Austrian Business Cycle Theory: evidence from Kansas agriculture.
Russell, Levi A. ; Langemeier, Michael R.
JEL CLASSIFICATION: Q14, E3, B53
INTRODUCTION
Though it is considered a "heterodox" school of
economics, Austrian Economics is one of the fastest growing schools. One
of the best-known elements of Austrian theory is the Austrian Business
Cycle Theory (hereafter ABCT). This theory has received increased
attention (whether positive or negative) in the popular press (a Google
search of "Austrian Business Cycle Theory" under the
"News" tab returned 1,990 results on June 25, 2014) and in
academic studies (Laidler, 2011; Bordo and Landon-Lane, 2013).
ABCT is a theory of malinvestment (De Soto, 2009, p. 375). The
central proposition is that the market rate of interest is driven below
the rate of time preference that prevails in society (Garrison, 2001,
ch. 4). This is accomplished by an increase in the supply of money The
time preference that prevails in society is known as the "natural
rate of interest" and was developed by Wicksell (Wicksell, 1962).
Since interest rates are driven below equilibrium, the quantity demanded
of loanable funds is now higher and the quantity supplied of loanable
funds now lower than they otherwise would have been. Investment is now
unsustainably higher than its equilibrium level. At the same time,
consumption is higher because the incentive to save is lower This
constitutes the overinvestment portion of the theory As to
malinvestment, the increase in the money supply has so-called Cantillon
effects on the economy (Garrison, 2001, ch. 4). The structure of capital
in the economy is changed by the unsustainable increases in investment
and consumption This structure of capital can be conceived of as the
various complementary relationships between various capital goods
(Garrison, 2001, ch. 4; Lewin, 2011, p. 122). Investments are made which
would not otherwise be made, since the costs of those investments are
below equilibrium levels. Since the Austrian view conceives of the
economy as a complex structure instead of a series of aggregates, the
Cantillon effects are important. Some industries enjoy increases in
output prices which are higher than others. These changes in relative
prices result in unsustainable investment which affects some industries
more than others. Overall, during the boom, investment and consumption
are high. Prices in consumer goods industries and industries farthest
removed from consumption in the structure of production are higher than
prices in industries in the intermediate stages.
The onset of the bust comes when interest rates begin to increase
and converge toward the natural rate. This condition is met either when
the monetary authority sees fit to influence rates higher or when rates
on the market begin to rise, as expectations of inflation are brought to
bear (De Soto, 2009, p. 375). Investments are liquidated, but since some
capital investments are, to varying degrees, specific to certain
production processes, this liquidation can take time. Unemployment
results, as skill sets are specific to certain production processes To
the extent that retooling and retraining are hindered or costly, the
bust will persist. Output as a whole declines as liquid funds from
divested capital are reorganized into productive investments. Once the
structure of production is again consistent with resource availabilities
and tastes and preferences, the economy can resume sustainable growth
(Garrison, 2001, ch. 4). The recession of 1920/21 is often cited as a
prime example of ABCT (Woods, 2009).
Though there are few studies claiming to test or illustrate ABCT
via econometric means relative to other theories, such studies have
largely found favorable results. Wainhouse (1984) used Granger causality
tests on output data from 1959 to 1981 to determine whether a monetary
origin of the business cycle existed. Results were generally favorable,
suggesting that ABCT had empirically-demonstrated explanatory power.
Bismans and Mougeot (2009) used a panel regression approach with
data from France, Germany, UK, and USA from 1980 to 2006 to determine
whether effects consistent with ABCT could be found in the data The
study focused on changes in the term spread of interest rates (a proxy
for the difference between natural and market interest rates) as a
driver of changes in GDP. The authors did not explicitly account for
changes in monetary policy, relying instead on Bernanke (1990) to
indicate that monetary shocks explain 55 percent of the variation in the
term spread.
Recent work in the econometric examination of ABCT (Keeler, 2001;
Bismans and Mougeot, 2009; Mulligan, 2006) used observed changes in the
term structure of interest rates as a proxy for changes in the
difference between the Wicksellian natural and market interest rates The
use of the term structure as a proxy for this difference was criticized
by Carilli and Dempster (2008). They suggested that the use of the term
structure of interest rates was based on the Expectations Theory of the
term structure, which was suspect. Further, they suggested that a
measure of the difference between the natural and market rates of
interest should be independent of monetary policy actions. In the place
of the term structure of interest rates, Carilli and Dempster (2008)
used both the real growth rate of GDP and the ratio of savings to
consumption as proxies for the natural rate of interest and the federal
funds rate as the market rate.
