Financial Markets and Financial Crises.
Kindleberger, Charles P.
This book which grew out of a 1990 NBER conference divides fairly
well into two parts, the first on crises and panics in commercial
banking, the second on current issues in corporate debt, the dollar and
the savings-and-loan troubles of the 1980s.
The first part include papers by Mark Gertler, Glenn Hubbard and
Anil Kashyap on the connections between crises and fluctuations in real
investment; by Ben Bernanke and Harold James on the gold standard and
1929; by Fred Mishkin, testing the role of asymmetric information in
panics; and by Charles Calomoris and Gary Gorton on the origins of
panics. Barry Eichengreen and Peter Garber also write on the 1951
Fed-Treasury accord, an issue on the edge of the crisis theme.
There is much to chew on in these initial essays. The writers are
at pains to move beyond earlier views focussed narrowly on monetary
explanations, for example, that the October crash had little to do with
the 1929-33 depression, or that distinction should be made between
"real" financial crises which involved large declines in the
money base, and "pseudo crises" which confound markets but do
not. Much is what is made of what are claimed to be new theoretical
insights, some of which are familiar if put into plain English from the
new jargon, e.g., asymmetric information, adverse selection, moral
hazard, agency problems, heterogenously-informed depositors,
sequential-service constraint. Emphasis is put on panics occuring
following a rise in the interest-rate differential between riskless and
risky assets, following some untoward event such as a stock-market
crash. Today in Wall Street this is called "a flight to
quality." It is consonant with a change in expectations from
euphoric which may have resulted in a bubble or in less spectacular
overshooting to uncertainty or to fears of trouble.
Little attention is given to the events causing the change in
expectations. Gertler, Hubbard and Kashyap blame monetary policy,
mentioned three times in a single paragraph [p. 27]. Bernanke and James
mention the possibility of a rise in real wages, without noting that
this in 1929 and later came entirely from the decline in prices.
Bernanke's frequently-cited 1983 paper explaining how bank troubles
could produce depression through credit rationing did not investigate
the connection between call-loan difficulties in October 1929 and the
collapse in commodity prices as bank credit was denied commodity
brokers. His paper with James mentions a price decline of 4 percent in
1929. With monthly instead of annual data, this decline, concentrated
mostly into two months, when U.S. nominal imports fell 25 percent, would
look different. Nor do Bernanke and James observe that the depreciation
of sterling involved appreciation of the gold bloc and the dollar, with
strong downward pressure on prices, another force supporting the
debt-deflation argument of Fisher, Minsky and Kindleberger, which they
allow as a possibility but for which they do not test.
Mishkin's emphasis on the interest differential makes a
powerful case. in his further research he might note that in 1930, it
occurred in foreign bonds (March) earlier than in domestic issues [5,
227; 2, 304]. It went beyond bonds, treasury bills and commercial paper,
moreover, into municipal bonds [4] to mortgages (the Bank of the United
States) and to real estate [3].
Calomoris and Gorton, investigating the origin of panics, compare
"random withdrawals," especially at harvest or planting time
when agricultural credit is stretched, with asymmetric information, and
decide, after some hesitation, in favor of the latter. They divide
depositors into insiders and outsiders, the sophisticated and the badly
informed, a distinction that could also be made in the euphoric phase of
booms, applauding the well-informed who withdraw deposits early for
their help in monitoring banks [p. 126]. Would that also apply to those
who break early for the doors in a theatre when someone has shouted
fire? What is rational in an individual may be dysfunctional en masse.
Mark Warshawsky's paper on corporate debt concludes that there
is still considerable danger in high debt structures, especially in
construction. The data in his, as in most of the papers reach down only
to 1988, and cannot assess the relief afforded by the 1991 reduction in
interest rates. Bankim Chadha and Steven Symansky apply the IMF MULTIMOD
econometric model to the single years from 1990 to 1995 and to 2000 and
2010, with various assumptions, to contemplate whether the U.S. balance
of payments is sustainable. Besides the U.S., there is a group of other
industrial countries, which lend, and the net debtor countries, which
take little part in the action. I have little faith in linear models
which stretch out twenty years into the future. If other countries
continue to lend, and we devalue 10 percent, this country will
accumulate $3.4 trillion in foreign assets by 2010. Various other
assumptions, however, put the country in that year into foreign debt
(all figures relative to the base line) between $1.5 and 8.4 trillion,
with domestic debt, at the peak, of $32.2 trillion, owing to the power
of compound interest. The authors are aware of the capital needs of
Eastern Europe and the former Soviet republics, but could not allow for
them.
The three papers on the thrift industry will appeal to students of
finance. All emphasize the disintermediation that came with the sharp
rise in interest rates in 1979-81. Patric Hendershott and James Shilling
continue to worry over the possibility of new cycles of rising interest
rates, given the switch from fixed to adjustable rate mortgages which
helps borrowers as rates rise, even while fixed-rate borrowers refinance
on the down side. Eduardo Schwartz and Walter Touros offer a technical
paper on the value of caps to ARM borrowers. To this reader the long
paper by George Benston, Mike Carhill and Brian Olasov was highly
informative, both for the problems for thrifts from disintermediation
and legislative attempts to remedy them. Studying particularly events in
the southeast of the country, the authors are inclined to play down the
malfeasance that features so prominently in the press. One ironic twist
is that small rural thrifts whose depositors were too unsophisticated to
disintermediate (and their officials too traditional to take risks, go
for brokered deposits, or understand junk bonds?), survived far better
than their urban counterparts.
The essays provide an abundance of data in tables and graphs, plus
much econometric testing. A number of the authors, however, are less
than confident about the results and call for more and careful research
[pp. 27, 64, 77, 105]. It is something of a reflection on the profession
that now, sixty years after the event, it is still unable to explain
with confidence the 1929 U.S. and world depression.
References
[1.] Bernanke, Ben, "Non-monetary Effects of the Financial
Crisis in the Propagation of the Great Depression." American
Economic Review, June 1983, 257-76. [2.] Friedman, Milton and Anna
Jacobson Schwartz. A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960.
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1963. [3.] Hoyt, Homer. One
Hundred Years of Land Values in Chicago. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 1933. [4.] McFerrin, John Berry. Caldwell and Company: A Southern
Financial Empire. Chapel Hill, N.C.: University of North Carolina Press,
1939, reissued, Nashville, Tenn.: Vanderbilt University Press, 1969.
[5.] Sachs, Jeffrey. "LDC Debt in the 1980s, Risk and
Reforms," in Crises in the Economic and Financial Structure, edited
by Paul Wachtel. Lexington, Mass.: D.C. Heath, 1982, pp. 197-243.