The marginal efficiency of capital: Rejoinder.
Fuller, Edward W.
JEL CLASSIFICATION: E12, E22, E52, E58
INTRODUCTION
This paper is a rejoinder to "The Marginal Efficiency of
Capital: Comment" by Lucas M. Engelhardt. Engelhardt attempts to
show that Keynes's Marginal Efficiency of Capital (MEC) and the Net
Present Value (NPV) always give identical rankings if factor prices are
flexible. Engelhardt is unsuccessful. Therefore, Engelhardt does not
prove that Keynes has a wealth maximizing theory of investment.
ENGELHARDT'S EXAMPLE
Engelhardt uses an example to illustrate that Keynes's MEC and
the NPV always give identical rankings if factor prices are flexible.
However, his example is problematic. What Engelhardt (p. 522) represents
as the MEC is not Keynes's MEC. Engelhardt calculates something
much different: "I assume that the project's startup cost is
equal to the greater of the two present values. Then I calculate the
interest rate that would be required to make the Net Present Value of
each project zero" (Engelhardt, p. 521). This is not the definition
of the MEC. Keynes's MEC is the "rate of discount which would
make the present value ... equal to its supply price" (Keynes, p.
135 emphasis added). The calculation of Keynes's MEC does not
involve two investment projects. Keynes's MEC only involves one
project, but Engelhardt's calculation involves two projects. Since
Engelhardt does not use Keynes's MEC, he does not prove that the
NPV and Keynes's MEC always give identical results if factor prices
are flexible.
In table 1 of his comment, Engelhardt (p. 521) incorrectly ranks
investment projects according to the Present Value (PV) instead of the
Net Present Value (NPV): "we calculate the Present Values (not the
Net Present Values). Fuller's NPV was really just present value,
but subtracting an arbitrary constant" (Engelhardt, p. 520). This
is a fundamental error. Investors do not rank projects by PV. Investors
rank projects by NPV. The NPV is the investor's entrepreneurial
profit, and "business always tends to adopt those practices and
that scale of activity which maximize profits" (Rothbard, p. 1118).
According to Mises (1922, p. 119),
the motive force of the whole process which gives rise to market
prices for the factors of production is the ceaseless search on the
part of the capitalists and the entrepreneurs to maximize their
profits by serving the consumers' wishes ... It is only the
prospect of profit which directs production into those channels in
which the demands of the consumer are best satisfied at least cost.
Engelhardt's Internal Rate of Return (IRR) rankings are
identical to his PV rankings However, PV rankings are not wealth
maximizing rankings. Therefore, Engelhardt's IRR rankings are not
wealth maximizing. Even if Keynes had used Engelhardt's IRR, his
theory would still be flawed. Engelhardt's IRR is not a substitute
for the NPV or Keynes's MEC. Engelhardt does not clarify the
difference between the Austrian and Keynesian approaches to economic
calculation because he does not use the NPV or Keynes's MEC.
CLARIFICATIONS
According to Engelhardt (p. 520), "the result that the two
approaches result in different rankings will only hold if factor prices
are held constant. " This is not true, and Fuller (p. 393) does not
assume that factor prices are constant to show that the MEC contradicts
the NPV Economic calculation must take place at a certain point in time.
Balance sheets and NPV calculations "describe as well as possible
the state of affairs at an arbitrarily chosen instant while life and
action go on and do not stop" (Mises, 1949, p. 215). Prices are
always changing, but the investor must use current market prices at the
time he is ranking projects. Given factor prices at the time of economic
calculation, Keynes's MEC contradicts the NPV when the interest
rate is below the crossover rate Factor prices can change in the future,
but what matters is that the MEC contradicted the NPV at the time of the
investor's economic calculation.
Engelhardt does not distinguish between independent projects and
mutually exclusive projects. This is clear in table 3 of his comment
Engelhardt (p 523) says, "if the interest rate is less than 23.38
percent, then both Project 1 and Project 2 are undertaken."
