High tuition, financial aid, and cross-subsidization: do needy students really benefit?
Sorensen, Robert L.
Our policy is total Robin Hood - we put our tuition up as high as
possible and then put most of the extra money into financial aid. [Eamon
M. Kelly, president of Tulane University, 19871.](1)
I. Introduction
One way to make a college education widely accessible is to charge
low tuition. Yet many college administrators argue that a policy of
charging high tuition while generously awarding financial aid can even
further reduce the net price paid by needy students.(2) Since there is
little doubt that this implicit form of cross-subsidization has
benefited some students, this practice has been widely accepted by the
public. To date, however, no one has investigated the actual impact of
cross-subsidization on the net price paid by needy students.(3)
The fact that this question has not been addressed is surprising
since this form of cross-subsidization is observationally equivalent to
ordinary price discrimination. Indeed, high tuition coupled with
generous financial aid awards may simply reflect a policy of maximizing
tuition revenues to pursue other objectives. How, then, can we be sure
that institutions that claim they charge high tuition to subsidize needy
students are in fact reducing their net price?
In this paper we investigate whether the net price paid by the
average needy student is negatively related to the degree in which
institutions appear to inflate their tuition to engage in
cross-subsidization. First we show that cross-subsidization can, under
fairly general conditions, reduce the average net price paid by all
needy students. Next we identify a necessary condition for concluding
that cross-subsidization results in the average needy student paying a
lower net price. We then test whether this condition is satisfied by
examining the cross-sectional relationship between tuition and financial
aid awards for 502 private institutions of higher learning. Finally, we
compare some selected budget items of institutions that charge
relatively high tuition to those that charge relatively low tuition to
gain insight into what kinds of institutional objectives compete with
the goal of maximizing accessibility.(4)
II. The Model
Cross-Subsidization and Net Price for Needy Students
Can institutions that charge inflated tuition actually reduce the
net price paid by all needy students through cross-subsidization? This
question can be addressed by way of an example. Let n be the total
number of students attending a particular institution and let m be that
institution's number of needy students. Now consider a tuition
increase of one dollar that leaves both n and m unchanged.(5) All
students must now pay an additional dollar to attend. Now suppose that
each of the m needy students receives an additional dollar of financial
aid to fully offset the tuition increase. In this case the net price
paid by each needy student does not change but (n - m) dollars of
additional tuition revenue is left over to be spent at the
institution's discretion. If only one of these dollars is put into
additional financial aid and divided among the needy students, then the
tuition increase will actually reduce the net price paid by all needy
students. Indeed, in this example average financial aid awards among
needy students increased by the amount of the tuition increase ($1) plus
1/m even though the institution gains (n - m - 1) dollars of additional
tuition revenue.
Tuition, Institutional Financial Aid Awards, and Net Price
In the example presented above we showed that institutions that can
inflate their tuition can expropriate additional revenues from wealthy
students to reduce the net price paid by all of their needy students. We
now identify a necessary condition for concluding that such policies
generally reduce the average net price paid by needy students.
The financial aid award for any given student is determined by both
the cost of attending a given institution and the student's ability
to pay. We can characterize the relationship between tuition, ability to
pay, and average financial aid awards with the following expression:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where A is an institution's average financial aid award among
all n full-time undergraduates, T is tuition, [P.sub.i] is the ith
financial aid recipient's ability to pay, m is the number of needy
students receiving institutional financial aid, and 0 [is less than or
equal to] [THETA] [is less than or equal to] 1 is the average percentage
of each financial aid recipient's need gap (T - [P.sub.i]) that is
closed by institutional financial aid awards.(6) The student's
ability to pay, [P.sub.i], is the institution's estimate of what
the student can afford to spend on a college education. We assume that
all institutions are in agreement as to the value of [P.sub.i] for any
given student.(7)
Let [T.sup.e] be the expected value of an institution's
tuition given its observable characteristics. In other words, [T.sup.e]
= E[T/X], where X is a vector of institutional characteristics that
describe an institution. Now suppose an institution considers adopting
tuition T > [T.sup.e] to engage in cross-subsidization. In such a
case, how much larger must the average financial aid award be for the
average net price paid by needy students to be reduced? A policy of
charging T > [T.sup.e] implies that for every student (including the
m needy ones) the cost of attending is now [DELTA T] = T - [T.sup.e]
greater than when T = [T.sup.e]. Of course, if each of the m needy
students receives less than [DELTA T] in additional financial aid, then
it follows that the average net price paid by the m needy students will
be greater than when T = [T.sup.e].