The present work purports to test for ABCT effects using output
data from the production agriculture industry (defined as the use of
arable land to grow crops or to raise livestock) as a proxy for an
early-stage industry. We defend the selection of production agriculture
as an early stage industry on the basis that 1) it is a
capital-intensive industry, 2) its assets are highly specialized, and 3)
its products are relatively distant from final consumption.
Previous work has examined ABCT effects in early-stage industries.
Mulligan (2002) examined early-stage industries from a capacity
utilization standpoint and Young (2005) used employment statistics to
test the Hayekian version of ABCT. This study differs in that it focuses
on the net production of the agricultural sector In this way, it is
similar to other studies which focus on net aggregate production of
final goods (Carilli and Dempster, 2008; Bismans and Mougeot, 2009).
Thus, the use of output statistics in an early-stage industry is a
contribution of this study to the existing literature.
DATA
To specify the variables used in this study, six data series were
used. The time series data included information from 1973 to 2010. To
approximate the changes in reserves resulting from monetary policy,
annual data on money at zero maturity (MZM) was obtained from the St.
Louis Federal Reserve FRED database. Money at zero maturity is defined
as the M2 money supply less time deposits plus money market funds.
The gap between the natural rate and the market rate of interest
(GAP) was also approximated with data from FRED. The market rate of
interest is specified as the annual effective federal funds rate. Since,
as Carilli and Dempster (2008) and Murphy (2003) indicate, liquidity
preference is a key determinant of interest rates, the present authors
believe that the use of the real growth rate of GDP as a proxy for the
natural rate of interest is suspect. Thus, following Carilli and
Dempster (2008) and Rothbard (2001), we specify the ratio of savings to
consumption as a proxy for the natural rate To approximate output in
Kansas agriculture (OUTPUT), annual data on net farm income and value of
farm production (gross margin) were obtained from the Kansas Farm
Management Association dataset. Output is specified as the ratio of net
farm income to value of farm production. This is done to eliminate the
effect of prices on output.
The authors use profit to measure net output. This ensures that the
econometric analysis is focused on the contribution of this particular
stage (production agriculture) to the total output of the economy. Due
to the stage- and location-specificity of the data, the authors used
value of farm production to net out the effects of changes in the value
of the dollar rather than conventional price indices Conventional price
indices would not accurately account for changes in agricultural product
prices since the specific types and quality of agricultural output has
changed drastically over the period of the study. All data series from
FRED were converted to real values using the chain type price index on
personal consumption expenditures.
To determine whether each series is stationary, Augmented Dickey
Fuller tests were conducted The results can be found below in Table 1.
All three series were nonstationary in levels, so it was necessary to
difference them. The percentage change was calculated for MZM and
OUTPUT. For GAP, the first difference was taken.
METHODS
To determine whether output statistics from production agriculture
are consistent with the ABCT, the complex theory was distilled into two
propositions: that changes in reserves impact the interest rate gap, and
changes in the interest rate gap impact output of production
agriculture. Recall that GAP is defined as the difference between the
natural rate of interest and the federal funds rate. If, ceteris
paribus, the federal funds rate is pushed down (pushed up), or if the
natural rate rises (falls), GAP increases (decreases). Further, it was
necessary to find an endogenous turning point in the data where the
interest rate gap indicates, first, a rise in output followed by a fall
in output. This was done to differentiate between the claims of the ABCT
and the claims of the Monetarists (namely that policymakers can
influence output when inflation expectations are high) These two models
are approximations of those used in Carilli and Dempster (2008).
To estimate the first model, a structural vector autoregression
(SVAR) was estimated. The SVAR was used because it allows for
relationships between contemporaneous values of the regressors whereas
standard VAR analysis does not. This is a departure from Carilli and
Dempster (2008). To determine the number of lags, the Akaike information
criterion was used. The results are found in Table 2. A lag length of 3
was chosen based on this test.
To determine whether the causal relationships elucidated in the
first model were a feature of the data, Granger causality tests were
conducted. Granger causality is not a test of causation in the
conventional sense; it merely shows whether or not there is significant
evidence that lagged values of one variable improve the forecasts of
another variable Still, it is important in deciphering whether or not
changes in MZM are leading indicators of changes in the interest rate
gap and whether or not changes in the interest rate gap are leading
indicators of changes in agricultural output.