Engelhardt does not realize that he is dealing with mutually exclusive
projects. According to Mises (1949, p. 694), "there is the
embarrassing multitude of producers' goods and the infinite variety
of procedures that can be resorted to for manufacturing definite
consumers' goods." Furthermore,
it can very easily be decided which kind and what number of
consumption goods should be produced. No one has ever denied that. But
once this decision has been made, there still remains the problem of
ascertaining how the existing means of production can be used most
effectively to produce these goods in question. In order to solve this
problem it is necessary that there should be economic calculation
(Mises, 1922, p 123)
The wooden bridge and the steel bridge are mutually exclusive
projects. The investor-entrepreneur can only build one bridge. He cannot
build both bridges in the same place The investor in Fuller (p. 385)
uses the NPV to decide which bridge to build. It is not a simple accept
or reject decision as Engelhardt (p. 522) suggests. Engelhardt's
example in table 3 does not prove that the MEC and NPV give identical
results because Engelhardt does not distinguish between independent and
mutually exclusive projects.
CONCLUSION
Fuller (p. 393) shows that Keynes has a flawed theory of
investment. To Keynes, investment is the fundamental problem with the
free market economy: "The weakness of the inducement to invest has
been at all times the key to the economic problem" (Keynes, pp.
347-348). Keynes's theory of investment is absolutely essential to
his critique of Say's Law and the free market economy. According to
Alvin Hansen (p. 34),
The slope of the consumption function ... is indeed a necessary
pillar for the overthrow of Say's law. But it is not sufficient. In
addition, it must also be shown that there is no reason to suppose
that the price system will operate in a manner so that investment
outlays will automatically tend to fill the ever-widening gap, in
absolute terms, between consumption and output.
Keynes's critique of the free market economy is problematic
because Keynes's theory of investment is flawed. Moreover, since
the MEC is not a wealth maximizing theory of investment, the MEC rules
out the Austrian Business Cycle Theory.
One great advantage of Roger Garrison's capital-based
framework is that it is a comparative framework It can be used to
compare the Austrian theory with Keynes's theory However, there is
no place for the individual entrepreneur conducting economic calculation
in the capital-based framework The NPV diagram injects the individual
entrepreneur into the capital-based framework. The NPV diagram is also a
comparative framework that can be used to compare the Austrian theory
and Keynes's theory The NPV diagram shows that "Keynes's
internal rate of return [MEC] did not give an investment demand function
according to the maximum present wealth criterion of choice by
investors" (Alchian, p. 941). The NPV diagram illustrates that
Keynes's critique of the free market economy is problematic because
Keynes had a flawed theory of investment. Engelhardt does not prove that
Keynes has a wealth maximizing theory of investment. Engelhardt has not
successfully defended Keynes's theory.
REFERENCES
Alchian, Armen A. 1955. "The Rate of Interest, Fisher's
Rate of Return over Cost and Keynes' Internal Rate of Return,"
American Economic Review 45: 938-942.
Engelhardt, Lucas M. 2014. "The Marginal Efficiency of
Capital: A Comment," Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 17,
no. 4: 519-524.
Fuller, Edward W. 2013. "The Marginal Efficiency of
Capital," Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 16, no. 4:
379-400.
Hansen, Alvin H. 1953. A Guide to Keynes. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Keynes, John M. 1936. General Theory of Employment, Interest and
Money. Amherst, N.Y. : Prometheus Books, 1997.
Mises, Ludwig von. 1949. Human Action: A Treatise on Economics.
Scholar's Ed. Auburn, Ala. : Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1998.
--. 1922. Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis.
Indianapolis: Liberty Classics, 1981.
Rothbard, Murray N. 1962. Man, Economy and State: A Treatise on
Economic Principles. Scholar's Ed. Auburn, Ala. : Ludwig von Mises
Institute, 2004.
Edward W. Fuller (Edward.W.Fuller@gmail.com), MBA, is a graduate of
the Leavey School of Business.