated firms whose owners derive
satisfaction from at least one good not traded a perfect market. Given
the assumption of competitive commodity and input markets, type A firms
face exogenously given prices and therefore economic profit is correctly
measured by observable profit.
Now suppose that in long-run competitive equilibrium type A firms
are experiencing zero observable and hence zero economic profit whereas
type B firms are recording negative observable profit. One might hasten to conclude that type B firms cannot survive. However, if economic
profit as measured by (19) is non-negative, then these firms may indeed
survive and choose to maintain their self-owned inputs, including
entrepreneurial services, in their present area of employment.
Intuitively, condition (24) suggests that the utility-maximizing
entrepreneur may be willing to sacrifice observable profit for sources
of utility that cannot be acquired in the marketplace. Only if type B
firm experience negative economic profit as measured by (19) or negative
accounting profit as measured by (21) will they exit the industry and
reallocate self-owned inputs to other uses.
The results that negative economic profit implies exit from the
industry is dependent upon the absence of non-convexities in preferences
and technology. However, if such non-convexities do exist, economic
profit measured in terms of virtual prices may not be a consistent
indicator of entry/exit decisions and hence resource allocation.(12)
Consider a simple economy with two goods, output and leisure, and a
single input, labor. Figure 1 depicts the choice problem for a
representative entrepreneur. Distance OT on the horizontal axis measures
total time endowment with point T the point of maximum leisure and zero
work. The slope of line TC measures the market wage in terms of output
when the entrepreneur engages in non-entrepreneurial activity. If the
entrepreneur chooses to work for himself, the production possibilities
set is given by TBAO, which indicates that TB hours of work effort is
required before positive production is possible. If a perfect market
exists for entrepreneurial labor, then a feasible consumption set for
the entrepreneur is given by OANLT. To maximize utility, the
entrepreneur produces at point N where the marginal product equals the
real market wage thereby maximizing observable profit, the vertical
distance between point N and point P. He then consumes at point F where
the marginal rate of substitution equals the real market wage thereby
working TS hours at his own firm and employing SR hours of hired labor,
a perfect substitute.
Now assume that an imperfection exists in the market for
entrepreneurial labor so that the entrepreneur cannot be a net purchaser
at the prevailing market wage. In this case, the entrepreneur must
equate his own labor demand and supply so that point E depicts the
utility-maximizing position. The slope of line JK measures the virtual
wage, which clearly exceeds the market wage. Economic profit evaluated
in terms of the virtual wage is negative and equal to the vertical
distance between point E and point H. If the entrepreneur could sell his
labor services at this virtual wage, he would maximize utility (point G
on indifference curve IV) by closing down his firm and working for
another firm. However, given the market imperfection the wage rate
available in the outside market is below the virtual wage. Therefore,
even though the entrepreneur is experiencing negative economic profit
measured in terms of virtual prices he will still choose to operate in
the industry. This is because operating the firm results in a higher
utility level (point E on indifference curve II) than shutting down the
firm and supplying labor at the market wage (point D on indeferrence
curve I). This paradox arises because the virtual wage is a marginal
rather than average value and varies with the level of work effort.
However, this type of inconsistency between utility-maximizing choices
and economic profit would not exist if the production possibilities set
were convex.
In the absence of non-convexities, utility-maximizing firms
experiencing non-negative economic profit will choose to remain in the
industry while those experiencing negative economic profits will choose
to exit. Long-run feasibility requires that accounting profit be
non-negative. Thus, long-run survival requires that both economic an
accounting profit be non-negative, but puts no restrictions on the
largely irrelevant observed profit.
VI. Non-Cost Minimizing Behavior
The model of the power operated firm we develop in this paper
suggests that the entrepreneur may trade-off observable profit for goods
that cannot be acquired on perfect markets. Possibilities include such
"goods" as nepotism, discrimination, against certain types of
inputs, and charitable contributions in the form of excessive wages paid
to employees. The existence of these non-market goods result in the
divergence of virtual prices for inputs from their observed prices. The
result is non-minimization of observed costs. One might be tempted to
label this phenomenon "X-inefficiency" and conclude that it is
a firm specific problem.(13) However, we believe our model offers
advantages over the X-inefficiency theory. We maintain a framework where
seemingly inefficient behavior actually from rational decision making.