There was not statistically significant evidence of a
Granger-causal relationship between MZM and GAP (Table 3). That is, lags
of MZM do not improve forecasts of GAP. However, there was a
statistically significant relationship between changes in GAP and
changes in OUTPUT. Lags of changes in the interest rate gap improved
forecasts of changes in output This result indicates that some
statistically significant relationship exists between the interest rate
gap (and therefore interest rate policy) and output in agriculture.
Further tests are needed to explore this result in greater depth.
The next step in the analysis was to specify the coefficient matrix
for the contemporaneous values of the regressors in the SVAR To specify
this matrix (Table 4), assumptions based on theory were necessary. Since
there were three variables, it was necessary to specify three
assumptions. For the equation with the percentage change in MZM as the
left hand side variable, it was assumed that the other variables do not
impact MZM in the current year Since the Federal Open Market Committee
influences market rates via manipulation of bank reserves, it is
unlikely that interest rates would impact reserves in the same period.
Even if such effects exist, there are lags associated with monetary
policy that would push these effects off to a later period It is
unlikely that production agriculture is large enough to have an impact
on total reserves contemporaneously as well Output in production
agriculture may impact reserve levels if managers, overall, reduce or
increase their debt loads in a relatively short period of time. However,
this effect is likely to be delayed, since even short-term operating
loans are secured before the production year. The third and final
assumption was that output will not impact the interest rate gap in the
same period Market interest rates may be impacted if farmers change
their debt loads, but again, this decision is made after that output is
observed.
To further determine the impacts of changes in MZM on GAP and the
impacts of changes in GAP on changes in OUTPUT, impulse response
analysis and forecast error variance decompositions were estimated This
analysis will paint a more detailed picture of the relationships between
these variables The impulse response analysis (IRA) shows how an
exogenous shock to one variable impacts other variables over time This
was important for determining whether the ABCT effects were features of
the data The forecast error variance decomposition (FEVD) gives the
percentage of the forecast error variance of a given variable that is
explained by exogenous shocks to all the variables over time The results
of this analysis will help to understand how much each variable was
responsible for changes in the others from a forecasting standpoint.
The next element of the analysis was to estimate a polynomial
distributed lag model The purpose of this analysis was to determine
whether or not an endogenous turning point exists in the data That is,
whether or not lags of GAP have a relationship to OUTPUT such that
earlier lags were positively related and later lags were negatively
related. The question being answered is whether or not the business
cycle (in this case, increases followed by decreases in the output of a
sector relatively distant from consumption) was a function of this gap
The polynomial distributed lag model estimated will be quadratic so as
to capture the potentially-nonlinear relationship between GAP and
OUTPUT.
Finally, the Diebold-Mariano (D-M) test was conducted. This test
was designed to determine whether one of a pair of variables was better
at forecasting a third. For the purpose of this study, the two predictor
variables being compared were changes in MZM and changes in GAP. The
findings will indicate to what degree the interest rate gap was
necessary in the causal chain proposed above to predict OUTPUT.
RESULTS
Impulse Response and Forecast Error Variance Decomposition Analysis
To determine the relationships between MZM, GAP, and OUTPUT,
impulse response analysis (IRA) was conducted on the SVAR coefficients
(Table 5). Since GAP is the difference between the natural rate of
interest and the federal funds rate, it should rise as MZM increases.
The IRA (found in Table 6) displays some interesting results. An
exogenous, one unit shock to the change in MZM results in a large
increase in the change in the interest rate gap, as expected. This
change eventually becomes negative at 4 steps ahead and returns to a
positive (albeit small) value in period 7.
The initial positive effect of MZM on GAP which turns negative
after 4 years indicates that changes in the money supply can only
temporarily drive rates below their natural level There is an endogenous
turning point; an increase in the money supply will drive rates down in
the near term, but rates must rise later because the pool of saved
resources has not increased This endogeneity differentiates ABCT from
the claims of the Monetarists.
At 8 steps ahead, there is still a small, positive level effect on
the change in the interest rate gap In other words, a change in the
money supply tends to drive a wedge between the natural rate and the
market rate even after 8 years have passed. However, these results are
suspect, as the Granger causality test found no evidence to support the
notion that a change in MZM is a leading indicator of changes in the gap
The change in MZM also has an initially positive effect on the change in
output. At 6 years ahead, this effect becomes negative and remains so
through 8 years ahead.