Since [DELTA T] = T - [T.sup.e], equation (1) can now be rewritten
as:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
which is equivalent to:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where [THETA] = [THETA.sub.1] = [THETA.sub.2] = [THETA.sub.3]. An
implicit assumption of this chain of equalities is that, for financial
aid awards, there is no behavioral difference between tuition dollars up
to [T.sup.e] and tuition dollars above [T.sup.e]. This, however, is
antithetical to a policy of cross-subsidization since with such a policy
the purpose of setting T > [T.sup.e] is to award financial aid to
needy students at an accelerated rate, which is equivalent to observing
that [THETA.sub.2] exceeds [THETA.sub.1].
From the discussion above it should be clear that if the objective
of charging T > [T.sup.e] is to make a college education more
affordable for needy students, then financial aid awards for all needy
students must be made at least [DELTA T] greater. Unfortunately, a
direct test of this requires student-by-student data which is
unavailable. This example does, however, have a straightforward
implication for the institution's average financial aid awards
among all full-time undergraduates. Specifically, it implies that a
necessary condition for concluding that T exceeds [T.sup.e] to reduce
the average net price paid by needy students is that average financial
aid awards must be more than (m/n) [DELTA T] larger than if T =
[T.sup.e]. To see this, note that this expression is simply the sum of
the increased burden placed on the m needy students averaged over all n
full-time undergraduates. Note that this is also equivalent to requiring
that A/ [DELTA T] > (m/n) if [DELTA T] > 0. In the context of
equation (3), this amounts to restricting [THETA.sub. 2] to be greater
than one. Thus, if [DELTA T] > 0 and we discover that [THETA.sub.2]
is less than one, we must conclude that the average needy student
actually pays a higher net price than if tuition were equal to
[T.sup.e]. We now turn to the task of estimating [THETA.sub.2].
III. Empirical Analysis
Methodology
In this section we develop a methodology for estimating equation
(3). We first discuss the formulation of proxies for [T.sup.e] and
[DELTA T]. We then alter equation (3) so [THETA.sub.2] can be estimated
conditional on [DELTA T] > 0. Finally, we identify proxies for (m/n)
and (1/n) [SIGMA.sub.1.sup.m] = 1 [P.sub.i.]
As noted above, [T.sup.e] = E[T/X] where X is a vector of
institutional characteristics that describe an institution. If X is
non-stochastic, then we can obtain estimates of [T.sup.e] by simply
regressing T against the members of X.(8) We therefore approximate
[T.sup.e] by estimating an OLS equation that models tuition as a
function of institutional quality, scope and mission while adjusting for
the presence of other sources of income. The tuition level predicted by
the tuition equation for institution j ([T.sub.j]) then serves as our
proxy for [T.sup.e] while the unpredicted component of tuition ([DELTA
T.sub.j] = [T.sub.j] - [T.sub.j]) serves as our proxy for [DELTA T].
Below we now discuss the relevant members of X.
Although no single variable can fully reflect institutional
quality, a common approach in previous research is to employ some
measure of selectivity such as average entrance exam scores [1; 13; 14].