Our model of the owner operated firm provides more structure and
explanation and forces attention on market failures. We have shown that
if perfect markets exists for all commodities and inputs, then
utility-maximizing firms would make the same choices as competitive
profit-maximizing firms and achieve economic efficiency from a social
view. In our model, the explicit source of seemingly inefficient
behavior is the existence of an imperfect or absent market instead of a
more nebulous "firm specific inefficiency.
Our model of the owner operated firm also provides greater
theoretical foundations for models of non-cost minimizing behavior such
as those presented by Toda [31], Atkinson and Halvorsen [2] and Eakin
and Kniesner [7]. These models relax the cost-minimization assumption by
letting perceived input prices systematically differ from observed
market prices. The term capturing the divergence is typically modelled
as a single parameter to be estimated. Our theory provides an
explanation for this deviation, but also makes explicit the endogeneity
of the shadow price. While we have bolstered the theoretical foundations
of the none-minimum cost function, we have also exposed an inconsistency
in these empirical models which needs to be rectified.
VII. Summary and Conclusions
We have presented a general theory of the owner operate firm in
which market imperfections result in deviations between virtual and
observed prices. When markets imperfection are not binding constraints,
the model reduces to one of perfect markets and there is a convergence
of virtual and observed prices and economic an observed profit. The
comparative static properties for the owner operated firm show that
binding market constraints result in income effects in production and
asymmetric substitution effects. These non-traditional effects originate solely from market imperfections and not from restrictive assumptions,
about technology, preferences or behavior. The existence of these
effects gives rise to the theoretical possibility of downward sloping
output supply curves and upward sloping input demand curves.
We resolve the debate on the consistency of utility maximization
and profit maximization by demonstrating that in the presence of
imperfect markets economic profit diverges from observed profit.
Observed profit is not directly relevant to either the firm's
objective or survival. We also have shown that market imperfections may
be the source of seemingly uneconomic behavior, thereby providing a
theoretical foundation for models of X-inefficiency and systematic
allocative inefficiency. (1)The perfect markets model is structurally
equivalent to the variety of recursive farm household models for
developing economies [16; 19; 4]. In this sort of model estimating the
production and consumption sides separately greatly facilitates the
estimation procedure. (2)The concept of virtual prices is explained
later in this section. (3)Equations (2) and (9b) imply that
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. This is the form of the last
constraints facing tthe entrepreneur given by equation (10e). (4)This
usage of the term shadow price is consistent with that of Neary and
Roberts [22]. (5)Theoretical and empirical evidence supporting this
assumption is in Olsen [24]. (6)In the case of one output, the
first-order condition imply [Mathematicall Expression Omitted] where P
is output price ad [Delta] F/[Delta] [V.sub.m] is the marginal product
of the entreprenuer. (7)This assumption is also implicit in the
short-run analysis of Olsen [23]. (8)When the jth input price changes
the term [W.sub.j] [Z.sub.j] is separated from I in order to capture the
full effect of the alteration in price. The net effect is to change the
weight attached to the income derivative from [Mathematical Expression
Omitted]. This is true for j = I, ..., m. (9)This non-traditional income
effect is widely recognized in the development literature and has been
found principally to generate sloped demand curves for farm households
in these economies [4; 19]. (10)Of course in a world of perfect markets
economic profit and observable profit coincide and constitute an exact
measure. (11)In addition to those papers cited in section I, see Reder
[26], Alchian [1], Friedman [12], and Williamson [32]. (12)We thank the
referee for pointing out this possibility. (13)For a discussion of the
notion of X-inefficiency see Leibenstein [20; 21].
References
[1]Alchian, Armen, "Uncertainty, Evolution, and Economic
Theory." Journal of Political Economy, June 1950, 211-21.