The impulse response function analysis indicates that the ABCT
effects on output may be a result of shocks to changes in MZM. The
impacts of a shock to the change in the interest rate gap have very
little effect at all on changes in output. It is necessary to be humble
about all the results presented on the IRA because the confidence bands
are extremely broad. This is likely a result of the small sample size.
The FEVD analysis (Table 7) further indicates that MZM is a
relatively more powerful predictor of OUTPUT Nearly all the variation in
the forecast errors is a function of exogenous shocks to the change in
MZM That is, shocks to the change in the interest rate gap are not
responsible for hardly any of the variation in the forecast errors for
the change in output This suggests that perhaps changes in MZM in this
model have the most predictive power for the variables of interest This
is a somewhat strange result, as the Granger causality test for changes
in the interest rate gap as a leading indicator of the changes in output
was significant at the 10 percent level More work is needed to decipher
these seemingly conflicting results.
Polynomial Distributed Lag Function Analysis
The results of the polynomial distributed lag model (Almon, 1965)
show, perhaps, the strongest evidence for ABCT effects in production
agriculture Lags of GAP are regressed on OUTPUT to determine whether
effects predicted by ABCT exist. The model was estimated with a
polynomial of degree two According to the results (Table 8), the
p-values on the linear and quadratic terms were both significant at the
5 percent level. The polynomial may be of a higher order, but it is at
least quadratic. (1)
The lagged values exhibit features consistent with the ABCT and
demonstrate the existence of an endogenous turning point This endogenous
turning point differentiates the Austrian theory from the Monetarist
theory in that it demonstrates that interest rate manipulation creates
mal-investments and overconsumption in the short run which must be
liquidated and reduced in the long run.
(Carilli and Dempster, 2008). The five earliest lags have positive
coefficients (though they are not statistically significant at the 10
percent level) and the final three lags have negative coefficients. This
implies that an innovation in GAP, which occurs when the market rate of
interest is driven below the natural rate, initially raises OUTPUT for
four years, after which OUTPUT falls This result, coupled with the
Granger causality tests, indicates ABCT effects in the data which are
distinct from effects consistent with Monetarist theory. Only two of the
coefficients for this model are significantly different from zero
statistically. Again, this may be a problem of a small sample size.
Diebold-Mariano Test
The Diebold-Mariano test (Table 9) for differences in the forecast
errors of two models was also conducted. The first model is the change
in MZM predicting the change in OUTPUT The second is the change in GAP
predicting the change in OUTPUT The null hypothesis is that the expected
value of the difference between the squared errors is zero. If the null
hypothesis is rejected, it indicates that the forecasting ability of the
two models are different. If we fail to reject the null, it indicates
that the forecasting ability of the two models are not statistically
different. If forecasts in the two models are not statistically
different, it indicates that the interest rate gap may not be the
conduit through which changes in the money supply affect agricultural
output.
A squared loss function was used to compute z-scores to determine
if there is a statistically significant difference between the
forecasting power of the two models Recursive, pseudo-outof-sample
forecasts were estimated for the models starting in 1988. Forecasts for
1, 2, and 3 steps ahead were calculated and a squared loss function was
used. As the z scores indicate, the difference between the forecast
errors is not significantly different from zero.
Since changes in MZM and changes in GAP are both equally good
leading indicators of changes in OUTPUT, it may be that changes in
output are not explained very well at all by either. This indicates that
neither model is better than the other at predicting changes in output.
These findings contradict the results of the FEVD analysis. However, it
is important to note that this paper makes use of annual data and that
it may be difficult to distinguish statistically between innovations
and, MZM and GAP.
CONCLUSION
The purpose of this study was to determine whether the observable
data on the US monetary system and Kansas production agriculture are
consistent with ABCT. The findings in this study are mixed. The Granger
causality test and the polynomial distributed lag analysis indicate that
changes in the interest rate gap are a good leading indicator of changes
in agricultural output, and therefore that ABCT effects exist in the
data.