The Barrons index of institutional selectivity divides institutions into
six categories based on the average high school class rank and the
median entrance exam scores (SAT or ACT) of entering freshman. In our
tuition equation we therefore include a set of dummy variables that are
based on the Barrons index [2]. This index classifies institutions into
the following categories: most competitive (MOST), highly competitive
(HIGHLY), very competitive (VERY), competitive (COMPET), less
competitive, and non-competitive institutions of higher learning (the
last two categories constitute the omitted group). A description of each
category is contained in Appendix I.
To reflect institutional scope and mission we also include a set of
dummy variables that classify each institution according to a
classification scheme that has been developed by the Carnegie
Foundation. A description of each Carnegie category is contained in
Appendix II. The Carnegie Foundation classifies each school as being
either a national university (UNIVERSITY), a national liberal arts
college (LIBERAL), a large comprehensive university (LGCOMP), a small
comprehensive university (SMCOMP), or a regional liberal arts college
(which is the omitted group).
Some institutions can charge lower tuition because they enjoy a
significant amount of non-tuition income. Similarly, some must charge
high tuition to make-up for a lack of non-tuition revenue. To account
for this we include endowment income and federal research grant overhead
dollars per full-time enrollment (including graduate students) (OTHER)
in our tuition equation.
Some institutions charge tuition that is equal to or below what is
predicted by the tuition regression equation so that [DELTA T.sub.j] [is
less than or equal to] 0. Since the testable implication derived in the
previous section only applies to the case where [DELTA T.sub.j] is
positive, we must now separate the [THETA.sub.2] (m/n)[DELTA T] term in
equation (3) into two terms conditioned on the estimated sign of [DELTA
T.sub.j]. To do this we replace the [THETA.sub.2(m/n)[DELTA T.sub.j]
term in equation (3) with [Mathematical Expression Omitted], where
[HIGH.sub.j] is a dummy variable equal to one if [DELTA T.sub.j] > 0
and [LOW.sub.j] = 1 - [HIGH.sub.j]. With this framework we can examine
the empirical validity of our testable implication under the
circumstances for which it applies (that is, when [DELTA T.sub.j] >
0) without altering the econometric properties of equation (3).
To estimate equation (3) a proxy for (1/n) [SIGMA.sub.1.sup.m = 1
[P.sub.1] is also needed. This term is equivalent to ability to pay
among the set of needy students averaged over the set of all full-time
undergraduates. Though this term is closely related to the average
ability to pay across all full-time undergraduates, a suitable proxy for
this term should only consider ability to pay among the set of needy
students. Below we argue that average federal Pell grant awards can be
used to devise an inverse proxy for (1/n) [SIGMA .sub.1.sup.m] = 1
[P.sub.1].
The U.S. Department of Education has established a detailed and
uniform methodology for determining student financial well-being on the
basis of student and parental income, net worth, number of siblings, and
other factors. To receive a federal Pell grant award a student must
first qualify by being deemed needy according to this uniform
methodology. Consequently, the total Pell grant dollars reported for any
given institution only pertains to the institution's m financially
needy students. In addition, the size of any Pell grant varies directly
with the individual student's financial well-being and, hence,
varies negatively with any recipient's ability to pay. Therefore,
we use total federal Pell grant award dollars divided by total full-time
undergraduate enrollment (AVGPELL) as an inverse proxy for the ability
to pay of an institution's needy students averaged over all
full-time students.(9)
Finally, before we can estimate equation (3) we must also identify
a proxy for (m/n). The proxy we use for (m/n) is the percentage of
students that receive any form of financial aid (PERAID). Unfortunately,
this variable may tend to overstate (m/n) since federal financial aid is
also included in the PERAID measure. This problem is at least partially
offset, however, by the fact that PERAID is based on both part-time and
full-time students. This tends to overstate n, which tends to make
PERAID understate (m/n).