[2]Atkinson, Scott and Robert Halvorsen, "Parameter Efficiency
Tests, Economies of Scale and Input Demand in U.S. Electric Power
Generation." International Economic Review, October 1984, 643-62. [
]Auster, Richard and Morris Silver. "Comparative Statics of the
Utility-Maximizing Firm." Southern Economic Journal, April 1976,
626-32. [4]Barnum, Howard and Lyn Squire," An Economic Application
of the Theory of the Farm Household. Journal of Development Economics,
June 1979, 79-102. [5]Becker, Gary, "A Theory of the Allocation of
Time." Economic Journal, September 1965, 493-517. [6]Clower,
Robert, "Mr. Graaff's Producer-Consumer Theory: A Restatement and Correction." Review of Economic Studies, 1952, 84-85. [7]Eakin,
B. Kelly and Thomas J. Kniesner, "Estimating a Non-Minimum Cost
Function for Hospital." Southern Economic Journal, January 1988,
583-97. [8]Feinberg, Robert, "Profit Maximization vs. Utility
Maximization." Southern Economic Journal, July 1975, 130- 1. [9]--,
"On the Consistency of Non-Profit-Maximizing Behavior with Perfect
Competition." Southern Economic Journal, July 1980, 1160-66.
[10]--. "On Equivalence of Profit Miximization and Utility
Maximization by an Owner-Manager: Reply." Southern Economic
Journal, July 1982, 260-61. [11]Formby, John and Edward Millner,
"The Convergence of Utility and Profit Maximization." Southern
Economic Journal, April 1985, 1174-85. [12]Friedman, Milton. Essays in
Positive Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1953. pp. 3-4
. [13]Graaff, J. De V., "Rothbarth's Virtual Price System and
the Slutsky Equation." Review of Economic Studies, 1948, 91-95.
[14]--, "Income Effects and the Theory of the Firm." Review of
Economic Studies, 1950-51, 79-86. [15]Hannan, Timothy, "On the
Equivalence of Profit Maximization and Utility Maximization by an
Owner-Manager: Comment." Southern Economic Journal, July 1982,
255-59. [16]Krishna, Raj. "Models of the Family Farm," in
Subsistence Agriculture and Economic Development, edited by C.R.
Wharton, Jr., Chicago: Aldine Publishing, 1969. [17]Ladd, George,
"Utility Maximization Sufficient for Competitive Survival.
"Journal of Political Economy, July/August 1969, 478-83. [18]Lapan,
Harvey and Douglas Brown, "Utility Maximization, Individual
Production, and Market Equilibrium." Southern Economic Journal,
October 1988, 374-89. [19]Lau, Lawrence, Wuu-Long Lin, and Pan
Yotopoulos, "The Linear Logarithmic Expenditure System: An
Application to Consumption Leisure Choice," Econometrica, July
1978, 843-68. [20]Leibenstein, Harvey, "Allocative Efficiency vs.
X-Efficiency." American Economic Review, June 1966, 392-415.
[21]--, "A Branch of Economics is Missing: Micro-Micro
Theory." Journal of Economics Literature, June 1979, 477-502.
[22]Neary, J. Peter, and K. W. S. Roberts, "The Theory of Household
Behavior Under Rationing." European Economic Review, January 1980,
25-42. [23]Olsen, E. Odgers, "Utility and Profit Maximization by an
Owner-Manager." Southern Economic Journal, January 1973, 389-95.
[24]--, "Profit Maximization vs. Utility Maximization: A
Correction." Southern Economic Journal, January 1977, 1390-9 .
[25]Piron, Robert, "Utility Maximization Sufficient for Competitive
Survival: Comment." Journal of Political Economy, May/June 1974,
654-57. [26]Reder, Melvin W., "A Reconsideration of the Marginal
Productivity Theory." Journal of Political Economy, October 1947,
450-58. [27]Rothbarth, E., "The Measurement of Changes in Real
Income under Conditions of Rationing." Review of Economic Studies,
1940-41, 100-107. [28]Schlesinger, Harris, "A Note on the
Consistency of Non-Profit Maximizing Behavior with Perfect
Competition." Southern Economic Journal, October 1981, 513-16.
[29]Scitovoszky, Tibor, "A note on Profit Maximization and its
Implications, "Review of Economic Studies, 1943-44, 57-60.
[30]Slutsky, Eugen, "On the Theory of the Budget of the
Consumer." Giornale degli Economisti, 1915. Translated and
reprinted in Readings in Price Theory, Volume 6, edited by G. Stigler
and K. Boulding, Chicago: R. D. Irwin, 1952. [31]Toda, Yasushi,
"Estimation of a Cost Function When Cost is not Minimized."
Review of Economics and Statistics, August 1976, 259-68. [32]Williamson,
Oliver. The Economics of Discretionary Behavior: Managerial Objectives
in a Theory of the Firm. Englewood Cliffs, N.J., Prentice Hall, 1964.