Specifically, the results indicate that downside deviations in the
interest rate gap have a nonlinear effect on output such that output is
increased in the short run and decreases after a period of time Since
this nonlinear effect of the interest rate gap on output has an
endogenous turning point, we suggest that this is evidence of the ABCT
and not of Monetarist theories which do not predict an endogenous
turning point. (Carilli and Dempster, 2008)
However, the IRA, FEVD, and D-M test analyses indicate that Federal
Reserve policy is a better predictor of changes in agricultural output
and that ABCT effects do not exist in the data according to the model
presented. While monetary policy clearly has an effect on the interest
rate gap, it is not clear based on the findings of these tests whether
monetary policy affects the output of production agriculture through its
effect on the interest rate gap. Additional research is needed to
determine whether these results can be reconciled or whether more robust
results can be found with similar data.
One of the primary difficulties with this analysis is determining
whether MZM is a good indicator of reserves Part of the problem here is
that many Austrian business cycle theorists speak of the supply of money
rather than reserves as the variable that is manipulated by the monetary
authority We have followed the method used by Carilli and Dempster
(2008) in an earlier version of their paper. However, MZM was not used
in the final version of their paper More work is needed to determine the
proper variable to specify the measure spoken of in the theory.
Another problem with this analysis is a lack of data. Future
analysis will include finding a suitable proxy for production
agricultural output to enhance the number of observations available.
Another appropriate extension would be to use other specifications
of the natural rate of interest.
REFERENCES
Almon, Shirley. 1965. "The Distributed Lag Between Capital
Appropriations and Expenditures," Econometrica 33, no. 1: 178-196.
Bernanke, Benjamin. 1990. "On the predictive power of interest
rates and interest rate spreads. " New England Economic Review
3486: 51-68.
Bismans, Francis, and Christelle Mougeot 2009. "Austrian
Business Cycle Theory: Empirical Evidence," Review of Austrian
Economics 22, no. 3: 241-257
Bordo, Michael D. , and John Landon-Lane. "Does Expansionary
Monetary Policy Cause Asset Price Booms; Some Historical and Empirical
Evidence," NBER Working Paper Series, 2013: Working Paper 19585.
Carilli, Anthony M., and Gregory M. Dempster. 2008. "Is the
Austrian Business Cycle Theory Still Relevant?" Review of Austrian
Economics 21, no. 4: 271-281.
De Soto, Jesus Huerta 2009 Money, Bank Credit, and Economic Cycles
Auburn, Ala : Ludwig von Mises Institute
Garrison, Roger W 2001. Time and Money: The Macroeconomics of
Capital Structure. New York: Routledge.
Keeler, James P 2001. "Empirical Evidence on the Austrian
Business Cycle Theory," Review of Austrian Economics 14, no. 4:
331-351.
Laidler, David 2011 "The Monetary Economy and the Economic
Crisis," Center for the History of Political Economy.
Lewin, Peter 2011 Capital in Disequilibrium Auburn, Ala : Ludwig
von Mises Institute.
Mulligan, Robert F 2002 "A Hayekian Analysis of the Term
Structure of Production," Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics
5, no. 2: 17-33.
--. 2006. "An Empirical Examination of Austrian Business Cycle
Theory," Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 9, no. 2: 69-93.
Murphy, Robert P. 2003. "Unanticipated Intertemporal Change in
Theories of Interest. " Dissertation, New York University Available
at https:// files.nyu.edu/rpm213/public/files/Dissertation.pdf.
Rothbard, Murray N. 2001. Man, Economy, and State: A Treatise on
Economic Principles. Auburn, Ala. : Ludwig von Mises Institute.
Wainhouse, Charles. 1984. "Empirical Evidence for Hayek's
Theory of Economic Fluctuations. " In B. Siegel, ed., Money in
Crisis, pp. 37-71. San Francisco: Pacific Institute for Public Policy
Research.
Wicksell, Knut 1962. Interest and Prices. New York: Sentry Press.
Woods, Thomas E. , Jr. 2009. "Warren Harding and the Forgotten
Depression of 1920," The Intercollegiate Review 44, no. 2: 22-29.
Young, Andrew T 2005. "Reallocating Labor to Initiate Changes
in Capital Structures: Hayek Revisited," Economics Letters 89, no.
3: 275-282.
Levi A. Russell (lrussell@tamu.edu) is Assistant Professor and
Extension Economist in the Department of Agricultural Economics at Texas
A&M University. Michael R. Langemeier (mlangeme@purdue.edu) is the
Associate Director of the Center for Commercial Agriculture in the
Department of Agricultural Economics at Purdue University The authors
appreciate helpful comments from an anonymous reviewer.