We can now express equation (3) in its estimable form of:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where [AVGAID.sub.j] is institution j's average total grant and
scholarship financial aid awards across all n full-time undergraduate
students, [BETA.sub.0] is a constant term, and [BETA.sub.1],
[BETA.sub.2], and [BETA.sub.3] correspond to [THETA.sub.1],
[TETHA.sub.2.sup.H], and [THETA.sub.2.sup.L]. The [BETA.sub.4]
coefficient is equivalent to [alpha THETA.sub.3] where [alpha] is an
implicitly identified positive constant relating (1/[n.sub.j])
[SIGMA.sub.i.sup.m] = 1 [P.sub.ij] to the inverse proxy [AVGPELL.sub.j]
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. The [epsilon.sub.j] term is a zero
mean disturbance term that captures idiosyncratic sources of variation
in financial aid award decisions across institutions. Given the
discussion above, all of the slope coefficients are expected to be
positive.(10)
The Data
The data we use to estimate equation (4) are taken from the College
Examination Board's American Survey of Colleges (ASC) and the
Higher Education General Information Survey (HEGIS) for the academic
year 1985-86. Institutions that do not grant baccalaureate degrees or
were classified as being either proprietary or specialized in mission
(e.g., Bible colleges, theological seminaries, etc.) were eliminated
from the sample. The source, definition, and summary statistics for all
variables are presented in Table 1.
[TABULAR DATA OMITTED]
It should be noted that public institutions of higher learning are
not included in our sample. They are not included because observed
deviations from predicted tuition will reflect differing levels of
governmental support. Consequently, if we were to include them in our
sample, we would introduce a significant unobservable random component
to tuition which would reduce the efficiency of our coefficient
estimates.
IV. Regression Results and Interpretation
To generate estimates of [T.sub.j] and [THETA.sub.j] for the
estimation of equation (4) we now estimate the tuition equation using
ordinary least squares. The result of this estimation is summarized in
equation (5) below.
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
Sample: 502 observations
[R.sup2]:.56
Note: the absolute value of t-statistics are in parentheses.
As might be expected, the more selective the institution, the
higher the tuition. Interestingly, while national universities and
national liberal arts colleges have the highest tuition, national
liberal arts colleges are the more expensive of the two. This may
reflect the fact that liberal arts colleges, which focus on teaching and
feature small classes, generally have a higher faculty to student ratio
than universities. While the sign of the coefficient on the OTHER
variable is signed according to a priori expectations, it is
insignificant. This may result from the fact that the institutions that
possess the greatest amount of non-tuition income are also the most
prestigious ones [11]. Not surprisingly, the most prestigious
institutions also generally charge the highest tuition, which tends to
cancel-out the subsidizing effect of non-tuition income.
Using the estimates of [T.sub.j] and [DELTA T.sub.j] derived from
the estimations of the tuition equation, we can now estimate equation
(4) using ordinary least squares. Two formulations of average aid awards
are used in the estimation of equation (4). Specifically, AVGAID is
average grant and scholarship aid while NAVGAID is limited to need-based
grants and scholarships. The results of these estimations are reported
in Table II. As can be seen from the table, all of the coefficient
estimates conform to a priori expectations and nearly all were
statistically significant. The most striking result is that the
[BETA.sub.2] coefficient, and hence [THETA.sub.2], is always
statistically significant and positive but is always clearly less than
one. More importantly, the difference between [BETA.sub.1],
[BETA.sub.2], and [BETA.sub.3] in either of the regressions is
statistically insignificant, which implies that [THETA.sub.1] [is
congruent with] [THETA.sub.2].(11) This means institutions that charge
relatively high tuition are no more generous per tuition dollar than
those that charge expected or relatively low tuition. Of course this is
completely inconsistent with a policy of charging high tuition for the
purpose of reducing the net price paid by needy students. Finally, for
institutions that charge relatively low tuition (that is, institutions
in which [DELTA T.sub.j] [is less than or equal to] 0), average
financial aid awards are correspondingly lower.(12)
[TABULAR DATA OMITTED]
V. Other Institutional Objectives
If high tuition is not used to reduce the net price paid by the
average needy student, then why do some institutions inflate their
tuition above what would be expected given their programs and other
sources of income? There is no doubt that some institutions charge high
tuition to offset unusually high costs of operation. But this falls
short of a full explanation since our methodology already takes into
account the fact that some types of institutions are more expensive to
run than others. Another explanation is that the behavior of
institutions of higher learning is best understood when viewed in the
broader context of nonprofit organizations. In particular, James [5] has
argued that undergraduate instruction may function as a profit oriented enterprise that subsidizes other activities which yield utility directly
to college administrators and members of the faculty.
To gain some insight into the institutional activities that compete
with the objective of reducing the net price paid by needy students, we
now examine some selected budget items of the institutions in our
sample. In Table III we divide our sample into three categories:
national universities, comprehensive universities, and liberal arts
colleges. We further divide each of these categories into thirds:
institutions that charge relatively high tuition ([DELTA T/T.sup.e] much
larger than zero), institutions that charge relatively low tuition
([DELTA T/T.sup.e] much below zero), and those in between. The
conditional means of the following can now be calculated: relative
financial aid awards (AVGAID/T), administrative overhead expenditures
per full-time student, instructional costs per full-time student, and
the percentage of graduate students.(13)
[TABULAR DATA OMITTED]
In the table three regularities emerge within each category. First,
the proportion of tuition that is discounted by financial aid awards
(AVGAID/T) does not rise as we move from relatively low to relatively
high tuition institutions. This is entirely consistent with our
regression results. Second, administrative overhead expenditures per
full-time student rises noticeably as we move from relatively low to
relatively high tuition institutions. This is consistent with the view
that colleges and universities are subject to the same kinds of
incentive problems as other nonprofit organizations. It is also
consistent with recent increases in administrative costs over the last
decade - a period of rapid tuition increases as well [3]. Third,
instructional costs per full-time student also rise as we move from
relatively low to relatively high tuition institutions. High
instructional costs may reflect the fact that the faculty are earning
relatively high salaries or that they have relatively low teaching
loads. It should also be noted that since instructional costs include
internally funded research activity, high instructional costs may
reflect a greater emphasis on research.
In the table it is also clear that, for national universities, both
instructional costs and the percentage of graduate students rises
sharply as we move from relatively low to relatively high tuition
institutions. Since instructional costs include graduate instruction,
this finding is consistent with James [5] and James and Neuberger [6]
who note that "the tenured faculty at a university may make
allocation decisions that maximize the time spent on research and
graduate training, two activities they prefer."
VI. Concluding Remarks
In this paper we investigated whether the net price paid by the
average needy student is negatively related to the degree in which
institutions price discriminate to, presumably, engage in
cross-subsidization. We find that while institutions that appear to
inflate their tuition do make larger financial aid awards, their awards
are not large enough to reduce the average net price paid by needy
students.
We should emphasize that this finding does not mean that all needy
students are made worse-off by such policies. Rather, it more likely
suggests that to whatever extent such cross-subsidization does occur, it
is practiced in a more selective fashion than modeled here. Perhaps
institutions concentrate their efforts on reducing the net price paid by
narrowly targeted groups of needy students. If institutions do target
their financial aid, however, then the merit of cross-subsidization is
difficult to assess. The targeted needy students are obviously made
better-off and the additional revenues can be used to pursue any number
of worthy institutional goals. On the other hand, the needy students
that are not targeted are made worse-off and there is no guarantee that
the additional revenues are spent in a manner that is consistent with
the stated objectives of the institution.
In our examination of selected budget items we attempted to reveal
what was actually being subsidized with high tuitions. The link between
high tuition and administrative overhead suggests that college
administrators are important beneficiaries of high tuition. The link
between high tuition and instructional costs suggests that faculty
members are also important beneficiaries. Finally, the link between high
tuition and the percentage of graduate students suggests that graduate
programs and graduate students also benefit.