(1) The Durbin-Watson test indicates white-noise errors. This
indicates that the lag length selection is not problematic.
APPENDIX
Table 1. Augmented Dickey-Fuller Tests
type t-stat 5% t-crit
MZM trend -0.083 -3.588
GAP trend -2.239 -2.994
OUTPUT trend -2.067 -3.588
Table 2. Lag Length Selection
AIC
0 4.728
1 4.283
2 4.371
3 4.138 *
4 4.390
* Minimum AIC indicates appropriate lag length
Table 3. Granger Causality Tests
Lags Improve p-value
of: forecasts
of:
MZM GAP 0.302
GAP OUTPUT 0.053 *
* indicates significance at the 10% level
Table 4. SVAR Matrix of Coefficients on
Contemporaneous Values
MZM GAP OUTPUT
MZM 0 0
GAP 22.321 1 0
OUTPUT 1.767 0.036 1
Table 5. SVAR Estimation Results
Equation: MZM Lag Coefficient P-value
MZM 1 0.925 0.000 ***
GAP 1 0 0.93
OUTPUT 1 -0.03 0.000 ***
MZM 2 -0.433 0.057 *
GAP 2 -0.007 0.084 *
OUTPUT 2 0.027 0.010 ***
MZM 3 0.074 0.62
GAP 3 -0.002 0.568
OUTPUT 3 -0.021 0.032 **
Constant 0.013 0.252
Equation: GAP Lag Coefficient P-value
MZM 1 12.499 0.209
GAP 1 -0.232 0.286
OUTPUT 1 0.033 0.925
MZM 2 -5.391 0.618
GAP 2 0.097 0.63
OUTPUT 2 0.441 0.363
MZM 3 -5.028 0.495
GAP 3 -0.298 0.061 *
OUTPUT 3 -0.162 0.718
Constant -0.279 0.622
Equation: OUTPUT Lag Coefficient P-value
MZM 1 5.215 0.313
GAP 1 0.102 0.367
OUTPUT 1 0.066 0.719
MZM 2 2.205 0.696
GAP 2 -0.164 0.127
OUTPUT 2 -0.053 0.832
MZM 3 6.951 0.079 *
GAP 3 0.14 0.090 *
OUTPUT 3 0.109 0.643
Constant -5.82 0.058 *
* Indicates significance at the 10% level
** Indicates significance at the 5% level
*** Indicates significance at the 1% level
Table 6. Impulse Response Analysis
Impulse Response
MZM GAP OUTPUT
1 22.321 1.767
2 7.369 7.617
3 6.893 4.206
4 -13.728 11.653
5 -5.930 4.201
6 -4.472 -1.482
7 6.057 -5.884
8 3.325 -2.830
Impulse Response
GAP OUTPUT
1 0.036
2 0.105
3 -0.190
4 0.120
5 -0.116
6 -0.048
7 -0.077
8 0.017
Table 7. Forecast Error Variance Decomposition
MZM MZM GAP OUTPUT
1 1 0 0
3 0.999 0.000 0.001
6 0.999 0.000 0.000
8 0.999 0.000 0.000
GAP MZM GAP OUTPUT
1 0.998 0.002 0.000
3 0.998 0.002 0.000
6 0.998 0.002 0.000
8 0.998 0.002 0.000
OUTPUT MZM GAP OUTPUT
1 0.757 0.000 0.243
3 0.986 0.001 0.013
6 0.995 0.000 0.005
8 0.996 0.000 0.004
Table 8. Polynomial Distributed Lag Function
Degrees of
Polynomial
Coefficient p-value
Intercept 0.014 0.943
Constant -0.025 0.856
Linear -0.288 0.005 ***
term
Quadratic -0.190 0.032 **
term
Lags of Lag p-value
GAP Distribution
Coefficient
0 0.039 0.616
1 0.078 0.197
2 0.095 0.111
3 0.090 0.164
4 0.064 0.345
5 0.016 0.808
6 -0.054 0.365
7 -0.145 0.010 **
8 -0.258 0.000 ***
Dubin-Watson Test Statistic
D-W = 1.752
*** indicates significance at the 1% level
** indicates significance at the 5% level
Dependent variable: OUTPUT
Table 9. Diebold-Mariano Test
steps z-score
1 0.214
2 0.213
3 0.213