Appendix I. Barrons Measures of College Selectivity
Most Competitive To be classified in this category a school must require ap
plicants to have a
(MOST) high school class rank in the top 10% to 20%. Median SAT t
est scores of
entering freshmen are at least 1250.
Highly Competitive To be classified in this category a school must require a
pplicants to have a
(HIGHLY) high school class rank in the top 20% to 35%. Median SAT
test scores of
entering freshmen are 1150 to 1250.
Very Competitive To be classified in this category a school must require a
pplicants to have a
(VERY) high school class rank in the top 35% to 50%. Median SAT
test scores of
entering freshmen are 1050 to 1150.
Competitive To be classified in this category a school must require a
pplicants to have a
(COMPET) high school class rank in the top 50% to 60%. Median SAT
test scores of
entering freshmen are 900 to 1050.
Less Competitive To be classified in this category a school must require a
pplicants to have
(omitted group) a high school class rank in the top 65%. Median SAT test
scores of entering
freshmen are below 900. Typically more than 85% of applic
ants are
admitted.
Non-competitive Schools in this category generally only require evidence
of high school
(omitted group) graduation.
Appendix II. Carnegie Foundation's Institutional Mission
Classifications
National Universities Schools in this category offer a full range of undergr
aduate programs and
(UNIVERSITY) grant the greatest number of doctoral degrees. Schools
in this category
must
receive at least $12.5 million annually in federal res
earch support.
National Liberal Arts Schools in this category are selective and attract stu
dents throughout the
U.S.
(LIBERAL) and award more than half of their degrees in the liber
al arts.
Large Comprehensive Schools in this category enroll more than 2,500 studen
ts and award more
(LCOMP) than half of their degrees in occupational or professi
onal disciplines
such as
engineering and business. Many schools in this categor
y also offer
master's degrees.
Small Comprehensive Schools in this category are simply smaller versions o
f those in the large
(SMCOMP) comprehensive category. They enroll less than 2,500 st
udents.
Regional Liberal Arts Schools in this category are typically less selective
than their national
counter-part
(omitted group) and award more than half of their degrees in the arts
and sciences.
(1.) This quote was taken from Brimelow [3]. (2.) McPherson, Schapiro
and Winston [11] have noted that for many private institutions tuition
increases since the late 1970s have been associated with increases in
institutional financial aid awards for needy students. For a discussion
of this issue as it pertains to public institutions see Hearn and
Longanecker [4]. (3.) It should be noted that our use of the term
"cross-subsidization" refers to a policy aimed at having one
group of students subsidize another. This should not be confused with
James's [5] use of the term which refers to a policy of having one
activity (such as undergraduate instruction) subsidize another (such as
graduate programs) in an institution of higher learning. (4.) In this
paper we define relatively high or inflated tuition as tuition that
exceeds what would be expected given a profile of characteristics that
meaningfully describe an institution. In section III we develop a
methodology for identifying tuitions that are relatively high or
inflated. (5.) Of course, some institutions do not possess sufficient
excess demand to increase tuition without reducing enrollment. These
institutions, however, are probably incapable of engaging in any
significant degree of cross-subsidization and are therefore irrelevant
to the analysis that follows. Regarding m, because of student
self-selection induced by a form of "sticker shock" an
increase in tuition is as likely to reduce m as to increase it [9; 12].
In the next section it will become clear that it is the ratio m/n that
matters in the empirical analysis, not the absolute size of n or m.
Since we cannot say with confidence how a tuition change will affect m
(if at all), we cannot predict, whether a tuition increase will
generally increase or decrease m/n. (6.) Institutional financial aid
includes all scholarship and grant forms of aid awarded by an
institution (this does not include federal student financial aid). Since
we are concerned with how aid affects net price, this measure does not
include aid in the form of loans or work-study. We define n as full-time
students because little if any institutional financial aid is awarded to
part-time students [8]. (7.) This assumption is based on the fact that
virtually all institutions of higher learning determine a student's
expected family contribution (EFC) according to formulas provided by the
College Board and the American College Testing Program. Since 1975 these
formulas have been required to arrive at the same EFC for any given
student, thereby establishing a uniform methodology for determining any
student's ability to pay. (8.) See Manski [10, 35-6] for an
excellent discussion of this point. (9.) Not all students that receive
Pell grants also receive institutional financial aid, and vice versa.
This means that the number of needy students as we define it (m) is not
necessarily equal to the number of students receiving Pell grants. In
the context of a cross-sectional regression, however, it is only
essential that these two variables covary across institutions in the
sample - it is not essential that they be equal for each institution.
(10.) It should be noted that our proxy for [DELTA T] is actually the
sum of the theoretical value of [DELTA T] and the estimated value of the
error term in the tuition equation. As long as the error term in the
tuition equation is independent of the error term in equation (4),
however, the coefficient estimates will remain unbiased and consistent
[7,298]. (11.) For both regressions the null hypothesis that
[BETA.sub.1] = [BETA.sub.2] = [BETA.sub.3] cannot be rejected at the 5%
on the basis of a standard F-test. The relevant F-statistics are
F(2,497) = 1.86 and F(2,497) = 0.28. The critical value for the 5% level
of significance for both tests is 3.00. (12.) Note that since [DELTA
T.sub.j] is negative for such institutions the positive coefficient
implies a negative relationship between [DELTA T.sub.j] and [A.sub.j].
(13.) Administrative overhead expenditures per student is calculated by
dividing total expenditures on institutional support (as reported to
HEGIS) by the number of full-time students (including graduate
students). Total institutional support includes general administrative
services, executive direction and planning, legal and fiscal operations,
and community relations. Note that instructional costs per student
includes the cost of graduate instruction as well as undergraduate
instruction.
References
[1.] Astin, Alexander W. and James W. Henson, "New Measures of
College Selectivity." Research in Higher Education, March 1977,
1-9. [2.] Barrons Profiles of American Colleges, 16th ed. New York:
Barrons Educational Services, 1988. [3.] Brimelow, Peter, "The
Untouchables." Forbes, November 30, 1987, 140-46. [4.] Hearn, James
C. and David Longanecker, "Enrollment Effects of Alternative
Postsecondary Pricing Policies." Journal of Higher Education,
September/October 1985, 485-508. [5.] James, Estelle, "Product Mix
and Cost Disaggregation: A Reinterpretation of the Economics of Higher
Education. " Journal of Human Resources, Spring 1978, 157-86. [6.]
_____ and Egon Neuberger, "The University Department as a
Non-profit Labor Cooperative." Public Choice, 1981(3), 585-612.
[7.] Kmenta, Jan. Elements of Econometrics. New York: Macmillan, 1971.
[8.] Leslie, Larry L., "Changing Patterns in Student Financing of
Higher Education." Journal of Higher Education, May/June 1984,
313-46. [9.] _____ and Paul T. Brinkman, "Student Price Response in
Higher Education: The Student Demand Studies." Journal of Higher
Education, March/April, 1987, 181-204. [10.] Manski, Charies E,
"Regression." Journal of Economic Literature, March 1991,
34-50. [11.] McPherson, Michael S., Morton Owen Schapiro and Gordon C.
Winston, "Recent Trends in U.S. Higher Education Costs and Prices:
The Role of Government Funding." American Economic Review, May
1989, 253-57. [12.] ______ and Morton Owen Schapiro, "Does Student
Aid Affect College Enrollment? New Evidence on a Persistent
Controversy." American Economic Review, March 1991, 309-18. [13.]
Solmon, L. C. "The Definition and Impact of College Quality,"
in Does College Matter?, edited by L. C. Solmon and P. J. Taubman. New
York: Academic Press 1973, pp. 77-105. [14.] Tierney, Michael L.,
"The Impact of Institutional Net Price on Student Demand for Public
and Private Higher Education." Economics of Education Review, Fall
1982, 363-83.